Antitrust and Trade Regulation Alert July 2007 Authors: Thomas Donovan +1.412.355.6466 thomas.donovan@klgates.com www.klgates.com Minimum Price Agreements Between Manufacturers and Resellers No Longer Automatically Unlawful David Lenci +1.206.370.5839 david.lenci@klgates.com John Longstreth +1.202.661.6271 john.longstreth@klgates.com K&L Gates comprises approximately 1,400 lawyers in 22 offices located in North America, Europe and Asia, and represents capital markets participants, entrepreneurs, growth and middle market companies, leading FORTUNE 100 and FTSE 100 global corporations and public sector entities. For more information, please visit www.klgates.com. Overruling a nearly 100-year-old bedrock antitrust law precedent, the Supreme Court held this week that manufacturers may enter into agreements with resellers to set a minimum price at which the retailer can resell the manufacturer’s product, where doing so does not result in an unreasonable restraint of trade. Manufacturers were previously able only to suggest such restrictions unilaterally, could enforce them only by terminating noncomplying retailers, and could not obtain any explicit or implicit agreement to adhere to them. Now that the per se ban on “resale price maintenance” under federal law has been removed, many manufacturers may be able to overtly, and in the Court’s view more efficiently, direct retailers to set price floors for the resale of their merchandise. However, some states may continue to apply per se prohibitions on resale price maintenance. Leegin Creative Leather Products, Inc. v. PSKS, Inc. (No. 06-480, June 28, 2007), a 5-4 decision, rejected the rule established in the 1911 “Dr. Miles” case,1 which made any minimum price agreement between manufacturer and distributor per se (or automatically) illegal under Section 1 of the Sherman Act. Justice Kennedy’s opinion for the Court holds that courts should now evaluate such “minimum resale price maintenance,” or “vertical price fixing,” agreements under the same “rule of reason” standard that governs most other “contracts, combinations or conspiracies” subject to challenge as restraints of trade. Minimum pricing arrangements between manufacturers and resellers will thus no longer automatically be deemed illegal under federal antitrust law; rather, each case will be evaluated on its own merits to determine whether the pricing arrangement restricts overall competition between the product itself and competitors’ products, or has procompetitive benefits that outweigh any such restrictions. THE LEEGIN CASE A small Texas boutique alleged that Leegin, a California-based women’s accessories manufacturer, violated the Sherman Act by enforcing a policy requiring each of its resellers to sign a written agreement to maintain minimum prices for its products. The trial court followed the Dr. Miles rule to find this policy violated antitrust laws, and the Fifth Circuit affirmed. Noting that Section 1 of the Sherman Act “outlaw[s] only unreasonable restraints” of trade or commerce in furthering its goal of benefiting consumers,2 Justice Kennedy finds the rule of reason to be the “accepted standard for testing whether a practice restrains trade in violation of §1.” The rule of reason requires a court to “weigh all of the circumstances of a case” in distinguishing anticompetitive restraints from those restraints that promote competition and help the consumer. Agreements between parties at different levels of distribution, such as manufacturer and reseller, are termed “vertical” agreements,” and all 1 2 Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. John D. Park & Sons Co., 220 U.S. 373 (1911). Leegin, slip op. at 5 (quoting State Oil Co. v. Kahn, 522 U.S. 3, 10 (1997)). Antitrust and Trade Regulation Alert but minimum resale price maintenance agreements are already judged under the rule of reason. Conversely, the Dr. Miles rule held per se illegal any vertical agreement to set minimum resale prices between a manufacturer and a retailer, regardless of the competitive effects of the vertical restraint. Justice Kennedy states that courts should only use per se rules in the Sherman Act context when considering restraints “that would always or almost always tend to restrict competition and decrease output.”3 Additionally, “to justify a per se prohibition a restraint must have manifestly anticompetitive effects and lack any redeeming value.”4 Leegin rules that the economic and competitive effects of resale price maintenance restraints do not justify a per se ban. Absent the precedential effect of Dr. Miles, the majority finds that a fresh review of the economic issues surrounding minimum resale price maintenance contracts would lead the Court to find the rule of reason to be the appropriate standard by which to evaluate such agreements. Admitting that “each side of the debate can find sources to support its position,” the majority finds that most economists agree that resale price maintenance can have procompetitive justifications, including the promotion of “interbrand competition—the competition among manufacturers selling different brands of the same type of product—by reducing intrabrand competition—the competition among retailers selling the same brand.”5 The majority also cites many other economic validations, for example that the elimination of price competition between retailers forces stores to “compete among themselves over services,” which ultimately benefits the consumer. The majority opinion notes that the Court has progressively rejected per se treatment of non-price vertical restraints, such as exclusive territories or requiring certain retail practices regarding staffing or store environment,6 and when considering “maximum 3 Leegin slip op. at 6 (quoting Business Electronics Corp. v. Sharp Electronics Corp., 485 U.S. 717, 723 (1988)). 4 Leegin slip op. at 6 (internal quotations omitted). 5 Leegin slip op. at 10 (emphasis added). 6 See, e.g., Continental T.V., Inc. v. GTE Sylvania Inc., 433 U.S. 36 (1977) (using the rule of reason rather than the per se rule to evaluate non-price vertical restraints). resale price maintenance.”7 Leegin’s complete overruling of Dr. Miles thus achieves intellectual and jurisprudential coherence by applying this same rule of reason to all vertical restraints imposed by manufacturers on retailers. Justice Kennedy emphasizes that the ruling will not simply open the floodgates for minimum resale price maintenance agreements: “as courts gain experience considering the effects of these restraints by applying the rule of reason over a course of decisions, they can … ensure the rule operates to eliminate anticompetitive restraints from the market and to provide more guidance to businesses.” EFFECTS OF LEEGIN ON THE MANUFACTURER / RETAILER RELATIONSHIP In order to avoid the harshest effects of the Dr. Miles rule, manufacturers have long relied on the Colgate decision,8 issued eight years after Dr. Miles, holding that no antitrust violation occurred unless the manufacturer and retailer had an “agreement” to establish minimum resale prices. Manufacturers were permitted to unilaterally adopt “Colgate Policies,” which announced their refusal to deal with resellers who did not adhere to carefully set resale price “floors” (the “Manufacturer’s Suggested Retail Price” or MSRP), but did not allow actual agreement with retailers on a resale price. In Leegin, the manufacturer went too far with its Colgate Policy and conclusively created bilateral agreements with its retailers regarding minimum resale prices. The Leegin decision allows manufacturers who already implement effective Colgate Policies to determine that concrete minimum resale price agreements with their retailers will help them function more efficiently. If challenged as anticompetitive measures in violation of antitrust law, these agreements will no longer be judged based on the stringent Dr. Miles rule and if the manufacturer can show effective competition with other manufacturers the agreements will likely be upheld under federal law. As noted above, however, applicable state laws on the subject must also be considered. 7 Kahn, 522 U.S. 3 (1997) (rule of reason used rather than the per se rule to evaluate maximum vertical price restraints). 8 United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300 (1919). July 2007 | 2 Antitrust and Trade Regulation Alert The Leegin decision does not change the judicial view of “horizontal” conspiracies among manufacturers, retailers, or others at the same level of distribution to maintain price floors or ceilings. Such horizontal action will still be judged under a per se rule and held illegal without regard to its competitive effects. The Leegin rule applies only to vertical agreements. last eighteen months.10 Following the general practice in government enforcement actions over the past few decades, these rulings may direct private actions to core anticompetitive conduct. Leegin continues the recent trend of Supreme Court rulings in favor of defendants in antitrust actions; it is the fourth such case this term9 and the seventh in the 9 See Weyerhaeuser Co. v. Ross-Simmons Hardwood Lumber Co., Inc., No. 05-381 (Feb. 20, 2007) (predatory buying claims must meet the same strict standards as predatory selling allegations); Bell Atlantic Corp. v. Twombly, No. 05-1126 (May 21, 2007) (plaintiffs must plead more than a “bare assertion of conspiracy” to state a claim under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, and must allege “enough facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face”); Credit Suisse Securities (USA), LLC v. Billing, No. 05-1157 (June 18, 2007) (broadening conditions under which extensive federal regulation of securities industry conduct impliedly immunizes that conduct from antitrust liability). 10 See Independent Ink Inc. v. Illinois Tool Works Inc., 126 S. Ct. 1462 (2006) (no presumption that a patent confers market power in tying cases); Texaco Inc. v. Dagher, 126 S. Ct. 1276 (2006) (pricing coordination among parties to a fully integrated joint venture not a per se illegal conspiracy); Volvo Trucks N. Am. Inc. v. Reeder-Simco GMC Inc., 126 S. Ct. 860 (2006) (recovery under the RobinsonPatman Act in competitive solicitation limited to actual competitors for the solicitation). K&L Gates comprises multiple affiliated partnerships: a limited liability partnership with the full name Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis LLP qualified in Delaware and maintaining offices throughout the U.S., in Berlin, and in Beijing (Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis LLP Beijing Representative Office); a limited liability partnership (also named Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis LLP) incorporated in England and maintaining our London office; a Taiwan general partnership (Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis) which practices from our Taipei office; and a Hong Kong general partnership (Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis, Solicitors) which practices from our Hong Kong office. K&L Gates maintains appropriate registrations in the jurisdictions in which its offices are located. A list of the partners in each entity is available for inspection at any K&L Gates office. This publication/newsletter is for informational purposes and does not contain or convey legal advice. The information herein should not be used or relied upon in regard to any particular facts or circumstances without first consulting a lawyer. Data Protection Act 1998—We may contact you from time to time with information on Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis LLP seminars and with our regular newsletters, which may be of interest to you. We will not provide your details to any third parties. Please e-mail london@ klgates.com if you would prefer not to receive this information. ©1996-2007 Kirkpatrick & Lockhart Preston Gates Ellis LLP. All Rights Reserved. July 2007 | 3