Wage Determination of Child Labor and Effect of Trade Reform Saibal Kar1 and Basudeb Guha-Khasnobis2 September 2003 Abstract This study examines the interaction of a small open economy engaged in trade in goods and services with the process of household decision-making, where individuals are characterized by a degree of relative risk aversion. In particular, we determine the demand for child labor originating in the small open economy and compare that against child labor supply determined by household decisions. In the process, we determine the equilibrium child wage endogenously, as a fraction of the equilibrium adult wage. Trade reform policies affect both demand and supply of child labor and the equilibrium child wage through its effects simultaneously on the production pattern and on household labor market decisions. Based on these demand and supply movements generated through various parametric shifts, we offer our propositions on the incidence of child labor. 1 Address for Correspondence: Dr. Saibal Kar, Research Officer, Reserve Bank Of India Endowment, Centre For Studies In Social Sciences, Calcutta. R 1, B.P. Township, Calcutta 700 094, India. PH. 91-33-2462 5794/ 5795/7252. EXT. 230. FAX. 91-33-2462 6183. E-mail: skar<econcsss@giascl01.vsnl.net.in> / skar1801@yahoo.com 2 UNU-WIDER, Katajanokanlaituri 6 B, Helsinki 00160, Finland. E-mail: basudeb@wider.unu.edu. 1. Introduction In almost all the recent studies on the existence of child labor in developing countries, its alarming extent and magnitude has been carefully documented and highlighted. The entrenchment of the practice of child labor in developing societies3has unanimously been declared problematic and upsetting.4 Various policy propositions in favor of eradicating child labor has at best produced inconclusive results, which in turn has made implementation of any or all of these policies rather difficult. As the extensive literature suggests, the issue of the prevalence of child labor has been approached from many angles. Grootaert and Kanbur (1995) provides an elegant compendium of how the economics of child labor may be approached, and in later studies we find a number of points mentioned here being taken up for further investigation. Apparently, such studies have been successful in creating a large number of explanations behind incidence of child labor, whether demand determined or supply determined. Demand for child labor is generated by several factors. Segmentation of the economy between formal and informal sectors and the degree of informalization is an important factor in generating such demand. Formal sector of an economy, which adheres more closely to labor laws prevailing in the country cannot for understandable 3 Although child labor is a much more visible phenomenon for developing nations, a decade or so ago even the United States had more than 4 million children in the working class (Corbin, 1988). Child labor by definition of ILO pertains to children below the age of 15 years. We also include children working for the household at the expense of school time. 4 Child labor is not necessarily considered ‘bad’ in every society. Work instead of education is believed to instill survival skills in the children (Bekombo, 1981; Agiobu-Kemmer, 1992). A related question may be: does every child need formal education? On the job training or apprenticeship and skill acquisition from an early age can provide them with an adequate means of living. Quoting Agiobu-Kemmer, (1992, p.7), “ Education broadens your mind but it does not teach you how to survive”. There is no doubt a problem with such arguments. Every child does not have to excel in educational attainments and neither is that practically feasible. However, every child must have at least primary education to take advantage of possible socio-economic developments around him/her. This not only enables the child to communicate with the outside domain but also acts as insurance against future shocks when such skills may be in considerable need. Moreover, education generates self-esteem and capacity of bargaining in the face of hostile socio-economic situations. reasons engage in child labor employment. 5 Demand for child labor mostly originate in the informal sector which itself bypasses legal regulations for various interests of its own. This moreover has much to do with the technology used in production under the behest of the informal economy. Children in developing countries are largely engaged in production of goods and services where adult labor are imperfect substitutes. This can range from employment of boys in quarries (where adult labor finds it difficult to do mining in the narrow tunnels) to chimney sweeps or of children for weaving carpets with their ‘nimble’ fingers (Grootaert and Kanbur, 1995, p. 195, also see GuhaKhasnobis et al, 1999). Apart from that there is high demand for children workers in the agriculture and allied sector, involving delicate plantations and harvesting or cattle herding. Use of children as domestic helps/servants is also a common feature in these countries. However, despite such widespread evidence on child labor, the problem remains in estimating the demand for child labor properly, simply because once child labor is prohibited by law, it does not exist legally and thus obtaining a positive demand for child workers becomes rather impossible. On the other hand, there are many supply-side determinants of the occurrences of child labor, ranging from cultural factors to poverty-related causes. In this connection Grootaert and Kanbur (1995) raise the issue of household responses towards risk. If households face income risk, they might send their children to work to better manage such risks, especially at income levels where any negative fluctuations could mean disaster. We pursue this point further. While the objective of this study is laid out shortly, we can elaborate a little bit more on this ground presently. In the absence of savings, liquid assets or ability to borrow (Mendelievich, 5 Exceptions are plantation farms (eg. Bonnet, 1993, for Africa; Goonesekere, 1993, for Sri Lanka). 1979) most individuals seem to be distributed on the higher scale of relative risk aversion and decide to engage their children in work for supporting an unstable household income. In the later part of the study, we obtain a critical degree of such relative risk aversion, such that, all individuals distributed with a relative risk aversion above the critical level would spontaneously trigger the decision to send their children to work with or without possibilities of adverse shocks. It may be argued that if individuals are characterized by varying degrees of relative risk aversion, then for highly risk-averse decision-makers, such reactions are obvious; the reverse being true for low risk-averse individuals. We show that attainment of the critical degree of relative risk aversion will automatically classify individuals falling into groups of high risk-averse individuals and low risk-averse individuals even if one begins with an assumption of equally risk-averse individuals distributed uniformly over a scale of measurement. Grootaert and Kanbur (1995, p. 194) carefully distinguish between strategies to insure against adverse income shocks and that between ensuring old-age care. In the first case, parents decide to send their children to work, while in the second case they would want to send their children to school so that old-age transfers are higher. Although demand for having children would be high in both cases, there is a potential conflict between short-run and long-run gains as realized by the parents. This should be reflected in the expected utility facing the parents and as our analysis would show, parents face a trade-off between high-risk and long run gains. Supply of child labor is accordingly affected by distribution of parents between high-risk and low-risk choices, or rather between short run income smoothing choice and long run income transfer.6 There are a number of other models of household decision to send children to work. Basu and Van (1998) assume child labor to be bad in parental preference, such that, as household income exceeds some threshold, children are withdrawn from the labor force. They identify several factors such as price and returns to education, the price of the goods that households consume and produces, adult wage, child wage as a fraction of adult wage etc.7 Here as also in Basu (2000), child wage is an arbitrary fraction of adult wage. Basu (1998) obtains equilibrium employment of child labor through a demand-supply interaction, but it is based on exogenously given child and adult wages. Empirically, child and adult labor are shown to be substitutes or complementary depending on gender, age and country type (see for example, Ray, 2000). One of the contributions we make in this paper is providing a definitive method of calculating the equilibrium child wage as a fraction of adult wage and obtaining the nature of relationship between child and adult workers, that can be interpreted suitably in accordance with the empirical results. Ray (2000) test for the luxury axiom in Basu and Van (1998), which essentially says that as the family falls into poverty, children are withdrawn from school. For Peru and Pakistan, the two countries with similar rates of children living in poverty (approximately 30%), that Ray (2000) tests for, it is observed that while the axiom is true for Pakistan (although with a gender discrimination against girls) it is contradicted for Peru.8 6 Note that, this is not a dynamic model. Here all gains are static and can at best be viewed as pesent discounted value of all future earnings. 7 Also see Baland and Robinson (2000). Brown (2000), Dixit (2000) consider the effect of raising foreign country price of goods using child labor on the incidence of child labor in developing countries in a simplified Basu and Van (1998) framework. 8 A possible explanation for contradictory evidence in Peru may be found in Patrinos and Psacharopoulos (1997, p. 398), “working actually makes it possible for the children to go to school.” Credit constraints may also play a significant role in influencing supply of child labor in a household model. Ranjan (2001, also see Dehejia and Gatti, 2002) builds up a connection between trade policy and child labor in a household model with credit constraints. This paper shows that trade sanctions might not reduce the incidence of child labor in a long-run model of trade based on differences in relative endowments across countries. Previously, Maskus (1997) shows that imposition of foreign tariff on the exported good has ambiguous effect on the incidence of child labor. On the other hand, if child labor serves as a specific factor to the export sector (Melchior, 1996), imposing tariff on export price of the good lowers returns to child labor and therefore the supply of child labor. These results seem to differ on the basis of peculiarities in the specific model building and the study by Edmonds and Pavcnik (2002) takes up an empirical connection between globalization of the rice price in Vietnam and reduction of the extent of child labor in the country. The results display a positive causation such that, a 30% increase in relative price of rice helps reducing child labor by an average of 9 percentage points. In rural Vietnam especially, it accounted for 45% reduction in child labor (about 1 million less child labor between 1993-98), with households having larger land holdings experiencing larger reductions. A brief encounter with the economics of child labor thus provides various paradigms one can look further into. This study is an attempt to bring together the interaction of a small open economy engaged in trade in goods and services with the process of household decision-making, where individuals are characterized by a degree of relative risk aversion. The importance of the study lies in the fact that here we determine the demand for child labor originating in the small open economy and compare that against child labor supply determined by household decisions. In the process, we determine the equilibrium child wage endogenously as a fraction of the equilibrium adult wage. Trade reform policies affect both demand and supply of child labor and the equilibrium child wage through its effects simultaneously on the production pattern and on household labor market decisions, channeled through the wage movements. Based on these demand and supply movements generated through various parametric shifts, we offer our propositions on the incidence of child labor. It should, however, be noted that we are not trying to provide yet another theory of determination of child wage and extent of child employment. Instead, we emphasize the importance of observing the link between economic restructuring, wage and labor mobility and labor market decisions by individuals characterized by relative risk aversion, in order to focus on the incidence of child labor. The plan of the paper is as follows. In section 2 we present the model. In section 3 we provide an overview of the results and conclude. 2. The Model Let there be a three-sector small open economy producing three goods X, Y and Z. X is an import-competing industrial good and is protected by a proportional tariff t. It requires the use of Y as an intermediate good, which is produced and traded at world prices, PY * . Z is an export good. Other than Y, X also requires the use of capital, K (interest rate, R) and adult labor, L (formal and unionized, at an administered wage w ). One can assume Y to be agricultural output, which is produced with adult labor (informal, at market-determined wage, w), child labor, C (at a wage γ L w , 0 < γ L < 1 ) and land (T, at rental rate τ ).9 On the other hand, production of Z requires the use of adult labor, child labor and capital at per unit prices given above.10 Production is based on fixed endowments of L, K and T and on the basis of given production technologies. Demand for child labor (C), on the other hand is determined endogenously, such that it is less than or equal to the stock of children ( C ) in the economy, C ≤ C . We define child labor wage as, wC = γ L w , 0 < γ L <1 (1) In standard literature (for example, Basu, 2000), γ , a general discounting factor, is treated as an exogenous constant and thus wC is readily determined once w is known. We propose that, γ instead is an endogenous variable, which2 may be interpreted as the equilibrium level of effort exerted by a child labor. A child may exert varying levels of effort at work and at school. At the point, where such efforts are same, the child is indifferent between going to school or to work. For sake of simplicity we assume that the total level of effort exerted by the child in going to school ( γ S ) and to work ( γ L ) cannot exceed 1. In other words, γ L = 1−γ S (2) It directly follows that when the child is full-time in school and not spending any time 9 One can assume X to be food processing industry, using agricultural, dairy, poultry and marine inputs traded at world prices. Y is a direct example of agricultural product ranging from fruits or cereals to fish and meat production. Z is an industrial/ handicraft export, using child labor. In case of India, for example, a famous example is in the carpet industry. 10 Viewed alternatively, the economy consists of a formal (and urban, X) sector and an informal (rural and urban/semi-urban, Y and Z respectively) sector. Formal sector follows legal procedures and labor laws, while similar enforcements are not suitably applicable for production of Y and Z. We conceptualize the general equilibrium structure of the economy in this form that covers main sectors using the essential in the labor market, γ S = 1 and γ L = 0. The reverse occurs when the child is employed full-time and has zero school attendance. Any combination of both school time and work time is possible under this structure.11 In our model, γ L is endogenously determined by the interaction of demand and supply for child labor. Demand originates from the general equilibrium structure of the small open economy and supply from the household comparison of parental utilities from sending the child to work or to school. While the intricacies of such determination will be presented below, we first offer the general equilibrium system of the small open economy under perfect competition following other neo-classical assumptions of fullemployment, diminishing marginal returns and so on. Let PX* (1 + t ) = Tariff included price of X PZ* = Price of export good Z aij = Amount of ith factor for producing one unit of jth commodity. The following equations display the zero-profit and full-employment conditions for our economy: a LX w + a KX R + aYX PY * = PX* (1 + t ) (3) a LY w + aCY wC + aTY τ = PY* (4) a LZ w + aCZ wC + a KZ R = PZ* (5) a LX X + a LY Y + a LZ Z = L (6) factors of production. One can further introduce capital specificity across formal and informal sectors, but we believe that it does not change the main results of our model. 11 It is also possible to begin with a total effort level < 1 or > 1, as a function of the inherent capability of the child, since individuals across ethnicities or country types may have different total effort levels. This in turn is a function of the existing conditions (including infrastructure, access to public goods, average aCY Y + aCZ Z = C (7) a KX X + a KZ Z = K (8) aTY Y = T (9) Given world prices of traded goods and w , from (3) we determine, R*. Substituting R* in equation (5) we obtain w* = w(γ L ) and substituting w* in (4) we determine τ * = τ (γ L ) , given international prices and the aij ’s. Clearly, determinate solutions of the above variables require determination of equilibrium γ L . The physical equations, on the other hand, solve in the following manner. From (9), we determine, Y, given total land resources, T . Substituting Y in (6), we solve simultaneously for X and Z from (6) and (8), given exogenous adult labor and capital stocks in the economy. We plough back Y and Z in equation (7) to obtain the demand for child labor in the economy, C as a function of γ L . Also, it displays the normal demand function. Intuitively, as γ L rises child wage rises, and demand for child labor falls. Thus, DC = C (γ L ) DC′ < 0 (10) We further assume that (1 − k ) L share of the total labor force is in the unorganized sector and would therefore be the source of child labor supply. This is explained next. k varies from country to country, but given the world average percentage of labor union affiliation one can safely assume k to be around 10% in most countries. Now in order to determine the equilibrium value of γ , we need to obtain the extent of supply of child labor in the economy. Let the economy, and thus all nutrition levels and health situations, dependence on climatic factors, etc) within the country. However, individuals face two states of nature, good sate with probability α and bad state with probability β , such that, α + β = 1 . Note that, organized workers keep earning w under all states of nature, while unorganized workers are susceptible to wage fluctuations depending on the state of nature prevailing in the economy. The level of unorganized wage in the economy is the prime determinant of the supply of child labor in our study. It is assumed that, w* = w(γ L ) as determined from equation (5) also represents the critical wage facing an unorganized worker. The reason for invoking this assumption will be made clear as we lay out the details of the supply-side of the model. However, we first comment on the potential size of the child labor supply. Since organized workers always earn more than the critical wage, children belonging to these families would not be a potential child labor subject to the state of nature. However, if labor from the organized sector is relocated to the unorganized sector due to effects of structural reform, children belonging to these parents would also add to the potential child labor supply. Before such reallocating effects of reform sets in, the actual number of children who could be potential child labor is obtained in the following manner. The average number of children (from a stock of C ) per adult worker is C / L , of which, (1 − k )C / L would be readily affected by swing in the state of nature. In our model the supply of child labor is determined by parental decision.12 We assume all parents to be equally risk averse distributed uniformly over a range of relative risk aversion and individuals are characterized by a von-Neumann-Morgenstern utility function. The parent (an individual decision-maker representing a household) we restrict our attention to the case of total effort level equal to 1. 12 Children self-selecting themselves either to school or to work is a possibility we bypass. Orphans, for example, if not supported by bequests or by social institutions must engage in labor work for survival. receives utility from sending the child to work and/or to school. The possibility of both school and work for a child is kept alive because there may be a situation when an individual would be indifferent between sending the child either to school or to work or both. More specifically, the individual compares separate utilities from sending the child to school or to work and at the intersection point of the two utility functions we obtain the critical relative risk aversion for the group of individuals. Individuals are so distributed that, those displaying a relative risk aversion greater than the critical level send the children to work, while those falling in the range where individual relative risk aversion is less than the critical level decide to send their children to school. The idea behind such decision-making is simple. It is well documented in the literature that parents send their children to work for smoothing out risk associated with income variability. We offer a point of departure in this context. The ultimate decision to send children to school or work would depend on the level of critical relative risk aversion and the distribution of individuals around that critical point. Put simply, we propose that the decision to send children to work for smoothing out income fluctuations is not universal among all individuals who are subject to wage uncertainties. Instead, it is a function of the distribution of individuals on the scale of relative risk aversion with reference to the critical point. This critical level of relative risk aversion defined in the range [0,1) is obtained next.13 w is the critical wage under steady state general equilibrium facing an unorganized worker (see appendix for an alternative approach for determining supply of 13 However, Kanbur (1982, p. 18) comments that value of relative risk aversion between 1 and 2 seems to be reasonable one to take. We use the measure of relative risk aversion as an analytical tool here and such specifications as r belongs to [0,2) can easily be introduced to check the validity of the model and results. child labor). This is obtained from equation (5) above. wα be the wage, such an worker earns in good state, while he earns wβ in bad state. The two states of nature are results of economic shifts, engendered through economic reforms in the country. It is a simplification that in good state, w jumps to wα and in bad state it falls to wβ . In fact, there can be an infinite number of wage levels between w and wα , and that between w and wβ . At w, an individual is indifferent between sending the child to work or to school.14 The idea is that, as w increases above the critical level, parents decide in favor of sending the children to school. On the other hand, if wage falls below w, children are withdrawn from school and sent to work. Based on this behavior, we conceive of two separate utility functions: one for supporting the household by sending the children to work (USH), and the other for increasing the educational attainment of the household by sending the children to school (UHK). For each case there are two possible outcomes. First, let us consider the case of supporting the household. In good state, which comes with a probability α , the individual does not send the children to work and the household does not gather an extra income from child work. Thus in good state, utility is a function of the difference in wα and w alone. In bad state on the other hand, as adult wage falls below the critical level, children are sent to work and they earn a fraction of 14 In other words, under steady state equilibrium when adult workers earn w, the economy still may have a positive supply of child labor as well as positive number of school goers. However, we are more interested in tracking the changes in the supply of child labor and school attendance that results from introduction of economic reform. the prevailing adult wage, γ L wβ . This is added to the household income in bad state.15 On the basis of the above discussion, we construct a Stone-Geary utility function of the following type. ( wα − w)1− r USH = 1− r ( w − wβ + γ L wβ ) (11) From (10), we obtain the expected utility function for supporting the household. EUSH = α ( wα − w)1− r + β ( w − wβ + γ L wβ )1− r where, (12) δ ( EUSH ) δ 2 ( EUSH ) > 0, < 0 . In other words, EUSH is a concave and wellδr δr 2 behaved function. Second, the flipside of the above situation reveals that, in good state the individual decides in favor of sending the children to school with a view to increase the educational attainment of the children and thus of the household. In good state, this educational attainment enters the utility function of the parent. In bad state, the children are simply withdrawn from school and thus utility becomes a function of w and wβ only. All children are endowed with an innate ability b. Administering individual effort at 15 As noted earlier, any wage level between w and wα , or that between w and wβ may well trigger the decision to send the children to school or work. At precisely what level of income differences such decisions take-off possibly needs to be addressed in an empirical framework. Here it is assumed that ( wα -w) is large enough, so that parents decide against sending the children to work and subsequently make schooling facilities available for them. Conversely, for a large ( wβ -w), parents are hard pressed to withdraw children from school and send them to the labor market. Utility from work and school are, however, accounted for separately in our model. Finally, such households do not have any other source of income or capital assets other than market determined wage earnings. Once again, cost of capital borrowing or returns from land holdings by individuals can be introduced in this framework to provide the general equilibrium structure. We believe, adding other markets would extend the main results of the model without altering any basic findings. school children acquire b(1 + γ S ) level of educational attainment.16 As already mentioned, in bad state such return from schooling is zero, children being withdrawn from school as soon as adult wage drops below the critical level. The Stone-Geary utility function representing these choices is given below. [ wα − w + b(1 + γ S )]1− r UHK = 1− r ( w − wβ ) (13) We denote the expected utility from sending or not sending the children to school by, EUHK = α [ wα − w + b(1 + γ S )]1− r + β ( w − wβ )1− r (14) δ ( EUHK ) δ 2 ( EUHK ) > 0, < 0 depicting a continuous and well-behaved utility Again, δr δr 2 curve. At the point where the curves depicting equations (12) and (14) intersect and using (2), we obtain the critical relative risk aversion of adult individuals ( r* = r * (γ L ) ).17 Algebraically, this is obtained at the point where, α ( wα − w)1− r + β ( w − wβ + γ L wβ )1− r = α [ wα − w + b(1 + γ S )]1− r + β ( w − wβ )1− r One can check for the intercepts of EUSH and EUHK. It can be easily seen that, EUHK r =0 > EUSH αb . < , , iff γ L r =0 βw − αb β (15) Once again, given other parameters, condition (15) sets the upper limit for γ L such that a equilibrium point exists. Determination of unique equilibrium further requires that, 16 This may be considered equivalent to the net present discounted value of return from schooling. We do not explicitly consider the market for education, but this static educational attainment has a market value equivalent at that point in time. Also, schooling is free, so the only cost of schooling is the wage loss and other expenses incurred for supporting the children when in school. We believe that, even if these features are explicitly modeled here, it does not change the basic analysis and results. δ ( EUSH ) δ ( EUHK ) > . δr δr Diagrammatically this is shown in figure (1). Individuals distributed to the left of the critical relative risk aversion ( r* = r * (γ L ), r*′ < 0 , point M) point choose to send their children to school, whereas those distributed to the right send their children to work. EUSH, EUHK EUSH M 0 r* EUHK r Fig (1) Intuitively, r* = r * (γ L ), r*′ < 0 is explained as follows. As γ L increases, child wage increases. Subsequently, expected utility from household support increases and EUSH curve shifts out. This leads to a drop in the level of critical relative risk aversion among individuals. Looked at alternatively, as γ L increases, γ S falls and expected utility from human capital formation falls, such that, EUHK shifts in. As a result, critical relative risk aversion falls with an increase in labor market work effort of the children. The attainment of the critical relative risk aversion, therefore, demarcates individuals distributed with higher relative risk aversion from those distributed with 17 At this stage, we do not rule out possibilities of multiple equilibria. lower relative risk aversion. This further influences the decision to send the children to school or to work. At the critical level, individuals are indifferent between sending the children to school or to work. This determines the number of individuals who send their children to work. For those who are distributed with higher relative risk aversion than the critical level, the decision is to send the children to work for smoothing out risk associated with variance in income. All individuals with relative risk aversion in the range [r*, 1) belong to this decision group. The actual number of such individuals is given by S = (1 − r*)(1 − k ) L (16) Now, as noted earlier, the number of children belonging to the unorganized workers is (1 − k )C / L . Thus, using (16) the number of children who are sent to work is given by, S C = (1 − k ) 2 [1 − r * (γ L )]C , S C′ (γ L ) > 0 as r *′ (γ L ) < 0 (17) S C (γ L ) in equation (17) represents the supply of child labor in the economy. Now, one can straightaway determine the equilibrium value of γ L (= γ L *) by equating (10) and (17), C (γ L ) = (1 − k ) 2 [1 − r * (γ L )]C (18) Once γ L * is known, equilibrium values of other variables are also determined w* = w(γ L *) , τ * = τ (γ L *) . Using these values we obtain the equilibrium child labor wage in the economy, wC * = γ L * w * (19) Comparative static a. Reduction in tariff rate on commodity X, i.e. dt<0. We show that a reduction in the price of X may change the incidence and magnitude of child labor in the economy, through its effects on both demand for and supply of child labor. The effect on demand for child labor is propagated primarily through factor price adjustments in the economy and subsequently through the impact of changing factor-prices on the production of goods and services. The supply effect, on the other hand, operates through shifts in household decisions on labor supply owing to factor-price movements - essentially, wage movements in the economy. Proposition I: Demand for child labor rises while supply of child labor falls with a tariff-cut on of X, if the respective conditions are satisfied : a. Demand condition: λ LX b. λ σ λ λ θ θ σX [θ LX − θ KX (θ LZ + θ CZ )] + Z ( LX KZ LZ KZ − CZ ) < 1 σ Y λ KX λ LY θ TY λ LY σY Supply conditions: For EUSH: − wβ For EUHK: b δγ L δγ > 1 , where, wβ . > w > 0 and L < 0 δw δw δγ S δγ > 1 , where, b>0 and S > 0 δw δw Proof: The detailed mathematical proof of Proposition I is provided in the appendix. Here, we explore intuitively if a tariff cut on the import of X leads to an increased demand for and a decreased supply of child labor. A reduction in tariff lowers R in sector X, along with a reduction in output and employment in sector X. Capital takes a flight to sector Z increasing production, employment and return to adult labor in the economy. If γ L is high in equilibrium, child labor is a close substitute for adult labor and employment of child labor rises. Again, even for a low equilibrium γ L and based on the structure of the industry and technique in production, there may be complementarity between adult and child labor.18 Thus, increasing adult employment also leads to an increase in demand for child labor. However, this does not portray the complete picture of the economy. A reduction in the output in sector X is associated with a drop in production and employment in sector Y, the agricultural commodity, which serves as an intermediate good to the import-competing sector. Thus the overall impact of trade liberalization on employment of child labor becomes a function of condition (a) shown above. One may argue that, with a large agricultural sector and high involvement of child labor in this sector, impact of a downsized food processing industry on negative demand for child labor may not be very deeply entrenched. Increased industrial demand for child labor dominates in the case of a tariff-cut, resulting in a higher overall demand for child labor. The supply of child labor on the other hand changes in the following manner. Note that, change in children’s supply of effort at school or at work is a supply-side phenomenon. We accommodate this feature here, while considering a constant effort level for earlier determination of shifts in demand. As adult wage unambiguously rises, parents prefer to withdraw children from the labor market. Consequently, children’s supply of effort in the labor market falls. In other words δγ L < 0 . Also, as rise in adult δw wage lowers children’s work effort, expected utility of household support through child 18 In fact, we assume fixed technological proportionality or correspondence between adult and child labor in sector Y and Z, whether the factors are substitutes or complements in production. income falls. The curve depicting EUSH shifts in with a rise in adult wage subject to condition (b) stated above. Similarly, as adult wage rises children are sent to school by parental decision. Children’s effort at school rises and households’ expected utility from educational attainment/human capital formation increase. There is an outward shift of EUHK. The adjusted critical relative risk aversion point (where new EUSP and EUHK intersect) locates higher up in the scale of relative risk aversion. Thus, more individuals compared to pre-trade reform situation are now distributed with a lower relative risk aversion than the critical level. This leads to a drop in the supply of child labor from the households. We display this supply-side shock with the help of the following diagram. EUSH, EUHK N M 0 r* r*’ EUSH EUSH’ EUHK’ EUHK r Fig (2) Subject to satisfaction of the conditions as in (b) above, EUSH curve shifts inward to EUSH’, while EUHK shifts outward to EUHK’. Consequently, the critical relative risk aversion point shifts from point M rightward to point N. This is indicative of an increase in the proportion of individuals distributed with a relative risk aversion lower than the critical level. Conversely, the proportion of individuals distributed with a relative risk aversion higher than the critical level falls with these adjustments. Therefore, the supply of child labor decreases as a direct consequence of these movements. Finally, we address the ultimate question that forms an important, if not the sole motivation behind this paper. Whether the size of the child labor force declines in equilibrium depends on the wage elasticity of demand for and supply of child labor. In this particular example, we observe a conditional increase in the demand for child labor. On the other hand, subject to fulfillment of conditions as under proposition I there may be a decrease in the supply of child labor in the economy. Thus the extent and magnitude of child labor in the post-reform economy would depend upon the relative strength of these shifts. b. Imposition of Import Ban on exports that use child labor Suppose the rest of the world imposes an import ban on products made with the use of child labor. In our model commodity Z is such an exportable. This sector is therefore directly affected by the imposition of import ban. If the technology of this sector is such that child labor is an indispensable factor input, then export of Z completely stops. If instead child labor could be substituted by adult labor or some other form of factor input, then the production and export of Z continues. However, sector Z can operate at the world prices due to presence of cost advantage generated from use of child labor. If child labor is replaced by an imperfect substitute, then the cost advantage disappears and the export sector may cease to exist. This is referred to as ‘jump’ and in models of international trade this feature can be quite clearly displayed. The phenomenon of ‘jump’ provides interesting examples of discontinuity in structures of production and exchange equilibrium. Essentially, jumps here show that some sectors may completely cease to exist in the face of structural adjustments.19 Alternatively, in the absence of child labor laws stringently enforced within the domestic economy, the sector may be producing non-traded instead. However, it must produce at the world prices and thus may face insufficient demand within the country to sustain previous production level. Thus in any case, output and employment in sector Z must fall (continuous and interior solution) due to imposition of import ban. In the extreme case (jump and corner solution), sector Z may cease to exist. Therefore, capital must take a flight to sector X, where return to capital R falls. Adult and child labor moves to sector Y. w* = w(γ L ) must also fall, although return to land τ * = τ (γ L ) increases. Let us now check the new demand situation for child labor. As capital moves to sector X, output increases there. Also, since both adult and child labor moves to sector Y, output increases in Y. Thus there are two cross-effects working on the aggregate demand for child labor. There is lower demand as production of Z falls, while an increased demand as production of Y rises. So the net effect on aggregate requirement of child labor C d = C (γ L ) may go either way depending on the relative strength of the production shifts in sectors Y and Z. Next, we investigate the effect of import ban on the supply of child labor. As 19 A similar example can be obtained in Marjit, Kar and Beladi (2003), mimeo, CSSSC, India. modeled above, parental decision to send child to work or school depends on the equilibrium wage rate. A fall in wage shifts the EUSH curve outward. This implies that when adult wage rate falls, at every level of relative risk aversion expected utility of supporting the household is higher than before. On the same note, this shifts the EUHK curve inward. Therefore the critical relative risk aversion point shifts to the left of the previous equilibrium. This increases the supply of child labor in the economy. This brings us to the determination of γ L as in (18). Successive determinations of other variables follow once γ L is obtained in equilibrium. Once again, the size of the child labor force employed in equilibrium depends on the adjusted demand and supply levels in the economy. 4. Conclusions Certain activities of children, usually those of the “helping-hand” variety confined within the immediate family may be normal, but the excessive involvement of children in hired labor segments is long-recognized as a social malaise and generally defined as child labor. It has co-habited with adult labor in nearly all human societies for ages. Globalization, still a relatively recent phenomenon, has added new and complicated, chiefly trade-related economic dimensions, to child labor calling for intervention by national governments and international institutions in this highly informal market. Policies which are the best for the children themselves may be hard to come by, because policymakers are influenced by two completely distinct groups of individuals, voicing from the same platform their concerns about child labor. Admittedly, one of the groups comprises genuine well-wishers of children who do not seem to have any vested interests. The welfare of children, especially of those in other countries, may or may not be of any real concern for the other group, but they certainly have a business interest in talking about child labor. In dealing with child labor, the task of the policymaker is thus not an enviable one. In this paper, we brought together two distinct classes of economic models to understand both the demand as well as the supply forces of child labor, operating in a stylized “globalizing” economy. Changes in the demand for child labor are caused by factor substitution, their reallocation between production sectors and concomitant changes in output levels of each good triggered by trade policies that are commonly associated with globalization. One such policy is tariff-reduction, its positive impact on efficiency well-known and firmly grounded in the theory of international trade. The distributional impact of tariff reduction, that is, its differential effect on various factor prices using child wage, is context specific, depending mainly on factor intensities. In our model, tariff reduction will increase the demand for child labor. The supply of child labor is based on decisions taken by parents characterized by different degrees of riskaversion in an uncertain world. We show that tariff reduction reduces the supply of child labor in our model. These two effects on demand and supply determine both the wage rate as well as the incidence of child labor in the new equilibrium. Whether wages and incidence rise or fall in the new equilibrium, depend on the relative strengths of the two distinct changes. We also discuss another important development associated with globalization, which is the growing use of trade measures to achieve non-trade objectives such as core labor standards, elimination of child labor or the protection of environment. Some countries have decided to impose an import ban on goods that are produced with child labor. We argue that such a policy can actually increase the supply for child workers in the exporting country, which is not what the aforesaid group genuinely concerned with child welfare would want. References Agiobu-Kemmer, I (1992), Child survival and child development in Africa, Bernard van Leer Foundation Studies and Evaluation Papers # 6. The Hague. Baland, J and Robinson, J (2000), Is child labor inefficient, Journal of Political Economy, 108, 663-79. Basu, Kaushik (2000), An intriguing relation between adult minimum wage and child labour, The Economic Journal, C-50, 110, 462. Basu, K and P.H. Van (1998), The economics of child labor, American Economic Review, 88, 412-427. Bekombo, M (1981), The child in Africa: Socialization, education and work, in G Rodgers and G. Standing (eds.) Child work, poverty and underdevelopment, Geneva, ILO. Bonnet, M (1993), Child labour in Africa, International Labour Review, 132, 3. Brown, D.K. (2000), A transaction cost politics analysis of international child labor standards, in A.V. Deardorff and Robert Stern (eds.) Social dimensions of U.S. Trade policies. Ann Arbor: U Michigan Press. Corbin, T (1988), Current trends in youth employment, NY State Department of Labor. Dehejia, R and Gatti, R (2002), Child Labor: The role of income variability and access to credit across countries, NBER Working Paper # 9018. Dixit, A (2000), Comment on “A transaction cost politics analysis of international child labor standards”, in A.V. Deardorff and Robert Stern (eds.) Social dimensions of U.S. Trade policies. Ann Arbor: U Michigan Press. Edmonds, Eric & Pavcnik, Nina (2002), Does globalization increase child labor? Evidence from Vietnam, NBER Working Paper # 8760. Goonesekere, S (1993), Child labour in Sri Lanka: Learning from the past, Geneva, ILO. Grootaert, C and Kanbur, R (1995), Child Labour: An economic perspective, International Labour Review, 134,2, 187-203. Guha-Khasnobis, Basudeb et al (1999), Seen but not heard? Dealing with child labor, Consumer Policy Review, 9, 4. Kanbur, Ravi (1982), Entrepreneurial risk taking, inequality and public policy: An application of inequality decomposition analysis to the general equilibrium effects of progressive taxation, Journal of Political Economy, 90,1, 1-21. Maskus, Keith (1997), Core labor standards: Trade impacts and implications of international trade policy, mimeo, World Bank International Trade Division. Melchior, A (1996), Child labor and trade policy, in Bjorne Grimsrud and A. Melchior (eds.) Child labor and international trade policy, Paris. Mendelievich, Elias (1979), Children at work, Geneva, ILO. Patrinos, H and Psacharopoulos, G (1997), Family size, schooling and child labor in Peru: An empirical Analysis, Journal of Population Economics, 10, 387-405. Ray, Ranjan (2000), Child labor, child schooling and their interaction with adult labor: Empirical evidence from Peru and Pakistan, World Bank Economic Review, 14, 2, 347-67. Ranjan, Priya (1999), An economic analysis of child labor, Economics Letters, 64,1, 99-105. Appendix Proof of Demand-side condition: dt From equation (3) as dt < 0, Rˆ = < 0 . From (5), using equilibrium γ L as given, θ KX such that, wˆ C = wˆ , we substitute R̂ to get (also see fn. 16 and the assumption that sector X requires relatively more capital per unit of labor, compared to commodity Z), wˆ = − θ + θ CY θ KZ θ KZ dt dt > 0 while from (4) τˆ = LY < 0. θ KX (θ LZ + θ CZ ) θ TY θ KX θ LZ + θ CZ Now, we obtain the changes in the output and employment in various sectors. From (9) Yˆ = −aˆ TY = −σ Y θ LY ( wˆ − τˆ) < 0 and LˆY = aˆ LY + Yˆ = aˆ LY − aˆ TY = −σ Y θ LY ( wˆ − τˆ) < 0 . On the other hand from (6) and (8), we get the respective changes, λ LX Xˆ + λ LZ Zˆ = −λ LX aˆ LX − λ LZ aˆ LZ − λ LY LˆY = M > 0 , (A.1) λ KX Xˆ + λ KZ Zˆ = −λ KX aˆ KX − λ KZ aˆ KZ = N < 0 (A.2) Substituting for aˆ ij , LˆY in (A.1) and (A.2), we get M >0 and N <0. We use Cramer’s rule to solve for Xˆ , Yˆ . λ LX λ KX λ LZ Xˆ M = λ KZ Zˆ N (A.3) We define ∆ = λ LX λ KZ − λ LZ λ KX < 0 , such that, λ M − λ LZ N λ N − λ KX M < 0 and Zˆ = LX > 0. Xˆ = KZ ∆ ∆ Also, equation (7) is rewritten as λCY (aˆ CY + Yˆ ) + λCZ (aˆ CZ + Zˆ ) = Cˆ (A.4) Substituting Yˆ , Zˆ in (A.4), and using the assumption that use of child labor in sector Y and Z do not undergo any technological change following factor-price changes, we obtain the change in the requirement of child labor in the economy. λ N − λ KX M . Thus with aˆ CY = 0 = aˆ CZ , Cˆ = −λCY σ Y θ LY ( wˆ − τˆ) + λCZ LX ∆ This with suitable manipulations is reduced to the form of λ LX λ σX σ λ λ θ θ [θ LX − θ KX (θ LZ + θ CZ )] + Z ( LX KZ LZ KZ − CZ ) < 1 σY σ Y λ KX λ LY θ TY λ LY (A.5) QED. Proof of supply-side conditions: From (12) δγ L δ ( EUSH ) = −α (1 − r )( wα − w) − r + β (1 − r )( wβ − w + γ L wβ ) − r (1 + wβ ) δw δw (A.6) such that for δγ δ ( EUSH ) < 0, it suffices to have (− wβ L > 1) , where, δw δw wβ . > w > 0 and δγ L < 0. δw Similarly from (14) δγ δ ( EUHK ) = α (1 − r )[ wα − w + b(1 + γ S )]− r (−1 + b S ) + β (1 − r )( w − wβ ) − r δw δw Once again, for QED. (A.7). δγ δγ δ ( EUHK ) > 0 , it suffices to have (b S > 1) , where, b>0 and S > 0 . δw δw δw