Midterm Answer Key Economics 435: Quantitative Methods Fall 2011 1 Warmup a) Yes. A proof is not required, but here it is: ! n 1X xi E(x̄n ) = E n i=1 n = 1X E (xi ) n i=1 n = = = = b) As usual, var(x̄n ) = σ2 n . 1X (µE I (i is even) + µO I (i is odd)) n i=1 ! ! n n 1X 1X µE I (i is even) + µO I (i is odd) n i=1 n i=1 1n 1n µE + µO n2 n2 µE + µO 2 A proof is not required, but here it is. First, note that since the observations 1 ECON 435, Fall 2011 2 are independent cov(xi , xj ) = 0 for all i 6= j. Then: n var (x̄n ) = = = = = = = 1X xi n i=1 var ! ! n X 1 var xi n2 i=1 n n 1 X X cov(xi , xj ) n2 i=1 j=1 ! n 1 X var(xi ) n2 i=1 ! n 1 X 2 σ n2 i=1 1 nσ 2 n2 σ2 n c) Yes. A proof is not required, but here it is. Let yj = x2j−1 +x2j 2 and let N = n/2. Then: n x̄n = 1X xi n i=1 = N 1 X x2j−1 + x2j 2N j=1 = N 1 X 2yj 2N j=1 = N 1 X yj N j=1 = ȳN Now, since the x’s are independent, so are the y’s. In addition, the y’s are identically distributed: y ∼ 2 N (θ, σ2 ). Therefore we have a random sample of size N on y and can apply the law of large numbers to say that ȳN →p θ. Since x̄n = ȳN , this implies x̄n →p θ as well. ECON 435, Fall 2011 2 3 The Mincer human capital model a) We use our standard procedure plim β̂1 = = = = = = = = = cov(LN ˆ W AGE, EDU C) (usual OLS formula) var(EDU ˆ C) plim cov(LN ˆ W AGE, EDU C) (by Slutsky) plim var(EDU ˆ C) cov(LN W AGE, EDU C) var(EDU C) cov(β0 + β1 EDU C + β2 EXP ER + u, EDU C) (by substitution) var(EDU C) cov(EXP ER, EDU C) β1 + β2 var(EDU C) cov(AGE − EDU C − 6, EDU C) β1 + β2 var(EDU C) cov(AGE, EDU C) − var(EDU C) β1 + β2 var(EDU C) −var(EDU C) β1 + β2 (since cov(AGE, EDU C) = 0) var(EDU C) β1 − β2 plim b) We can substitute (AGE − EDU C − 6) for EXP ER in the original model and get: LN W AGEi = β0 + β1 EDU Ci + β2 EXP ERi + ui = β0 + β1 EDU Ci + β2 (AGEi − EDU Ci − 6) + ui = (β0 − 6β2 ) + (β1 − β2 )EDU Ci + β2 AGEi + ui Since E(u|EDU C, AGE) = 0: plim β̂1 = β1 − β2 c) The coefficient β̂1 (and thus its probability limit) doesn’t even exist, because the explanatory variables in this regression are perfectly collinear (EXP ER is an exact linear function of EDU C and AGE). d) These regressions would tend to underestimate β1 . 3 Vector autoregressions a) First we substitute to get: mt = b0 yt + b1 yt−1 + b2 mt−1 + vt = b0 (a1 yt−1 + a2 mt−1 + ut ) + b1 yt−1 + b2 mt−1 + vt = (b0 a1 + b1 )yt−1 + (b0 a2 + b2 )mt−1 + (b0 ut + vt ) = π1 yt−1 + π2 mt−1 + t ECON 435, Fall 2011 4 Then we note that: E(t |yt−1 , mt−1 ) = E(b0 ut + vt |yt−1 , mt−1 ) = b0 E(ut |yt−1 , mt−1 ) + E(vt |yt−1 , mt−1 ) = b0 0 + 0 = 0 b) σu = cov(ut , t ) = cov(ut , b0 ut + vt ) = b0 cov(ut , ut ) + cov(ut , vt ) = b0 σu2 + 0 = b0 σu2 c) Note that: b1 σu σu2 = π1 − b0 a1 b2 = π2 − b0 a2 b0 = So applying the analog principle produces the estimators σ̂u σ̂u2 b̂0 = b̂1 = π̂1 − b̂2 σ̂u â1 σ̂u2 σ̂u = π̂2 − 2 â2 σ̂u ECON 435, Fall 2011 5 d) plim b̂0 plim b̂1 σ̂u σ̂u2 plim σ̂u = (Slutsky) plim σ̂u2 σu = (given) σu2 b0 σu2 = (previously shown) σu2 = b0 σ̂u = plim π̂1 − 2 â1 σ̂u σ̂u (Slutsky) = plim π̂1 − plim 2 plim â1 σ̂u σ̂u = π1 − plim 2 a1 (given) σ̂u = π1 − b0 a1 (previously shown) = plim = (b0 a1 + b1 ) − b0 a1 = b1 σu = plim π̂2 − 2 â2 σu σ̂u (Slutsky) = plim π̂2 − plim 2 plim â2 σ̂u = π2 − b0 a2 (given/previously shown) plim b̂2 = (b0 a2 + b2 ) − b0 a2 = b2