INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE OF FISHERIES ECONOMICS AND TRADE CONFERENCE 2014 Considering the Costs of Enforcement: Improving Marine Spatial Planning Katrina Davis David Pannell, Marit Kragt, Stefan Gelcich, & Steven Schilizzi Restricted-use management zones • No-take • Use rights Spatial optimisation • Terrestrial − National parks • Marine − Minimize losses to fishers The University of Western Australia Aim • Determine impact of including management and opportunity costs on spatially optimal marine zoning Management costs = costs of preventing poaching and enforcing catch restrictions, i.e. enforcement costs The University of Western Australia Chile Chile • 1989-1991 Fisheries law • 4,200 km of coastline − Territorial user rights for • Rich marine resources fisheries • One of top 10 countries for fisheries landings The University of Western Australia Central marine region of Chile Management zones Open access TURF Enforced-TURF No-take Enforced no-take Algarrobo The University of Western Australia Enforcement costs Deterring poachers and enforcing catch restrictions: − Costs vary spatially El Quisco A El Quisco B The University of Western Australia Spatial optimisation model • Allocate cells (Ci=1,..,96) to management zones Open access, TURF, Enforced-TURF, No-take, Enforced-no-take • Objective: Maximize fisher revenue from fish caught RevenueCi = (Number of fish which can be caught x Price) – Enforcement costs • Subject to minimum abundance targets The University of Western Australia Abundance targets • Targets based on maximum potential abundance The University of Western Australia Spatial optimisation model • Multiple scenarios – impact of enforcement • No enforcement: A → O, T, N • Enforcement, no cost: B → O, T, ET, N, EN • Enforcement, cost: C → O, T, ET, N, EN → $$ The University of Western Australia Results - Fisher revenue Benefits of enforcement = Revenue scenario B (Enforcement, no cost) - Revenue scenario A (No enforcement) Revenue (US$1,000) 1,200 Benefits 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 0% 4% 8% 12% Abundance target The University of Western Australia Fisher revenue Costs of enforcement = Revenue scenario B (Enforcement, no cost) - Revenue scenario C (Enforcement and cost) Revenue (US$1,000) 1,200 Benefits 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 0% 4% 8% 12% Abundance target The University of Western Australia Fisher revenue Costs of enforcement = Revenue scenario B (Enforcement, no cost) - Revenue scenario C (Enforcement and cost) Revenue (US$1,000) 1,200 Benefits Costs 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 0% 4% 8% 12% Abundance target The University of Western Australia Fisher revenue 1. Enforcement costs negligible compared to benefits 2. Benefit Cost Ratios (BCRs) > 1 Revenue (US$1,000) 1,200 Benefits Costs 1,000 BCR: 7 800 600 BCR: 9 BCR: 5 BCR: 5 400 200 0 0% 4% 8% 12% Abundance target The University of Western Australia Optimal spatial allocation – scenario C Abundance target: 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% The University of Western Australia Sensitivity analysis - Enforcement costs Allocation of study area % 100 90 80 70 60 100 50 90 40 80 30 70 20 60 10 50 0 Base case 5 Enforced-TURF Open access BCR 3 1 40 4 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 30 11 2 20 10 Scenario C, no abundance target 0 1 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 1 11 The University of Western Australia Sensitivity analysis - Enforcement costs Allocation of study area % 100 90 80 70 60 100 50 90 40 80 30 70 20 60 10 50 0 Base case 5 Enforced-TURF Open access BCR 3 1 40 4 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 30 11 2 20 10 Scenario C, no abundance target 0 1 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 1 11 The University of Western Australia Sensitivity analysis - Enforcement costs Allocation of study area % BCR 100 5 90 80 4 70 60 100 50 90 40 80 30 70 20 60 10 50 0 Base case Enforced-TURF 3 4 2 Open access BCR 1 3 1 40 5 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 30 11 2 20 10 Scenario C, no abundance target 0 1 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 1 11 The University of Western Australia Sensitivity analysis - Enforcement costs Allocation of study area % BCR 100 5 90 80 4 70 60 Base case 50 3 40 30 20 10 Enforced-TURF 2 Open access BCR 0 1 1 2 3 Enforcement cost multiplier 11 Scenario C, no abundance target The University of Western Australia Net benefits from enforcement • Enforcement of TURF zones has net benefits for fisher revenue • Mixture of enforced TURF and no-take zones was optimal for conservation The University of Western Australia Why are fishers not enforcing? • Fishers in the study area don’t enforce TURFs that are far away − Fishers may under-estimate the benefits of enforcement − Fisher associations may lack capacity or authority − Other biological forces at work − Transaction costs of enforcement may be higher than we have modelled Currently investigating this further The University of Western Australia Accounting for enforcement can improve marine management 1. Large benefits from enforcement, negligible costs 2. Costs have a spatial component and can be minimized Davis, K. J., M. E. Kragt, S. Gelcich, S. Schilizzi, and D. J. Pannell. In press. Accounting for enforcement costs in the spatial allocation of marine zones, Conservation Biology. katrina.davis@research.uwa.edu.au, School of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Western Australia The University of Western Australia