Copyright & endogenous market structure: A glimpse from the journal-publishing market

advertisement
ISSN: 2038-7296
POLIS Working Papers
[Online]
Dipartimento di Politiche Pubbliche e Scelte Collettive – POLIS
Department of Public Policy and Public Choice – POLIS
Working paper n. 169
September 2010
Copyright & endogenous market structure:
A glimpse from the journal-publishing market
Giovanni B. Ramello
UNIVERSITA’ DEL PIEMONTE ORIENTALE “Amedeo Avogadro” ALESSANDRIA
Periodico mensile on-line "POLIS Working Papers" - Iscrizione n.591 del 12/05/2006 - Tribunale di Alessandria
Copyright & Endogenous Market Structure:
a Glimpse from the Journal-Publishing Market1
Giovanni B. Ramello
Department of Public Policy & Public Choice, POLIS
Università del Piemonte Orientale
ABSTRACT: This article explores the journal publishing industry in order to shed light on the overall economic
consequences of copyright in markets. Since the rationale for copyright is among others to promise some market power
to the holder of the successful copyrighted item, it also provides incentives to preserve and extend market power. A
regular trait of copyright industries is high concentration and the creation of large catalogues of copyrights in the hands
of incumbents. This outcome can be observed as the aggregation of rights and is one of the pivotal strategies for
obtaining or extending market power, consistently with findings in other cases. Journal publishing is no different in this
respect from other copyright industries, and in the last decade has experienced a similar trajectory, leading to a highly
concentrated industry in which a handful of large firms increasingly control a substantial part of the market.
It also provides a clear example of the effect of copyright dynamics on market structure, suggesting that a different
attitude should be taken in lawmaking and law enforcement.
Keywords: copyright and market power, endogenous market structure, journal-publishing industry
JEL codes: D40, O34, O33, L12, L69
1. Introduction
The economic research on copyright issues in recent times has been intense, boosted by copyrighted
products’ greater weight in the markets and by the higher chance of infringement brought about by
ICT and digital technologies2. However, most of the contributions so far have treated the legal
regime governing the “market for the expression of ideas” as a sort of exogenous factor that simply
1
The author is greatly indebted to Piero Cavaleri, Michael Keren, Francesco Silva and Vittorio Valli for drawing their
attention to the scientific publishing market and raising some of the key questions, to participants to UC Berkeley Serci
conference and to Matteo Migheli for research assistance. This work is part of the CRT-Alfieri study on the law and
economics of scientific and academic publishing. The usual disclaimer applies.
2
The birth in 2004 of this journal focusing exclusively on the economics of copyright is a clear example of the
relevance of the topic in academic debate.
1
characterizes the property framework needed to make trade possible and provides some incentive to
the owner for creating and circulating new bits of knowledge3.
Still, if one tries to observe the real economic life of copyright within markets, another
interesting feature emerges: copyright plays a pivotal role in endogenously shaping the market
structure as it provides a number of economic incentives far exceeding the simple reward for
creative activities.
Very often, the outcome of these forces is a drift toward industry concentration and a
lessening of competition with an impact on efficiency. Another feature is the industry’s recurring
split into two distinct segments: one in which incumbents with large market shares enjoy substantial
market power by controlling large catalogues of copyrighted items, and one to which the other firms
are relegated and left exposed to competitive pressure. Substantial entry barriers prevent movement
from the latter to the former, thus preserving the persistence of market power.
From this viewpoint, the journal publishing industry investigated in this article can be seen as
a descriptive example of the evolutionary trajectory of copyright industries. Over the centuries, and
with a substantial acceleration in recent decades, the original goal of fostering creativity—shared
equally by copyright and scientific journals—has been taken over by rent-seeking behaviors largely
aimed at creating and preserving market power.
The likely consequence in this domain affects the circulation and accessibility of scientific
knowledge and research. This concern, already experienced to some degree as various research
libraries find themselves unable to afford the same variety of titles because of increased
subscription rates, has raised the alarm of scholars and research institutions that seriously fear how
the industry’s current organization will affect their core activity. Some action has been taken
accordingly, although the outcome is still uncertain.
Aside from the specific issue of science, these remarks suggest that we pay closer attention to
the endogenous effects of copyright on market structure and the production of knowledge, which is
by nature a cumulative process requiring broad access to previously created ideas. Proper
consideration of these aspects might provide important policy guidelines to lawmakers.
This article is organized as follows: Section 2 presents an overview of the current trend in
journal publishing, while Section 3 traces the main characteristics of copyright and scientific
journals and emphasizes their common features. Section 4 describes the progressive transformation
of the industry; Section 5 provides further insights into the endogenous role of copyright in shaping
the market, including with reference to economics journals. Section 6 summarizes and comments on
the main findings, and Section 7 concludes.
2. Background
The scientific debate on the economics of scholarly publishing recently gained momentum due to
the remarkable increase in prices experienced in the last two decades. According to the Association
of Research Libraries (ARL), a non-profit organization of 125 research libraries in North America
including many academic libraries4, between 1986 and 2004 the expenditure for serials rose by
more than 273% and the average price of a serial by more than 188%, compared with a 73%
increase in the consumer price index (CPI; see Figure 1). These statistics are merely averages; the
figures become even more dramatic—in excess of +600%5—for selected fields of research.
3
Most of the debate has been focused on the creation incentive provided by copyright and on whether copyright
infringement reduces profits and social welfare. For a broad survey on the economics of copyright law see Towse,
Handke & Stepan (2008).
4
Ref. http://www.arl.org/
5
Edlin & Rubinfeld (2004) report that between 1984 and 2001, the price of physics and chemistry journal subscriptions
rose by 615% .
2
Technological changes cannot be the main reason for the dramatic increase, as they equally
concerned the publication of books, whose average price rose by just 63% (less than the CPI, thus
implying some reduction from technological change, as expected); while total expenditure rose by
just 77% (pratically mirroring the CPI trend).
While the data above concern the US market, a similar trend took place throughout the world
(Dewatripoint et al., 2006) to the bane of libraries, whose budgets were crushed by the effort to
maintain the same assortment of journals essentially at the expense of books and other items (Parks,
2001; McCabe, 2002). Since then, the situation has become even more dramatic as budget cuts at
academic institutions in many countries have made it difficult to maintain expenditure.
Figure 1: Book and Serial Expenditures in ARL Libraries, 1986-2004
Source: ARL Statistics 2003-04, Association of Research Libraries, Washington, D.C.
On the other side of the market, the buyers—mainly scholars and research institutions by
means of libraries, who are also the main providers of input for scholarly publications—have
reacted severely and sometimes tried to fight back. A number of scientific associations and their
members have simply distanced themselves from publishers in order to stop legitimizing their
commercial conduct; in some cases they have launched competing publications.
In December 2006 the editors of the Journal of Topology, an international journal of
mathematics founded in the late 1950s, resigned from their positions in reaction to the new
publisher’s pricing policies, claiming that these would “[have] a significant and damaging effect on
Topology’s reputation in the mathematical research community”6.
A comparable position has been endorsed by the European Economic Association, which in
2002 decided to found a completely new organ, the Journal of the European Economic Association,
after having invested 23 years in building up the European Economic Review (EER) that was
6
Letter by the editors of Topology, August 10, 2006.
3
published commercially. However, it is interesting to note that despite this divorce (which is also
scientific as the board and editors resigned), the EER, through inertia, still enjoys a significant
reputation that is keeping it safely near the top of the ISI ranking7.
In other cases, well known research institutions have taken a clear position against this state of
affairs: the Senate of Stanford University, for instance, expressly lamented that many journals were
becoming “disproportionately expensive compared to their educational and research value” and
suggested that researchers “not … contribute articles or editorial or review efforts to publishers and
journals that engage in exploitive or exorbitant pricing”8. Similar positions have been taken by other
major US educational institutions, sometime fostering the countervailing publication of new
journals. That has been the aim of Berkeley Electronic (BE) Press, founded in 1999 by Berkeley
professors and intended, as stated on its website 9, to publish high quality peer-reviewed journals “at
sustainable prices” (very often free after registration to individual readers) and provide technologies
“to help the academic community produce, archive and disseminate scholarly work.”
A similar aspiration drives the Public Library of Science (PLoS), a project run by a non-profit
organization of scientists and physicians “committed to making the world's scientific and medical
literature a freely available public resource” that has so far published seven Open Access (OA) (i.e.
not for payment) journals10. In other fields such as economics, a number of selective journals have
been launched with the cooperation of scientific associations. Two examples are the European
Journal of Comparative Economics, published on behalf of the European Association for
Comparative Economics Studies, and this journal, which is managed by the Society for Economics
Research on Copyright Issues11.
The Open Access philosophy has also been fully endorsed by one of the most distinguished
research institutions in the US: the National Institutes of Health (NIH). Since December 2007,
according to the “NIH mandate” signed by President Bush, that institution has “require[d] that all
investigators funded by the NIH submit or have submitted for them to the National Library of
Medicine's PubMed Central an electronic version of their final, peer-reviewed manuscripts upon
acceptance for publication, to be made publicly available no later than 12 months after the official
date of publication: Provided, That the NIH shall implement the public access policy in a manner
consistent with copyright law”12.
However, these feeble attempts at countermeasures have so far failed to change the overall
state of affairs, whose inefficiencies are clear. First, research institutes in general and universities in
particular are spending significant resources to buy the intellectual output of their own
uncompensated researchers. By leading to a wasteful duplication of costs, this increases the cost of
research.
Next, because ICT allows the cheaper production and delivery of research results, the price
increase is based on market power. Since a substantial part of the costs per subscriber is fixed, the
concurrent increase in potential demand would have permitted a reduction in prices had the market
been competitive. As we have understood since Arrow (1962), the increase in the cost of access to
knowledge has a serious negative effect on downstream creative activities (Ramello, 2005a).
Furthermore, while in the past the market power enjoyed by the publisher was significantly
attenuated by provisos such as the “fair dealing” exceptions of copyright law, which essentially
provided a spill-over space of knowledge for non-paying users (Royal Society, 2003), these are no
7
This explanation is available at http://www.eeassoc.org/index.php?page=14
Available at http://facultysenate.stanford.edu/2003_2004/reports/SenD5540_serials_crisis.pdf
9
http://www.bepress.com/
10
http://www.plos.org/ The PLoS mission of building a public library of science includes “not only providing
unrestricted access to scientific research ideas and discoveries, but developing tools and materials to engage the interest
and imagination of the public and helping non-scientists to understand and enjoy scientific discoveries and the scientific
process.”
11
The former is available at http://eaces.liuc.it and the latter at http://www.serci.org .
12
Ref. http://www.nih.gov/
8
4
longer effective in the digital domain. And advances in ICT, which are reducing the cost of
disseminating information, seem paradoxically to be strengthening the hands of the oligopolists and
leading to price increases.
3. Copyright and the journal-publishing market
Scientific journals and copyright have something in common: both are aimed at fostering the
production and circulation of new knowledge. Journals provide authors with a powerful means of
diffusing a newly created expression of ideas, which potentially extends their reputation as scholars.
Indeed, publication allows the scientific work to be circulated much more widely than it could be in
person, while enhancing the author’s reputation by certifying the quality of the work through the
process of publication itself, which is very often dependent on peer review (Boyer, 1947; Johns,
2000). On the whole, it supplies an indirect economic incentive as far as reputation can be
converted into career advances, research grants and other concrete pecuniary benefits13.
Copyright, according to a standard justification, should do the same by giving authors the
chance to reap the benefits of newly created copyrightable works. At the same time, it solves the
puzzle of providing private incentive to invest in creative activities and of serving the public interest
by promoting advances in knowledge (Ramello, 2005a; Rothen & Powel, 2007; Towse, Handke &
Stepan, 2008).
Copyright and scientific journals appeared at nearly the same time, the late 17th and early 18th
century, when European society was entering an intense period of transformation: the
Enlightenment, which increasingly recognized the importance of authorial and inventive activity. At
first, however, they bore little relation to one another, and the first two scholarly journals had a
somewhat problematic relationship with copyright and its ancestors.
In France, the first scholarly publication was the Journal des Sçavans (later renamed Journal
de Savants), which appeared in Paris on January 5, 1665 thanks to the considerable effort of the
politician and learned man Denis De Sallo; it would soon become the focal point of national
scientific and literary society (Boyer, 1947). It is also familiar to modern economists as it is there
that Joseph Louis François Bertrand published his famous critique of the Cournot oligopoly in
1883.
It is worth noting that the popularity of this journal owed much to the flourishing number of
pirated copies that were widely distributed in France, openly infringing the printing privilegii
granted by the state which were the ancestors of droit d’auteur.
In England, the publication of the Philosophical Transactions by the Royal Society of London
in 1665 was crucial to disseminating the work of many scholars, including Newton, Boyle, Leibniz,
Cassini and Halley. In this case too, the venture was possible thanks to a royal exemption from the
charter granted in 1557 by Philip and Mary Tudor to the Stationers Company, which for nearly 150
years gave it a heavily criticized monopoly on printing and publishing in England (Johns, 2000;
Nicita & Ramello, 2007).
For a long time thereafter, the relationship between copyright and scientific journals was
merely occasional; because many of the earliest journal publishers were learned societies and then
academic institutions, copyright was licensed explicitly or implicitly to them, though it did not have
a central role in the business. Nonetheless, this was the foundation of the model on which academic
journals were later organized: the publisher acquires copyright over published papers, and in
exchange invests the crucial resources in manuscript revision and formatting and in the printing and
delivery of physical issues (Page, Campbell & Meadows, 1996).
13
As we will discuss later on, reputation is a pivotal element of scientific publication for journals as well.
5
4. The transformation of the journal-publishing industry: key elements
As mentioned above, in the beginning these publishers were often scientific associations or
universities. But this has been changing: commercial publishers have increasingly been entering the
market by introducing new journals, at times on behalf of scientific associations or individual
scholars, at times by acquiring existing titles. Over the years these dynamics have led to a
significant concentration in the academic publishing industry, in line with what has happened in
other copyright industries (Silva & Ramello, 2000; McCabe, 2002; Edlin & Rubinfeld, 2004; Nicita
& Ramello, 2007; Ramello & Silva, 2008). As we have seen, the result of increasing concentration
has been price growth far exceeding the rate of inflation and a substantial rise in costs.
To make matters worse, several commercial players have now adopted strategies of multi-part
tariff pricing and bundling of the titles they own in all disciplines in an attempt to extract much of
the buyers' surplus (OFT, 2002; Edlin & Rubinfeld, 2004). In general the fixed part, that plays the
role of an admission fee, equals the cost of the printed items bought in previous years, while the
variable part consists of the subscription to an online database, which is the preferred resource for
many researchers. If an institution decides to unsubscribe from a number of printed journals, thus
reducing the admission fee, a balancing mechanism has been set up that increases the variable part,
thus preserving the total cost (Dewatripont et al., 2006). As an example, consider the case of an
Italian middle sized university facing a large European publisher that has announced an increase in
subscription rates for the three years 2009-2012 by about 20% for the “admission fee” (just over 6%
annually) and by nearly 66% for the variable part, i.e., by over 17%, or one sixth per annum. This
strategy is hard to counter, as the variable part of the tariff is less constrained and introduces a
higher degree of uncertainty about the total future fee. Additionally, while bundling essentially
provides a means of discriminating that raises producer profits and sometimes the social welfare, in
the specific case of journal publishing—where some titles are subject to market power, as we shall
see below—it offers incumbents a device for foreclosing the market to small players and
newcomers.
Moreover, the slight though steady shift from the purchase of printed journals to admittance to
databases is also transforming the accessibility of the resources in an intertemporal perspective.
While printed journals, once acquired, become an asset that can be used in the future, access to a
database is given only for the duration of the contract and hence introduces a higher uncertainty for
the future, giving more power to the seller who has control over a broader catalogue of input.
The current state of affairs is leading to serious problems of access to research input by the
scientific community, increasing concern for the future while already posing obstacles to the less
affluent parts of the scientific community, particularly in low-income countries but also in the
developed world (Nevo, Rubinfeld & McCabe, 2005). The publishers’ strategies are presenting
universities and research institutions with a difficult choice as to how to allocate their funds, at the
very time when budgets are getting tighter (Parks, 2001). Last but not least, since publishers depend
on the availability and exclusive control of copyright, they are somewhat contradicting the aim of
fostering the production and diffusion of new knowledge.
Another feature that strengthens the market power of incumbents is the journal’s reputation,
which is a central element for attracting both authors and readers.
Journals are often ranked, and their ranking is roughly determined by the numbers of readers
and citations. To attract good submissions a journal needs to build a reputation, a readership that
will, at the least, browse its contents and read the relevant articles. Yet readers will spend time
perusing a journal only if they are assured that they may find in it material that is worth their time.
This is a chicken-egg problem: good papers raise the interest of readers, but they will not be
submitted to a publication that fails to attract readers’ interest (Spier, 2002; Cavaleri et al., 2009)14.
14
Reputation here is the pivotal element of differentiation and hence market power. However, “this reputation is much
more complex in its formation than the reputation of most branded products, such as a Mercedes automobile, and it is
6
The audience of an academic journal, the set of its potential readers, is only indirectly affected
by its price, which is usually borne by the library. These readers' time is a highly constrained
resource and the time and attention they can allocate to scientific literature is limited. Most
researchers read only the top journals in their wider field, plus a selected range of the journals in
their area of specialization. Consequently, the top journals and a few specialized ones get most
citations. This contributes to the stickiness of journal rankings, be they based on the ISI Thomson
impact factor or an alternative database15. Along with the concentration of publishers described
above, this feedback increases the market power of the main publishing houses.
Thus the opportunity cost of reading a given journal, and indirectly that of submitting to it, is
primarily composed of the costs of time and only partly of the pecuniary expense usually borne by
the institutions. When it comes to submission, the “publish or perish” rule leads researchers to send
their work to the most visible and high-reputation journals (Spier, 2002). This raises the importance
of quality as the almost exclusive consideration for reading a journal, and if the quality of a journal
is not perceived as comparable to the best, only those who are unable to access the paying ones will
choose to read (and indirectly—to submit to) it 16. A journal may in this manner be turned into an
Akerlof (1970) “lemon.”
Technological advancement could partially solve this puzzle in the form of electronic
publishing, which essentially provides ease of entry for newcomers and broad distribution,
especially when following the Open Access (OA) model (Rothen & Powell, 2007). However, the
conundrum of reputation it is not easy to solve because a new journal, even if free on the web (zero
price), is not assured of a readership and most assuredly not of worthwhile submissions due to the
lack of information about quality. That’s why many of the new OA (or quasi OA) journals have
tried to provide additional devices, for instance by heavily exploiting the link with complementary
reputation signals such as being published by a well-known institution—as in the case of Berkeley
Electronic Press—or a scientific society as in the case of PloS, the European Journal of
Comparative Economics (linked with the European Society for Comparative Economics Studies)
and RERCI (the organ of the Society for Economic Research on Copyright Issues) (Cavaleri et al.,
2009).
Another way to try to draw more attention is to become part of a bundle, so that some
economies of scale in attracting readers’ and submitters’ interest can be generated by the existence
of a critical mass of journals 17. Even better, the new journal can “borrow” the reputation of other
publications that are part of the bundle, mimicking what the marketing industry terms “brand
extension” and “brand stretching”18.
In all, while the convenience of being available on the web may be to a journal’s advantage, it
cannot in itself ensure the journal’s success. The technical feasibility of starting an e-journal,
although much easier than a traditional print journal, does not translate into a positive outcome in
terms of attracting authors and readers.
hard to reproduce […and w]hat makes a journal valuable is the simultaneous consensus of authors, reviewers, editors,
libraries, readers, tenure committees and indexing services […]” (Edlin & Rubinfled, 2004).
15
While ISI impact factor is still a well recognized reference, other systems are contending for the role
(http://www.isiwebofknowledge.com/). For instance, in economics REPEC provides a different kind of impact factor
calculated on its own databases (www.repec.org), the ranking of US law journals provided by the School of Law of
Washington and Lee University (available at http://lawlib.wlu.edu/LJ/index.aspx), and the H index (ref.
http://www.harzing.com/pop.htm) has recently been devised to rank scholars and journals. National research evaluation
agencies have also released their own rankings; e.g. in France the Agence pour l’Evaluation de la Recherche et de
l’Einsegnement Supérieur (AERES; http://www.aeres-evaluation.fr/) provides a national ranking of journals to
researchers.
16
Parks (2001) provides a compelling analysis of the motives of the various actors in this market.
17
This strategy has been followed by BE Press and PloS but also by the American Economic Association, which has
launched a number of new journals together.
18
Both techniques are intended to shift the incremental utility (goodwill) produced by a brand from the original market
to a different one.
7
5. Copyright and the endogenous market structure: a view from economics journals
The two pivotal features of modern copyright industries are the poor substitutability of the
copyrighted item, and the excludability enforced by copyright, which enables the holder to demand
a price for access.
Poor substitutability relates to the uniqueness of the information good—the lower the
substitutability, the higher the potential value to the consumer—and accordingly makes sense of
having copyright19.
It is important to note that this aspect figures more prominently in the articles of scientific
journals than in other information goods. Since research is an incremental activity based on
previously created knowledge, follow-on researchers rely heavily and unavoidably on earlier
contributions, to the point that their own advances must necessarily start from the “prior art” and in
the absence of it any serious further “advance,” as the term itself suggests, will be prevented 20. In
this respect, access to previous research is crucial, especially when this work has been published in
a well known journal that makes it an essential reference to scholars. In general, we can say that
researchers’ demand for articles and journals is somewhat inelastic and allows the publisher to
enjoy a strong monopoly.
This rigidity is somewhat attenuated for the real buyers—i.e the libraries—that act upstream
from researchers, and should therefore maximize the utility of a number of researchers subject to
budget constraints (McCabe, 2002; Parks 2001).
The legal excludability provided by copyright aims to give the first owner the possibility to
exact a price for accessing the newly created work (Ramello & Silva, 2008). Of course, the outcome
of this is to ration demand and accordingly to reduce access to essential inputs for follow-on
creators, thus producing an adverse effect on the incremental development of knowledge. Because
the consequences are more severe as the price increases, the actual amount of the price is really the
crucial matter. If the price approaches the average cost, the exclusion will be kept as low as possible
and in turn the negative consequences on incremental knowledge will be minimal (Ramello, 2005a
& 2008).
This will be a maximizing strategy from the social perspective, while the individual incentive
of the right holder diverges because the more rewarding choice will be the proper exploitation of the
price-cost differential, possibly as a monopoly. This is affordable when the license to the right is
exclusive, which explains why nowadays exclusivity has been extensively interpreted as a value per
se and has been widely enforced in the resale to downstream markets, such for instance in
publishing. The exclusivity clause potentially gives the licensee the chance to be a monopolist; in
turn, the right owner in most cases bids for the license according to an exclusivity regime for
extracting the reservation price. In many areas of copyright, these dynamics have transformed
competition “in the market” into competition “for the market,” with some negative consequences
for efficiency (Ramello & Silva, 2008).
This arrangement has essentially converted the legal monopoly given via copyright—which is
an exclusive right over a given resource—into an economic monopoly, i.e., an exclusive right over
a market. In an economic monopoly, whoever gets exclusive control of the right gains market
power over a specific demand. In general, market power intended as the ability to raise the price
above cost is inversely correlated with the perceived uniqueness of the good, which in the case of
19
If copyrighted works were homogenous we would not need copyright, as it would make more economic sense to
reward just one creator and leave the output available to society. It is variety that justifies the existence of copyright.
20
By nature, creative activity is a process recombining previous knowledge which is simultaneously an output, an input
and a technology; hence, any severe restriction on the use of existing knowledge will hamper the incremental process of
knowledge development, as argued in Ramello (2008).
8
copyrighted items, despite being somewhat exogenous, can then be endogenously enhanced (Silva
& Ramello, 2000; Motta, 2004).
In the case of scientific publishing, uniqueness is enhanced by the certification of quality
given by the journal’s reputation and the indicators provided by ranking, such as the impact factor.
In many circumstances, incumbents can exploit uniqueness and leverage market power by
clustering—i.e., bundling—together several copyrighted items. This reinforces the incumbent’s
position vis-à-vis newcomers21.
This rationale seems to have characterized the journal-publishing industry, where a handful of
incumbents now control large catalogues (the so-called Big Deal) and a substantial share of the
markets across distinct fields (e.g. economics, medical sciences, chemistry, etc.), while the residual
segment of every field is made up of minor players—publishers of a single journal or a few titles—
that operate in just that segment or at most in a limited number of fields (Edlin & Rubinfeld, 2004;
Dewatripont et al., 2006).
This pattern of “major-minor” firms replicates what is happening in many copyright
industries, starting with the seminal case of the recording business. There is regular entry and exit in
the minor segment (independent labels, in the music business) and substantial stability in the major
segment (Silva & Ramello, 2000). This difference points to a discrepancy in competition that can
only be explained by the fact that the two segments are different markets to a certain extent, and
there are barriers to moving from the minor to the major segment.
5.1 The industry of economics journals: a case study
The industrial trajectory described above highlights the role of copyright control in endogenously
defining the market structure, which is consequently not the cause but the outcome of the precise
strategies adopted by right holders in order to gain or extend market power.
In order to properly qualify this assertion for the journal-publishing sector, the rest of this
section will discuss the field of economics during the period 1999-2007. To better focus on the
competitive process, the analytical lens is provided by industrial economics and antitrust practice,
which are naturally suited to describing the extended competitive process.
The first step is to define the boundaries of the “relevant market,” i.e. the set of products and
geographical areas that can create competitive constraints on each other (see Motta, 2004). As
argued above, while to some extent every journal or even article is a poorly substitutable product to
the scholar, an investigation of competition must focus on the true demand, which in our case is
essentially comprised of libraries albeit acting as agents for scholars22.
From the library’s standpoint, demand is less rigid than for the individual scholar, so what
matters is the availability of a number of journals and collections (bundles) rather than single
titles23. We can then use two criteria to identify the relevant market in accordance with antitrust
practice. The first, relating to geographical area, relies on language24; although partitioned into
national groups, the economics community is global, so the real division is between English and
non-English language journals. The latter are country specific and at most complement rather than
substitute for the former.
The second criterion concerns product quality and substitutability. Demand from the library
considers many aspects relating to the final demand from readers, mainly scholars and students.
Although many criteria can be endorsed, the rough goal is to select the best possible quality, and the
21
For an in depth discussion also referring to some antitrust cases and a formal treatment see Nicita & Ramello (2007).
On the role of libraries as buyers, see Parks (2001) and McCabe (2002).
23
For the library the idea is to maximize the number of readers within the given institution, which happens even though
a number of readers are not satisfied.
24
This criterion is heavily used in many media sectors, including television. See for instance the cases mentioned in
Nicita & Ramello (2007).
22
9
most widely adopted measure for ensuring a minimal level of quality is the journal’s inclusion on
the ISI-Thompon impact factor list (Garfield, 2005).
The top journals are included on this list and at high levels the signal is clear, while it becomes
less precise for low-ranking journals, whose quality is perfectly comparable to non-ISI publications.
Hence, inclusion on the ISI list is a somewhat restrictive and imperfect selection criterion, as many
good and very good journals are not listed. Still, it seems reasonable to assert that because of their
“proximity” to highly ranked journals, low ISI ranked journals have a comparative advantage over
non-ISI journals and this makes them somewhat less substitutable 25. On the whole the criterion
appears plausible, as emphasized elsewhere (Garfield, 2005; Dewatripoint et al., 2006), and can be
roughly used to identify what we can call the “market for academic attention” for scholarly journals.
Table 1: Journals listed in ISI - “economics,” 1999-2007
Year
1999
2002
2004
2007
no. of journals
165
166
172
191
NFP +
/
3
2
6
NFP /
5
5
5
FP+
/
11
8
21
FP/
8
2
4
Source: elaboration on ISI-Thomson figures
Table 1 illustrates the cohort for the period observed. The overall increase during the period of
15.75% (second column) confirms the relevance of being ISI listed, which is underestimated as
entry is rationed by Thomson and only a small fraction of applicants are accepted by ISI every year.
In the field of economics, a rising number of top ranked journals are now in the hands of a few
publishing houses. Even though a number of journals are still owned and run by scientific societies
—in economics, leading universities such as Harvard and the University of Chicago and scientific
associations such as the AEA publish the leading journals in the field—commercial publishers own
an extensive number of titles and a considerable share of the market.
Consequently, journals can be easily divided by mission into “not for profit” (NFP)
publishers, those rooted in the history of scholarly journals and essentially comprising scientific
associations and university presses, and “for profit” (FP) publishers, i.e. undertakings that make a
profitable business of publishing, in strict accordance with profit maximization rules26.
The journal figures disaggregated by mission show that net entry is greatly in favor of FP
journals although, as argued below, the average quality is higher in NFP journals. Actually, in the
period observed the net increase in NFP journals was +28 items, while for FP this value was
negative (-4 items), signalling a sharp share increase trend in the FP segment—which of course
translates into markets shares as reported in Table 2.
TABLE 2: Publishers’ market shares by impact factor (per cent of the market), 1999-2007
Year
Blackwel
l
Routledge
T&F
Springer
Elsevier
Sharpe
Other
commercial
Academic
CR4*
1999
2002
17.690
19.968
3.918
4.201
6.383
7.278
22.706
24.796
0.465
0.424
7.398
5.696
41.440
37.637
50.697
56.243
25
A low ranked ISI journal can more easily become a high ranked ISI journal than a non-ISI journal. The perceived
probability of being a good journal is therefore enhanced by the simple fact of being on the list. It is worth noting that
many research assessment systems the around the world use the ISI/non-ISI label as a basic litmus test.
26
This division seems to be reasonable and descriptive even though different groupings are possible, e.g. by considering
the university presses as an intermediate case.
10
2004
2007
19.988
18.618
4.274
5.606
8.275 24.453 0.326
6.480
8.127 25.997 0.648
5.413
Source: elaboration on ISI-Thomson data
36.204
35.590
56.990
58.348
The industrial framework, as discussed, is an oligopoly in which a handful of commercial
players compete against societies or university presses and minor commercial players. The figures
in Table 2 are disaggregated for the top five commercial publishers, while the rest of them, which
occupy a very low share, have been grouped into “other commercial” for the sake of readability.
The same has been done with university presses and scientific associations.
It is fairly evident that within the FP publishers, the top four serve appreciable shares of
demand, while from the fifth on each journal serves less than the 1% of the market. The same sharp
division applies to impact factor, as on average (Table 3) the big players show stronger values that
increase with the years.
The percentage of market share held by the top four firms (CR4) is the most widely used
concentration ratio, and in our case demonstrates a highly concentrated market that is increasingly
so over time. Now it is well known in industrial economics that the link between concentration and
market power cannot be taken for granted because of the available data or the high elasticity of
demand (Donsimoni, Geroski & Jacquemin, 1984), and there are cases in which the opposite is true
(Salop & Stiglitx, 1977).
However, in journal-publishing, substitutability (although somewhat higher for libraries) is
significantly constrained by readers who when needing an article see one journal as a very poor
substitute for others and moreover they require access to a substantial catalogue of journals that
necessarily includes the highly ranked. Hence price elasticity is not high, and as demonstrated in the
literature, we can easily assess that in such a case the calculated concentration rate rather
understates the true quantum of market power (Scherer, 1980).
Moreover, there is a clear-cut argument that the dramatic increase in prices would not be
sustainable in a competitive environment. It is therefore plausible to assume that market power is
responsible for the high and increasing concentration.
Along with the shift of the market in the hands of FP publishers, which has moved from a
CR4 of 50% to almost 60% in less than 10 years despite a lower perceived quality (as shown by
average impact factor in Table 3, especially at the beginning of the observation period), the above
remark signals that there is a drift in the market’s attention that cannot be easily explained on the
grounds of standard competition. Rather, it shows that endogenous features are working to redirect
what would be the free choice of demand in a competitive market in which readers choose and buy
the journals of higher quality.
TABLE 3: Publishers’ average impact factor, 1999-2007
Year
Blackwell
1999
2002
2004
2007
0.451
0.559
0.609
0.604
Routledge
T&F
Springer
Elsevier
Sharpe
0.274
0.341
0.592 0.174
0.323
0.427
0.710 0.174
0.358
0.529
0.763 0.146
0.500
0.552
0.863 0.308
Source: elaboration on ISI-Thomson data
Other FP
Academic
0.377
0.319
0.395
0.351
0.829
0.827
0.867
0.907
Although all the impact factors (FP and NFP) are increasing (Table 3), it is fairly evident that
in general, academic journals perform better. Just one commercial publisher ranks closely, while the
others publish less highly ranked journals. Now, in a static framework one would expect the more
highly ranked journals (NFP) to prevail. Yet the previous figures showed that NFP journals are
more rapidly exiting the market, even though a greater rate of failure should be expected for their
11
less “attractive” FP counterparts. Consequently, there has to be something else affecting the
competitive process and altering the expected outcome.
Here is where bundling comes in. Many articles have discussed how the endogenous strategy
introduced by commercial publishers with extended catalogues favors the endorsement of
commercial policies of bundling rather than competition among titles (McCabe, 2002; Edlin &
Rubinfeld, 2004; Dewatripont et al., 2006; Cavaleri et al., 2009). The rationale is that the rigidity of
the buyer towards at least a number of items included in the catalogue can be leveraged in order to
sell the entire bundle at the cost of individually published journals. The publisher exploits the extra
willingness to pay for highly ranked journals and can sell the bundled items at a lower price than the
competitive product, so that demand subject to budget constraints shifts towards the better priced
bundle.
Essentially, the strategy of selling bundles while enjoying market power in one market can be
leveraged in order to control a secondary bundled market, inasmuch as the seller of two bundled
items can price them lower than the sum of buying them separately from different producers.
Assuming for instance a highly ranked journal A, and two lower ranked journals B and C (which
are more substitutable for one another), if one seller is the publisher of A and B and sells the bundle
at a price p A+B < p A + pC (where the right side describes the price of buying two journals A and C
separately from two publishers), then the strategy will likely favor the publisher of many journals
and will essentially foreclose the market to the single journal publisher.
This effect will be amplified if we assume that there are demand network externalities
affecting the evaluation of the journals (which seems to be the case, as the importance of a journal
and an article increases the more researchers use it and make it an essential input for a given stream
of research) and that buyers are also constrained by the opportunity costs of buying journals, since
they must buy books as well (Edlin & Rubinfeld, 2004).
If in the short run the bundling strategy could produce some gains in term of consumer
welfare27, in the long run it favors the persistence of incumbents, which can be problematic for the
competitiveness of the scholarly publication market and the variety of publishers.
TABLE 4: Quality distribution: percent of journals with an IF greater than 1, 2007
% of journals
with IF>1
Blackwell
Routledge
T&F
Springer
Elsevier
Sharpe
Other FP
Academic
18.182
12.500
23.810
37.209
n.s.
18.182
39.286
Source: calculation on ISI-Thomson data
Table 4 depicts the share of highly ranked economics journals in the year 2007, where
“highly” is defined as an impact factor of greater than 128.
Clearly only a fraction of the commercial publishers’ catalogue is highly ranked, and this
serves as a lever to sell other publications. Since researchers must have the high IF journal in order
to achieve their own advances, this is tantamount to opening the library door to the entire catalogue
29
.
27
If the publisher prices journal A above the monopoly price when sold alone, buyers will chose the bundle A+B and
there will be no gains, while the market will be foreclosed for publisher C.
28
While a journal with IF>1 is in general a well esteemed publication, one could object that this is too low a threshold.
However, this will actually strengthen the discussion here as the outcome in terms of share would be restrained and
would show how controlling a few “good” journals permits the bundling of inferior ones.
29
The correlation of 0.89 between this value and market share in the same year, although imperfect (as we are grouping
other commercial and academic publishers), suggests that market share is closely connected to the control of some
highly ranked journals.
12
However, the picture given here is under-representative, as many of the publishers with high
market shares in economics are also active in many other fields, so their ability to exploit the sale of
catalogues is very much enhanced.
The current FP incumbents with large market shares in economics are involved in many of the
other fields, which number 22 in all. As of this writing Elsevier is involved in all 22 fields, while
Wiley-Blackwell, Routledge/Francis & Taylor and Springer-Kluwer are active in 21. The only
exception is Lippincott, which did not show up in this picture as it is incumbent in only four fields
and is a major player in two of them.
6. Copyright, competition and exclusion in the market for academic attention: discussion
The rationale for copyright is that it promotes Schumpeterian innovation race: as argued above, in
the case of a successful copyrighted work, the right holder can reap the associated economic
benefit. The underlying economic model is that of a competitive process in which new products
compete with older ones all the time and the successful ones earn a reward. Hence, the incumbents
are only temporary and their success in the market should be challenged in every subsequent race
by other competitors.
The observation of copyright industries in general and of scholarly journals in particular
shows that this picture is very far from reality. In fact, it is more the exception than the rule.
The standard situation is that of a concentrated industry in which the incumbents progressively
increase their market shares and jointly dominate a large segment of the market, which to a great
extent can be considered a distinct market with no substantial entry and exit. The rest of the market
is then populated by other subjects that live in a more competitive environment. This partitioned
structure characterizes many copyright markets, including sound recording, the movie industry and
operating systems30. It is also the representative structure in journal publishing, either per field or in
general.
Many issues require further discussion. First, the model justifying copyright no longer seems
to apply. While concentration per se does not translate into lack of competition, the dramatic
increase in the market price of scientific journals (with non increasing possibly decreasing costs)
suggests that substantial market power exists. This stems from the idiosyncratic nature of journals
and articles, which are poorly substitutable, especially when the difference in perceived quality
produces a sharp differentiation.
Therefore, while there are no substantial entry barriers to the overall market for new journals,
demand inertia makes it very difficult to attract attention from the scientific community. This has
much to do with reputation and the value that scholars attribute to a journal. Hence there are
structural entry barriers to the “market for academic attention,” which is really the relevant market.
The conclusion is consistent with the findings of other studies31.
Furthermore, the particular features of this market for attention permit the creation of strategic
entry barriers that progressively reinforce the dominance of incumbents at the cost of other
publishers. The pivotal element of this strategy is bundling, which favors the success of new
journals that are part of a bundle, even though the overall quality is not always the best. The mere
existence of a few good journals in the bundle can be leveraged to attract attention to lower ranked
journals, at the expense of potential competitors who are unable to exploit bundling. In the long run,
this trend self-enforces attention toward the entire bundle and the ranking of all the incumbent
journals.
30
For references see Silva & Ramello (2000) and Cavaleri et al. (2009), among others.
Edlin & Rubinfeld (2004, p.138) discuss the topic in depth and conclude that “the likelihood of success [of a new
journal] is small unless the journal has some particularly valuable and distinctive innovation.”
31
13
The dynamics described above illustrate once again that copyright is much more than a neutral
feature of the market: it is a tool that endogenously shapes the market structure, with consequences
that in most cases foster rent-seeking behaviors and a gradual shift away from competition.
This outcome has at least two unwelcome consequences in the world of scientific research.
First, it raises the cost of research, which is by nature a cumulative process where (copyrighted)
knowledge is at the same time (publishing) output and input for further advances (Ramello, 2008).
Hence the endogenous shift of market structure toward market power makes this process more
costly and difficult, with some additional paradoxical effects as for journal publishing the inputs of
publication are freely provided by scholars.
Second, in the case of scientific publishing, journals are acting as gatekeepers of the ideas
disseminated among the scientific community. The preferred outcome that would preserve full
accessibility to any potentially interesting idea requires the existence of a neutral environment, so
that the “Republic of Science” that ought to characterize the scholarly community can freely work32.
The drift from a republic toward an oligarchy raises concerns about the safeguarding of this process
that real competition would be better able to preserve.
Further, many journal articles are the outcome of previously funded research. Consequently,
publication is just a way to certify quality and make the articles available to the community. In itself
this is not expensive, and even research societies and universities can afford it, especially in the
Internet era. Journals, while increasingly squeezing the budgets of research institutions, do not
provide any remuneration for the upstream inputs that make them valuable, and their price is to a
great extent not justified.
What is intriguing, however, in the current state of affairs is that copyright once more shows
inertia toward aggregating rights. Contrary to many situations in which property rights experience
inertia towards increasing fragmentation, in a pattern suggesting the existence of entropy (Parisi,
2007), for copyright—and intellectual property rights in general—the motion is reversed in a path
of continuous concentration.
While the aggregation of rights could be beneficial to the social welfare when it lowers
transaction costs (and examples of this do exist33), there are serious concerns as it is essentially recreating the market structure that in 1710 forced the birth of the first copyright law, the Statute of
Anne. This act was the outcome of intense civil protest by many members of society, including
property rights champion John Locke, against the monopoly on book publishing and distribution
enjoyed in England for nearly 150 years by the Stationers’ Company, which had seriously
hampered the quality and the quantity of books sold (Nicita & Ramello, 2007). The simple yet
powerful solution brought about by Queen Anne was to break up property rights over an entire
catalogue (constituting a monopoly situation) into small units—copyrights over individual books—
in order to make the market more competitive.
Today, in many cases including journal publishing, catalogues have been reconstructed and
seem to be a strategic lever used in most copyright industries.
Once again, competition seems to be the key issue for safeguarding the broader social welfare.
Nevertheless, investigations so far have been rare and inconclusive. The problem may be due to the
lack of tools for properly investigating dynamic efficiency. In any case, the conclusions thus far
available are ambiguous.
The British market for scientific, technical and medical (STM) journals was brought to light
through an investigation by the UK Office of Fair Trading. This antitrust authority has not yet found
it appropriate to intervene, but somewhat ambiguously asserts that the “position will be kept under
review” as “there is evidence to suggest that the market for STM journals may not be working well”
and “many commercial journal prices appear high, at the expense of education and research
institutions” (OFT, 2002, p. 4). John Vickers, the Director General of Fair Trading, stressed that
“[j]ournals are the principal means by which scientific knowledge is disseminated. The market,
32
33
See Ramello, 2005b.
Patent pools, for instance, are designed to solve this kind of problem.
14
which operates worldwide, has a number of features that suggest that competition may not be
working effectively. However, market forces harnessing new technology may change this without
the need for intervention”34.
This attitude is puzzling, as it more or less relies on the device heavily exploited in Greek
tragedies: the deus ex-machina, i.e. an exogenous technological shock that independently solves the
problem. The persistence of monopoly, the breadth of interconnected dominance and the random
path of technological change suggest that a different attitude, giving due consideration to the
endogenous effect of laws on market structure and the behavior of economic agents, would better
inform policy in copyright industries.
7. Conclusions
This article explores the journal publishing industry in order to shed light on the overall economic
consequences of copyright in markets. Until now, the economic debate on copyright has mainly
treated the right as given, trying at most to determine whether it encourages creative activity. We
argue here that this is just one of the incentives provided by copyright.
Since the rationale for copyright is essentially to promise some market power to the holder of
the successful copyrighted item, it also provides incentives to preserve and extend market power. A
regular trait of copyright industries is high concentration and the creation of large catalogues of
copyrights in the hands of incumbents. This outcome can be observed as the aggregation of rights
and is one of the pivotal strategies for obtaining or extending market power, consistently with
findings in other cases. Journal publishing is no different in this respect from other copyright
industries, and in the last decade has experienced a similar trajectory, leading to a highly
concentrated industry in which a handful of large firms increasingly control a substantial part of the
market.
This situation raises concerns about the governance and efficiency of scientific activity, as it
affects access to previously created ideas and puts a small number of gatekeepers in charge of
selecting scientific ideas.
It also provides a clear example of the effect of copyright dynamics on market structure,
suggesting that a different attitude should be taken in lawmaking and law enforcement.
References
Akerlof, G.A. (1970). “The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism”,
Quarterly Journal of Economics 84; 488–500.
Arrow, K.J. (1962), ‘Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention’, in Nelson,
R.R. (eds9), The Rate and Direction of Incentive Activity: Economic and Social Factors, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Bergstrom, T. C. (2001), “Free Labor for Costly Journals?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15;
232–238.
Betrand, J.L.F. (1883), “Theorie de Richesse”, Journal de Savants, September ; 499-508.
34
September 9, 2002, available at http://www.oft.gov.uk/news/press/2002/pn_55-02
15
Boyer, J.(1947), “Création du premier journal scientifique, La Nature, August 1, 243-244,
downaloaded at http://www.gloubik.info/sciences/IMG/pdf/3141-journal-des-savants.pdf
Cavaleri, P., M. Keren, G.B. Ramello and V. Valli(2009), “Publishing an E-Journal on a Shoe
String: Is It a Sustainable Project?’, Economic Analysis and Policy, 39; 89-101
Dewatripont, M., V. Ginsburgh, P. Legros, A. Walckiers, J.P. Devroey J.P., M. Dujardin, F.
Vandooren, P. Dubois, L.Foncel, M. Ivaldi and M.D. Heusse (2006), Study on the Economic and
Technical Evolution of the Scientific Publication Markets in Europe, Bruxelles: European
Commission.
Donsimoni, M.P, P. Geroski and A. Jacquemin (1984), “Concentration Indices and Market Power:
Two Views, Journal of Industrial Economics, 33; 419-434.
Edlin, A.S. and D.L. Rubinfeld (2004), “Exclusion or Efficient Pricing? The “Big Deal” Bundling
of Academic Journals”, Antitrust Law Journal, 72; 128-159
Garfield, E. (2005), “The History and Meaning of the Journal Impact Factor”, Journal of the
American Medical Association, 295; 90-93
Johns A. (2000), “Miscellaneous methods: authors, societies and journals in early modern
England”, British Journal of History of Science, 33; 159-186
McCabe, M.J. (2002), “Journal Pricing and Mergers: A Portfolio Approach”, American Economic
Review, 92; 259-269.
Nevo, A., D.L. Rubinfeld. and M. McCabe (2005), “Academic Journal Pricing and Demand of
Libraries”, American Economic Review, 95; 447-452.
Nicita A. and G.B. Ramello (2007), “Property, Liability and Market Power: the Antitrust Side of
Copyright”, Review of Law and Economics, 3; 767-791.
OFT (2002), The market for scientific, technical and medical journals, London, UK: Office of Fair
Trading,.
Page, G., R. Campbell and J. Meadows (1996), Journal Publishing: Principles and Practice.
London: Butterworths.
Parisi, F. (2007), “Entropy and the Asymmetric Coase Theorem”, in Porrini, D. and G.B. Ramello
(eds), Property Rights Dynamics: A Law and Economics Perspective, London and New York :
Routledge,.
Parks, R. P. (2001), “The Faustian Grip of Academic Publishing”, Journal of Economic
Methodology, 9; 317-335
Ramello G.B. (2005), “Private appropriability and Knowledge Sharing: Contradiction or
Convergence ? The Opposite Tragedy of Creative Commons”, in Gordon W., L. Takeyama and R.
Towse (eds), Developments in the Economics of Copyright, Cheltenham, UK-Northampton, MA,
US: Edward Elgar
16
Ramello, G.B. (2005b) “Property Rights, Firm Boundaries and the Republic of Science”, Industrial
and Corporate Change, 14; 95- 1204.
Ramello, G.B. and F. Silva (2008), “Exclusion, Competition & Change: the Shifting Boundaries of
the Television Market”, Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 5; 55-74
Ramello, G.B. (2008), “Access to vs. Exclusion from Knowledge: Intellectual Property, Efficiency
and Social Justice” in Gosserie A., A. Marciano and A. Strowel (eds), Intellectual Property and
Theories of Justice, London and Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Rothen, D. and W.W. Powell (2007), “The Frontiers of Intellectual Property Expanded Protection
versus New Models of Open Science”, Annual Review of Law and Social Sciences,, 3; 45-373.
Royal Society (2003), Keeping Science Open: The Effects of Intellectual Property Policy on the
Conduct of Science, London: Council of the Royal Society.
Salop, S. and J. Stiglitz (1977), “Bargains and Ripoffs: a Model of Monopolistically Competitive
Price Dispersion”, Review of Economic Studies, 44; 493-510.
Schere,r F.M. (1980), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Boston : Houghton
Mifflin.
Silva, F. and G.B. Ramello (2000), “Sound Recording Market: the Ambiguous Case of Copyright
and Piracy”, Industrial and Corporate Change, 9; 415– 442.
Spier, R. (2002), “The history of the peer-review process”, Trends in Biotechnology, 20; 357-358
Towse R., C. Handke and P. Stepan (2008), “The Economics of Copyright Law: A Stocktake of the
Literature”, Review of Economic Research on Copyright Issues, 5; 1-22
17
Recent working papers
The complete list of working papers is can be found at http://polis.unipmn.it/pubbl
*Economics Series
T
Territories Series
**Political Theory Series
t
Transitions Series
ε
Al.Ex Series
Q
Quaderni CIVIS
2010 n.169*
Giovanni B. Ramello: Copyright & endogenous market structure: A glimpse
from the journal-publishing market
2010 n.168*
Mario Ferrero: The cult of martyrs
2010 n.167*
Cinzia Di Novi: The indirect effect of fine particulate matter on health through
individuals' life-style
2010 n.166*
Donatella Porrini and Giovanni B. Ramello: Class action and financial markets:
Insights from law and economics
2010 n.165** Corrado Malandrino: Il pensiero di Roberto Michels sull'oligarchia, la classe
politica e il capo carismatico. Dal Corso di sociologia politica (1927) ai Nuovi
studi sulla classe politica (1936)
2010 n.164ε
Matteo Migheli: Gender at work: Productivity and incentives
2010 n.163Q
Gian-Luigi Bulsei and Noemi Podestà (Eds): Imprese differenti. Le
organizzazioni cooperative tra crisi economica e nuovo welfare
2010 n.162*
Claudia Cusinello and Franco Amisano: Analysis for the implementation of a
sustainable transport model in the eastern Piedmont county of Alessandria, Italy
2010 n.161*
Roberto Ricciuti: Accumulazione del capitale e crescita economica tra Italia
liberale e regime fascista
2010 n.160*
Carla Marchese and Giovanni B. Ramello: In the beginning was the Word. Now
is the Copyright
2010 n.159ε
Peter Lewisch, Stefania Ottone and Ferruccio Ponzano: Free-riding on altruistic
punishment? An experimental comparison of third-party-punishment in a standalone and in an in-group environment
2009 n.158*
Rongili Biswas, Carla Marchese and Fabio Privileggi: Tax evasion in a
principal-agent model with self-protection
2009 n.157*
Alessandro Lanteri and Stefania Ottone: Economia ed etica negli esperimenti
2009 n.156*
Cinzia Di Novi: Sample selection correction in panel data models when
selectivity is due to two sources
2009 n.155*
Michela Martinoia: European integration, labour market dynamics and
migration flows
2009 n.154*
Massimo Pasquariello and GianMarco Chiesi: Valore aggiunto e tipologia di
spesa in Piemonte. Un confronto tra Alessandria e gli altri capoluoghi di
provincia
2009 n.153*
Massimo Pasquariello: Produttività, sistemi locali del lavoro, specializzazione
produttiva e scenari futuri. Studio preliminare in preparazione del Piano
strategico per il comune di Alessandria
2009 n.152*
Massimo Pasquariello and GianMarco Chiesi: L’analisi dei determinanti di
un’area territoriale. Studio preliminare in preparazione del Piano strategico
per il comune di Alessandria
2009 n.151*
Cristina Elisa Orso: Formal and informal sectors: Interactions between
moneylenders and traditional banks in the rural Indian credit market
2009 n.150*
Michele Giuranno: The logic of party coalitions with political activism and
public financing
2009 n.149*
Matteo Migheli: Sharing the pie: the Lutheran is neither opportunistic nor
generous
2009 n.148*
Amedeo Fossati and Marcello Montefiori: Migrants and mafia as global public
goods
2009 n.147*
Alberto Cassone: L'impatto economico dell'Universita' del Piemonte Orientale
“Amedeo Avogadro”: un aggiornamento al 2008
2009 n.146*
Daron Acemoglu, Davide Ticchi and Andrea Vindigni: Persistence of civil wars
2009 n.145*
Daniele Bondonio: Impact identification strategies for evaluating business
incentive programs
2009 n.144*
Barry Eichengreen, Rachita Gullapalli and Ugo Panizza: Capital account
liberalization, financial development and industry growth: a synthetic view
2009 n.143*
Emma Galli and Roberto Ricciuti: Sulla political economy del deficit pubblico
nell’Italia liberale
2009 n.142*
Matteo Migheli: Religiosity and happiness: an ever-winning couple? An answer
from India
Download