Put Your Money where Your Mouth Is: An Equilibrium Model Relating Bank Scale to Bank Quality Tianxi Wang April, 2012 Abstract In a framework where bank …nancing plays a certi…cation role, the paper shows that if each and every bank enlarges credit supply, then each and every’s asset quality falls. It identi…es scale produces two forces shaping quality: the increasing return to fund scale in obtaining screening expertise and the equilibrium e¤ect. In equilibrium, …nancial intermediation arises naturally, and direct …nance and intermediated …nance coexist in a uniquely determined allocation. The paper sheds new lights on the leverage and industry organization of the banking sector. Key Words: Certi…cation; Asset Scale; Asset Quality; Increasing Return to Scale; Leverage; Industrial Organization JEL: D53, D82, G21, G30, L10 Email: wangt@essex.ac.uk. Correspondence: Economics, University of Essex, Colchester, CO4 3SQ, UK. Fax: +44 (0) 1206 872724. I am indebted to Dmitri Vinogradov for his enormous help with the exposition. I thank Sanjay Banerji, Hans Gersbach, Esa Jokivuolle, Weimin Liu, Xuewen Liu, John Moore, Jean Rochet, Zhen Song, Tuomas Takalo, Huainan Zhao, and seminar participants at Zhejiang University, Fudan University, Essex University, Bank of Finland, ETH Zurich, Nottingham Business School, for their helpful coments. 1 1 Introduction The recent crisis arouses grave concerns about banks’ asset quality in general and risk taking in particular. The focus, so far, is on capital adequacy ratio, unsurprisingly, given its determining role in preventing banks from picking knowingly ine¢ cient, highrisk projects (see e.g. Jensen and Meckling 1976). The paper, however, takes a di¤erent angle, the scales of banks’assets. It shows that independent of banks’capitalization, their sizes play a decisive role for their asset quality and risk taking, by determining the level at which they know the qualities of the projects. With this exercise, the paper sheds new lights on many empirically well documented phenomena regarding the leverage and industrial organization of the banking sector. To study the choice of knowledge level by banks, the paper considers two types of investors: households and bankers. Households are always uninformed of the types of entrepreneurs’projects. Bankers, by contrast, can obtain the expertise of screening projects to some accuracy by paying the according costs. Bankers’ fund, which intends to capture equity capital of banks, is scarce. Entrepreneurs depend mainly on households’fund for …nancing. But they will not get any if they do not convince the households of the quality of their projects. They do it by obtaining enough fund from the bankers who have attained the expertise and screened the projects with it. That is, for certi…cation purpose, entrepreneurs need to demand a su¢ cient amount of the informed capital (i.e. expertised bankers’fund),1 which drives it to earn a higher return rate than is earned by the uninformed capital (e.g. households’fund). The gap in return rate gives bankers the incentive to obtain screening expertise and become informed. This incentive, the paper …nds, is shaped by two forces that the scales of funds supplied by bankers bring forth. 1 Consistent with the certi…cation role of bank …nance, empirical studies well document that obtaining bank …nance induces signi…cant movements of the borrower …rm’s stock price; see James (1989), Mikkelson and Partch (1988), Lummer and McConnell (1989), Best and Zhang (1993), and Billett et. al. (1995), Maskara and Mullineaux (forthcoming), and Ross (forthcoming). Moreover, the certi…cation role is not con…ned to commercial banks. For example, Goldman Sachs’s purchase of $375 million of Facebook shares sends the value of the company to $50 billion, more than 100 times of its annual earning $472 million; see "Facebook move lucrative for Goldman" and "Facebook", on Financial Times, the 4th and 9th of Jan., 2011, respectively. 2 The …rst is the increasing return to fund scale in obtaining screening expertise. If a banker, by paying the cost, obtains the expertise of some level, then she knows the types of projects to the corresponding accuracy, whereby all the fund she invests earns the return rate of the informed capital at the accuracy. The larger the scale of the fund she invests, the bigger the pro…t she earns by becoming informed;2 thus the bigger the incentive of her to spend in screening expertise and the higher the level of screening expertise she obtains. This type of increasing return to application scale in acquiring a technology or expertise exists much widely. For instance, learning a widely spoken language delivers a bigger bene…t than learning a thinly spoken one; and it is more pro…table to become a top comedian where the audience is bigger. The force alone commands that if all banks expand its credit supply, then all their asset quality would be enhanced. But there is the second, counter force. That is the equilibrium e¤ect: the ampler the aggregate supply of the informed capital by bankers, the lower the return rate it earns, which dampens all bankers’incentives to become informed. If each and every banker increases her supply of fund, the scale of each banker and the aggregate supply of bank …nance will both increase and then the two forces are in con‡ict. The second force dominates, the paper …nds, and in net the expertise level of each and every banker falls, with which the asset quality of each and every declines. This is consistent with the two trends which the years preceding the recent crisis witnessed: the scale of banks’lending colossally expanded, while the loan quality monotonically fell.3 Especially, Mian and Su… (2009) document that securitization, the main way of enlarging credit supply that time, led both a "sharp drop" in the interest rate and a "signi…cant more" increase in the default rate.4 The paper derives a number of results regarding the leverage and industrial organiza2 Williamson (1986b) and Hauswald and Marquez (2006) consider other cases of increasing return to scale in relation to information acquisition. 3 See Demyanyk and Van Hemert (forthcoming), Ja¤e et al (2009), Keys, et al (2010), Loutskina (forthcoming), Mayer et. al (2009), Mian and Su… (2009), Pozsar et. al (2010), Purnanandam(forthcoming); especially, see Demyanyk and Van Hemert (forthcoming), Mayer et. al (2009), and Mian and Su… (2009) for the monotonic quality fall. 4 For a closer examination on why securitization weakens the incentives of banks to monitor borrowers or to acquire soft information, see Parlour and Plantin (2008) and Rajan et al (2008). 3 tion of the banking sector. First, the increasing return to scale gives big banks an advantage over small banks. Thus, the bigger the bank, the higher the level of screening expertise, evidence of which is o¤ered by Ross (forthcoming) who shows that …nance by the dominate US banks certi…es the borrowers are of higher quality and lower risk, and by Hao (2003) who documents that bigger banks issue loans of smaller yields, suggesting they pick higher quality borrowers. Second, the paper …nds a complementarity between leverage and screening expertise, whereby leverage enhances the scale advantage of big banks. On the one hand, the higher is a banker’s level of screening expertise, the more she can borrow. On the other hand, the more she borrows, the larger the scale of the fund she deploys, which, due to the increasing return to scale, drives her to choose a higher level of screening expertise. One immediate implication is that bigger banks are leveraged at higher ratios, which is empirically well documented.5 Third, common shocks allowing bigger leverage for all banks edge small banks out and stimulate consolidation of the banking sector. Therefore, the upward trend of bank leverage is a driving force for the trend of consolidation in the banking sector. Both trends are empirically well documented,6 but the paper is the …rst that theoretically establishes a causal link between them, as far as we know. The paper looks into the asset quality of banks from a new angle by showing that their sizes play a decisive role for their asset quality. It is thus related to the literature that explains why loose lending standards are associated with lending booms (and vice versa); see Rajan (1994), Ruckers (2004), and Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006). A di¤erence is that in the present paper, scale expansion drives quality fall, whereas in this literature, both are driven by other elements, such as career concerns of bank managers in Rajan (1994), the distribution of borrowers’ quality in Ruckers (2004), or the distribution of 5 See Liang and Rhoades (1991), McAllistera and McManus (1993), Akhavein et al. (1997), Demsetz and Strahan (1997), and Berger (1998) among others. 6 For the former, see Berger et al (1995) (…gure 1, for US over 1840-1990), Saunders and Wilson (1995) (…gures 4-6, for UK, Canda and US over 1893-1991) Hortlund (2005) (…gure 2; for Sweden 1870-2001), Miles et al (2011) (for UK over 1880-2004). For the latter, see Berger, Kashyap and Scalise (1995) (for US over 1979-1994), Saunders and Wilson (1995) (…gures 2 and 3, for Canada and UK over 1893-1991), Berger, Demsetz and Strahan (1999) (for US over 1988-1997), Jones and Critch…eld (2006) (for US over 1984-2003). 4 information in Dell’Ariccia and Marquez (2006). The paper contributes to the literature that examines in general equilibrium banks’ provision of services that help …rms with information frictions; see Allen et. al. (forthcoming), Besanko and Kanatas (1993) (BK hereafter), Cantillo (2005), Holmstrom and Tirole (1997) (HT hereafter), Morrison and White (2005), and Williamson (1986a). These papers have other focuses than causal links between asset scale and asset quality. Furthermore, the service examined in the present paper is certi…cation that helps with unobservable types of projects,7 whereas it is ex ante monitoring that helps with moral hazards, in Allen et. al. (forthcoming), BK, HT, and Morrison and White (2005), and is ex post monitoring or restructuring in Cantillo (2005) and Williamson (1986a), helping with costly state veri…cation à la Townsend (1979). Lastly, the paper features that direct …nance and intermediated …nance coexist: in equilibrium, households’ fund ‡ows to entrepreneurs both directly and via bankers and the allocation between them is uniquely determined. In contrast, while in BK and HT entrepreneurs (or …rms) also receive fund from both households and banks, as in the present paper, BK consider no intermediated …nance (i.e. no banks issuing liability to households), and HT admit that in their paper the allocation between direct …nance and intermediated …nance is indeterminate. The certi…cation service naturally drives up …nancial intermediation: due to the service, bankers earn the rate of the informed capital on the asset side, while on the liability side, they repay the rate of the uninformed capital; the gap in between is the pro…t margin of …nancial intermediation. As such the paper contributes to the literature that endogenizes …nancial intermediation from the …rst principles; see the seminar works of Diamond and Dybvig (1983), Diamond (1984), and Diamond and Rajan (2001), and see Gorton and Winton (2003) for a survey. The paper’s …nding that bigger banks could enlarge scales further via leverage is related to increasing dominance which is extensively examined by the industrial organization literature; see Flaherty (1980), Gilbert and Newbery (1982), Vickers (1986), Budd, Harris 7 The idea that banks are informed and o¤er the borrowers a service of certi…cation can be traced back, at least, to Booth and Smith (1986), but this literature does not relate it to bank …nancing. Note that certifying a …rm’s quality by obtaining capital from a third, informed party (i.e. banks) is related to but di¤erent from signalling by the …rm’s retaining a share of its own assets, on which the literature traces back to Leland and Pyle (1977), with a nice survey provided by Daniel and Titman (1995). 5 and Vickers (1993), Cabral and Riordan (1994), Klepper (1996), Athey and Schmutzler (2001), Halbheer et al (2009), Cabral (2002, 2011), Besanko et al (2011) among others. The paper progresses as follows. Section 2 sets up the basic model, with which Section 3 examines the certi…cation role of bank …nancing. To the basic model, Section 4 adds the accuracy choice by bankers and thereby shows that scale up, quality down. Section 5 further encompasses bankers’leverage to show the coexistence of intermediated …nance and direct …nance. Section 6 considers the case of heterogenous bankers and thereby spells out the implications on the industrial organization of the banking sector. Some further discussions are put in Section 7. And Section 8 concludes. All proofs are relegated in Appendix. 2 The Basic Model There are two dates with no discount, today for contracting and …nance, tomorrow for repayment and consumption. The economy consists of three sectors: entrepreneurs, bankers, and households. All agents are risk neutral and protected by limited liability. Entrepreneurs have projects but no funds. Bankers and households have funds but no projects. Entrepreneurs are of measure [0; 1] [0; 1], and bankers of measure [0; 1].8 The idea is that each banker serves a large number of entrepreneurs so that she can rely on the Law of Large Numbers to smooth out uncertainty to the demand for her fund (hereafter we refer to bankers with female pronouns, entrepreneurs with male ones). We interpret bankers as those who run banks in the interest of equity,9 and households as the investors who have no time or expertise to evaluate the pros and cons of the risky investment in entrepreneurs. However, the business of …nancial intermediation is not considered until Section 5, whence bankers are closer to what the name means in real life. Fund is either invested in entrepreneurs’projects or in a risk free asset of which the gross return rate is 1. The project of an entrepreneur requires an investment of $B; and 8 For readers who feel uneasy with a continuum of continuum, here a continuum of measure 1 could mean to represent, for example, one thousand; then there are one million entrepreneurs and one thousand bankers. 9 We assume away the agency problems between the management and equity of banks 6 returns $Z if it succeeds and nothing if it fails. High projects succeed with probability q and low ones with probability q: 1 > q > q > 0: Thus V qZ B is the net present value (NPV) of a high type, V qZ B that of a low type. The proportion of high types is denoted by n, that of low types by n = 1 n. We assume that high type projects have a positive NPV and that on average projects have a negative NPV, that is, V >0 nV + n V : (1) The latter assumption makes bankers’certi…cation service indispensable for generating a positive social value, as will be seen. Moreover, assume that if an entrepreneur expects to get zero pro…t, he will not …nance and run the project.10 The assumption serves only to simplify the exposition, without which low type entrepreneurs could want to run the projects anyway, from which they have nothing to lose, and consequently some uninteresting equilibria would arise. The assumption would not be necessary (i.e. these equilibria would not arise) if we let entrepreneurs have a small amount of capital of their own or incur a little disutility from running the projects, either of which would impose a cost on low types to mix with high types. All bankers are identical in Sections 2 through 5 and the case of heterogenous bankers is examined in Section 6. Each banker has K > 0 units of fund. A unit is de…ned as the sum total of a continuum of measure 1 of dollars; that is, out of 1 unit of fund, $1 can be invested in each and every of a measure 1 continuum of projects.11 We assume bankers’ fund is scarce: K <Vn q q q : (2) This inequality, we will show, commands that the fund of bankers earns a higher return rate than the fund of households. Households, in aggregation, have abundant fund. As a result, not all of their fund is absorbed by entrepreneurs and part of it ‡ows to the risk free asset. It follows that households are satis…ed with expected gross return rate 1. 10 A possible explanation is that he incurs disutility in running the projects and has lexicographic preference over the pro…t and the disutility. 11 Following footnote 9, if a continuum of measure 1 represents 1,000, then 1 unit means 1,000 dollars. 7 Households only know the prior distribution of the types, but bankers have the expertise to evaluate them. In the basic model, we assume bankers perfectly observe the types. What matters of this assumption is not that the observations are noiseless – if banker observe noisy signals of the types, then just rede…ne the signals as the types and all the analysis carries on –but that the accuracy of the observations is given, the choice of which is be examined in Section 4. Given the knowledge di¤erence between bankers and households, the fund provided by bankers is called the informed capital, that provided by households the uninformed capital. To focus on the sector of bankers, we assume that an entrepreneur does not know his type before being evaluated by a banker, but after that he knows the evaluation. Contracting between Entrepreneurs and Bankers If bankers do not provide certi…cation service, that is, their information on entrepreneurs’types is not communicated to households, then by assumption (1), households will not invest in entrepreneurs. As bankers’fund is scarce, most high type projects will be forsaken, which is a huge social loss. In this economy, bankers can provide certi…cation service only by investing enough of their own fund. They could not do it with word of mouth, by simply announcing the evaluations of projects to households, because the economy is essentially static and reputation mechanisms are assumed away.12 On the other hand, if a banker invests enough of her own fund in a project, she must truly think it good. For the purpose of certi…cation, therefore, the entrepreneur-banker contract must involve the investment of the banker’s fund. The contract is characterized by two variables (I; Q), where I is the amount of her fund to be invested and Q the amount of revenue to be repaid when the project succeeds (on its failure, by limited liability, no one gets anything). We call the ratio Q I F as the face rate of return, because it is the return rate that reads from the contract. A contract (I; Q) could be represented as (I; F ); where F = 12 Q : I In fact, even under repeated interactions, reputational mechanisms will not work if q is small enough, that is, if the observed signal, success or failure, is very noisy about the true quality; see the literature on reputation under imperfect monitoring, e.g. Abreu et al (1986) and Abreu et al (1988). 8 Given face rate F , the expected return rate of the banker is qF if the borrower is a high type and is qF if he is a low type. To get the same expected return rate R, the banker charges face rate R=q to a low type and a lower one, R=q; to a high type. If the banker cannot collude with the entrepreneur, given R; the contract to a low type is (I; R=q) and that to a high type is (I; R=q) for any investment amount I, however small it is; and therefore, obtaining even one cent of bank …nance at a low interest rate certi…es the borrower is of high quality. To prevent such a unrealistic scenario, we assume that besides the investment contract, an entrepreneur could have other contracts with the banker, for example, for consulting services, and it is too costly for households to check all the contracts between the two. Under the assumption, for small I, contract (I; R=q) does not certify the entrepreneur is a high type, because he might (over)pay I(R=q R=q) to the banker in another contract. But, given R, contract (I; R=q) with a a su¢ ciently large I certi…es high types, we will show. After an entrepreneur secures an investment contract from a banker, he goes to the market for households’fund. He shows before them the contract, trying to convince them that his project is of high type. If they are convinced, they accept face rate 1=q (namely, for $1 given up today they get back $1=q tomorrow if the project succeeds). Certainly, the projects of which no bankers are willing to take a stake are of quality below the prior average and are hence not invested by households. Timing of Events and De…nition of Equilibrium The timing of today’s events is as below. 1: Each banker posts R, the expected return rate she is to charge for her fund. 2: Each entrepreneur goes to one banker and is evaluated by her, with the evaluation observed by both sides. 3: The entrepreneur submits his demand for her fund. If she accepts it, she signs with him a contract which speci…es the amount of her fund to be invested (I) and the face rate of return (F ). 4: Entrepreneurs, showing the contracts with the bankers if available, go to the market for households’fund. 5. A project is started if the entrepreneur has got $B altogether. 9 In equilibrium, we will show, all the bankers charge the same return rate, R. We can thus de…ne a general equilibrium as below, where for a variable x; we use x b to denote its value in equilibrium. b I; b L) b is an equilibrium if De…nition 1 Pro…le (R; b a high type entrepreneur demands $Ib (i): given the price of the informed capital is R, b of the informed capital and a low type $L; b clears the (ii): given the demands of the two types of entrepreneurs are as above, R b = K: market for the informed capital: nIb + nL 3 Certi…cation by Bank Financing In this section, we show that there is a unique equilibrium in which high types are sorted b whereby all the socially out by the amount of the informed capital invested, that is, Ib 6= L; e¢ cient projects are …nanced. Let us start with how an individual banker provides certi…cation service. Lemma 1 Among the entrepreneurs who come to a banker charging R > 1; the high types demand I(R) = V R qq (3) 1 dollars of her fund, whereas the low types demand L(R) = 0. Thus the high types are certi…ed out. The ex ante expected pro…t of the entrepreneurs is (R) = nV R( qq 1) R qq 1 : (4) The key to the lemma is that high types can sort themselves out by demanding I I(R) dollars of the banker’s fund –then as her fund is more expensive than households’ (R > 1), they only demand I(R); the minimum amount needed for sorting, with the short fall …nanced by cheap households’fund. To see an intuition for the sorting, consider a low type who mimics by demanding $I of the banker’s fund also. He cannot hide his type from the banker, who observes it. Therefore, he must give her a surplus of I(R 1). But by mimicking, he cheats the households and convinces them to …nance the shortfall, $(B I); at face rate 1=q: As his project succeeds actually with probability q; the households lose 10 1 q=q dollar for each dollar invested and overall (B entrepreneur. He, therefore, gets by mimicking V + (B is non-positive if I Note that 0 q=q) dollars to the I) (1 I) (1 q=q) I(R 1); which I(R): (R) < 0; that is, the higher the rate a banker charges, the smaller the pro…t to her entrepreneur customers. Therefore, in equilibrium all the bankers charge the b Then, Condition (ii) of De…nition 1, that of market clearing, commands: same rate, R. With the help of Lemma 1, b + nL(R) b = K: nI(R) q b = ( nV + 1): R q K (5) b > 1. Put back to Lemma 1, in equilibrium high types As K is small by assumption (2), R demand Ib = K ; n b = 0; and the ex ante pro…t of entrepreneurs is low types L b= q q q (nV + K): (6) The equilibrium expounded above is unique: in any equilibrium, by Lemma 1, high b I; b R) b as types are certi…ed out and all the bankers charge the same price, which gives (L; above. To summarize: Proposition 1 For any K, there is a unique equilibrium where Ib = K ; n b = 0 and R b is L given by (5), and all the high types are certi…ed out by bank …nance and thus invested. The analysis so far shows that given bankers’level of screening expertise in terms of the accuracy in which they observe the types, the asset size of bankers (measured by K) does not matter for the asset quality, because bankers only invest in the projects they evaluate as high types (that, however, is not technically given but driven by competition). Yet, we show below, size matters for the choice of expertise level and hence for asset quality. 4 Size, Screening Accuracy, and Asset Quality From this section onwards, bankers’level of screening expertise is not …xed, but chosen by them, and the level is measured by the accuracy of their evaluations, denoted by p 2 [0; 1], modelled below. Thus to the timing of the basic model, we add: 11 Stage 0. Each banker chooses expertise level p, which is publicly observed hereafter. (From it onwards, stages 1 through 5 are the same as in Section 2, namely, bankers post R - then entrepreneurs come to be screened by bankers and sign investment contracts with them if available - then entrepreneurs seek fund from households - …nally the entrepreneurs who have gathered $B start their projects.) The assumption of the level being publicly observed delivers the bene…t that the asymmetric information between bankers and households is concerned only with the evaluations, not with the expertise level. The alternative assumption that p is private information of the banker is to be discussed in Subsection 7.2. The expertise level is modelled as follows. On each project a banker evaluates, she observes a noisy signal se = g or b, which represents a good or bad evaluation, according to the following distribution: Pr(e s = bje q = q) = (p); Pr(e s = gje q = q) = (p): Namely, low types receive bad evaluations with probability (p) and high types receive good evaluations with probability (p): Across the projects she screens, the signals arrive independently. Here p 2 [0; 1] captures the accuracy of the banker’s evaluations and thereby represents the level of her screening expertise. We do not need a speci…c form of (p) and (p); the paper’s analysis is valid so long as they satisfy properties enlisted below with the following notations. Given accuracy p; let qg (p) denote the posterior probability of success of a project conditional on being evaluated good; qb (p) the posterior probability of success of an evaluated bad project; and ng (p) the probability of obtaining a good evaluation.13 Thus, Vg (p) qg (p)Z B denotes the NPV of a evaluated good project; S(p) ng (p)Vg (p) denotes the ex ante social surplus of a project if it is …nanced only when being evaluated good; and d(p) qg (p)=qb (p) denotes the quality dispersion between evaluated good and bad projects. The paper’s analysis only requires the following …ve properties, which are thus assumed: 13 That is, qg (p) = n (p)q+n(1 n (p)+n(1 (p))q (p)) ; qb (p) = n(1 (p))q+n (p)q n(1 (p))+n (p) 12 and ng (p) = n (p) + n (1 (p)): P0: qg (0) = qb (0) = n q + n q; the prior mean, and qg (1) = q and qb (1) = q ; that is, the evaluations are not informative at all at zero accuracy and noiseless at full accuracy. P1. qg0 (p) > 0; that is, the more accurate the evaluations, the higher the probability in which evaluated good projects succeed. P2. d0 (p) > 0; that is, the more accurate the evaluations, the bigger the di¤erence in quality between evaluated good and bad projects. P3. d(p) > 1 for p > 0; that is, this di¤erence is always positive so long as the banker is a little informed. P4. S 0 (p) > 0 and S 00 (p) 0; that is, the marginal social bene…t of more accurate evaluations is positive but decreasing. All these are reasonable properties for a proper modelling of accuracy and are satis…ed for those often used in the relevant literature.14 The banker needs to spend C(p) in order that her evaluations are of accuracy p. Function C( ) is convex over interval [0; 1] and satis…es C 00 ( ) > 0; C(0) = C 0 (0) = 0; and C 0 (1) = 1: And C 0 (p) = o( (1 1p)2 ) at p 1; 15 which ensures the cost does not grow too fast with p. Note that the C(p) is the cost of obtaining screening expertise of accuracy p, not that of observing the type of one project to the accuracy; that is, with C(p) invested, on each project to which the expertise is applied the evaluation is of accuracy p.16 We could add a marginal cost of evaluating a project and let it a¤ect the accuracy of the signal on the project also, which, however, would not qualitatively change the paper’s results. Moreover, to simplify the exposition, we assume C(p) is laid not out of the banker’ fund, but out of the revenue of investing in entrepreneurs; that is, having chosen accuracy p, she still has K units of fund in hand.17 Should C(p) be extracted out of K; none of the papers’results would qualitatively change. 14 The two often used examples are (p) = p; (p) = 1 and (p) = (p) = p+1 2 : They both satisfy all the properties P0-P5. 15 That is, C 0 (p)(1 p)2 ! 0 if p ! 1: 16 This investment in expertise (rather than in acquiring information project by project) is also present in Williamson (1986b) and Hauswald and Marquez (2006). 17 If the expenditure to improve screening accuracy mainly consist in recruiting …nancial experts, then the assumption means the experts are paid not out of the initial fund, but out of the investment revenue, which is indeed in the interest of the banker. 13 Let p is de…ned by Vg (p) = 0: That is, the evaluated good projects have a positive NPV if and only if the accuracy is beyond p. Therefore, any screening expertise of an accuracy below p is useless. A banker, if not choosing an accuracy beyond p; will choose p = 0. In this section we focus on the accuracy choice by bankers at stage 0. Instead of tediously writing down the full de…nition of subgame perfect Nash equilibrium, we take a shortcut. The choice of accuracy is determined by the pro…t associated with each level of accuracy p, which is in turn determined by the return rate charged, R; given the accuracy p, which in turn by bankers’competition for entrepreneurs. Of this competition the market conditions to bankers are summarized by a single variable, the ex ante pro…t to entrepreneurs in equilibrium, b ; because a banker can attract entrepreneurs to her only if her deal (p; R) o¤ers them a pro…t no less than b and in equilibrium she will not o¤er more. Therefore, bankers’choices of accuracy at stage 0 is ruled by the equilibrium de…ned below, where bankers are indexed by j 2 [0; 1]: De…nition 2 A pro…le of (fb pj gj2[0;1] ; b ) forms an equilibrium, if: (i) given entrepreneurs expect to get b ; banker j chooses accuracy pbj : (ii) given banker j has chosen pbj for j 2 [0; 1]; entrepreneurs expect to get b : There is always a unique equilibrium. Depending on the values of parameters, it is either a symmetric equilibrium where pbj all equal some pb > p; or a mixed equilibrium where pbj equals either pb or 0 (i.e. bankers are indi¤erent between being informed and being uninformed). To see that, let us examine how a banker, given the market conditions summarized by b , decides on her screening accuracy. For this exercise, the following remark is useful. To the basic model of Section 2, here we add the ex ante stage for accuracy choice, the subgame after which has been analyzed in Section 3. In order to use the results there for …nding the equilibrium here with backward induction, we only need to rede…ne the signals bankers observe here, g or b, as the types there, high or low. 14 4.1 The Decision of an Individual Banker on Screening Accuracy To …nd out what rate R the banker charges after choosing accuracy p, we need to …nd out what pro…t her deal (p; R) will give to the entrepreneurs who come to her. Lemma 2 Facing deal (p; R); the expected pro…t of the entrepreneurs is (R; p) = S(p) (d(p) 1)R ; d(p)R 1 (7) and the evaluated good entrepreneurs demand V (p) : Rd(p) 1 I(R; p) = (8) Note that this pro…t decreases with the rate charged, but it increases with the accuracy of the banker, p, because a higher p not only generates a higher social surplus (S 0 (p) > 0); but also widen the quality dispersion (d0 (p) > 0); both bene…ting the entrepreneurs.18 Therefore, if obtaining a higher accuracy, the banker can charge a higher return rate, while still attracting entrepreneurs to come. This gives her the incentive to increase accuracy. The return rate charged as a function of accuracy is to be found by equalizing the pro…t the entrepreneurs get from the banker, (R; p); to the pro…t they would get from any other bankers, b ; from which it follows: R(p; b ) = d(p) b b (d(p) 1)S(p) : (9) Note, however, that the banker can always choose not to compete for entrepreneurs and invest her fund in the risk free asset with gross return rate 1. Hence, the gross return rate of her fund is maxfR(p; b ); 1g; while the opportunity cost rate is 1. Therefore, by obtaining accuracy p, her economic pro…t is 18 K (maxfR(p; b ); 1g 1) C(p): Intuitively,the former bene…ts because entrepreneurs get a fraction of the social surplus, the latter because the bigger the quality dispersion, the more easily can high types certify themselves out. 15 With (9), the decision problem of the banker on the choice of accuracy, p; is: max K (maxf 0 p 1 d(p) b b (d(p) 1)S(p) ; 1g 1) C(p): (10) The solution to this problem is either some p > p (so S(p) > 0 and then R > 1); or p = 0, or both. However, Lemma 3 It is impossible that in equilibrium all bankers choose p = 0. Intuitively, if all the other bankers choose to be uninformed, thus unable to provide certi…cation service, then the particular banker is left with all the entrepreneurs as her customers and will get a huge pro…t by serving them all with screening expertise of some accuracy p > p. The equilibrium is thus either symmetric, where bankers’ fund earns a nonnegative net return and bankers all choose the same p > p, or mixed, where bankers’fund earns 0 net return and bankers are indi¤erent between choosing some p > p and being uninformed (p = 0). We focus on the former case, because it is more likely to capture the situation of real life banks in the decade preceding the recent crisis: bankers’fund means to represents bank equity, on which the average return rate in the decade was approximately 20%.19 However, for theoretical completeness, we discuss the mixed equilibrium in Subsection 7.1. 4.2 The Symmetric Equilibrium: Scale up, Quality down In the symmetric equilibrium, all the bankers choose to spend in screening expertise, driven by R > 1: Then, problem (10) becomes: ( b ; K) max K ( 0 p 1 b d(p) b (d(p) 1)S(p) 1) C(p): (11) Let its solution denoted by (K; b ); which then satis…es the following …rst order condition: 19 Kb 1)S 0 (b p) + d0 (b p)(S(b p) b ) = C 0 (b p): 2 [d(b p) b (d(b p) 1)S(b p)] (d(b p) See "Promises that proved ultimately empty", The Financial Times, Jan. 9, 2012. 16 (12) This equation elaborates condition (i) of De…nition 2. It is essentially the incentive compatibility constraint for bankers to spend in screening expertise, whereas ( b ; K) 0 is the individual rationality constraint (IR), which implies S(p) > 0, that is, pb > p: Now elaborate condition (ii) of De…nition 2. Lemma 4 If all the bankers have chosen accuracy pb > p; then the equilibrium pro…t of entrepreneurs, b ; is: p) 1 b = d(b (S(b p) + K): d(b p) (13) The symmetric equilibrium, (b p; b ), is the solution of the simultaneous equations of (12) and (13). Proposition 2 (i): The simultaneous equations of (12) and (13) has a unique solution, (b ps ; b s ): Therefore, the symmetric equilibrium uniquely exists if and only if namely, the IR is satis…ed. (ii): If db ps dK ( b s ; K) 0, < 0, that is, the equilibrium accuracy decreases with K. ( b s ; K) < 0; we establish the existence of a unique mixed equilibrium and char- acterize it in Section 7. Thus, the equilibrium always uniquely exists. To understand result (ii), note that K denotes both the individual stock and aggregate stock of bankers’fund. Hence, an increase in K by one unit means that each and every banker increases her fund stock by one unit. This change will generate two e¤ects upon bankers’ incentive to improve screening accuracy, both formalized below, which drive Proposition 2(ii). Lemma 5 @ (K; b ) @K @ (K; b ) @K > 0 and @ (K; b ) @b < 0; where (K; b ) is the solution to problem (11). > 0 captures the increasing return to fund scale in improving screening exper- tise: The more fund a banker has, the more extra pro…t she earns from an increment in the interest rate, and hence the bigger the marginal pro…t of improving accuracy; indeed, the left hand side (LHS) of (12), which represents the marginal pro…t, is in proportion to K. 17 @ (K; b ) @b < 0 captures the equilibrium e¤ect, which works in the opposite direction: The bigger the aggregate stock of the informed capital (K), the higher the equilibrium pro…t to entrepreneurs ( b ) (by 13), which reduces the marginal pro…t of a higher accuracy to all bankers as follows. Given p, a banker screens a mass entrepreneurs, from each and every of whom, she gets S(p) K I(p;R(p; b )) N (p; b ) of b ; the di¤erence of the social value of his project minus the pro…t she gives up to him. The marginal pro…t then consists of two parts: Np0 (p; b )(S(p) b ); from the expansion of scale, and N (p; b )S 0 (p); from the widening of pro…t margin. Both parts diminish with b : The former is because the pro…t margin, S(p) b ; diminishes with b : The latter is because so does the scale: the higher the pro…t to the entrepreneurs ( b ); the lower the rate charged (R); then the more of the banker’s fund demanded by each evaluated good entrepreneur for certi…cation purpose (IR0 < 0 by 8) and hence the smaller the scale. The two e¤ects are thus in con‡ict. In net, the proposition asserts, the latter one dominates. Hence if all bankers increase their fund by one unit, the screening accuracy of all goes down. As a result, the default risk of all their assets goes up: although bankers still invest only in evaluated good projects, with less accurate screening, a smaller proportion of them is actually good.20 Here comes a main result of the paper: if each and every bank expands its credit supply, then the quality of each and every bank’s assets goes down. An obvious way for bankers to expand credit supply is to borrow from households, which is examined in the next section, where we show that with all bankers expanding credit supply via leverage, their screening accuracy all goes down and hence so does their asset quality, as suggested by Proposition 2 (ii). 5 Leverage of Bankers So far bankers do not borrow from households and what they invest is their own fund, that is, they are running wholly-equitied banks. In this section, we add the stage when bankers borrow from households, which we assume occurs before they choose their screen20 Mathematically, the default probability of the projects they invest is 1 ps qg0 db dK > 0 because qg0 ( ) > 0 (by P1). 18 qg (b ps ) and d(1 qg (b ps )) dK = ing level.21 In this model economy, bankers are driven to borrow. On becoming informed, bankers earn the rate of the informed capital, which is above 1, on the asset side, while they repay households with the rate of the uninformed capital, which is 1, on the liability side. The rate gap gives the pro…t margin of borrowing.22 In fact, individual bankers take this pro…t margin as given, and so long as it is positive, they want to borrow as much as possible. But if they borrow too much, they will be susceptible to risk shifting problems, as in Jensen and Meckling (1976). 5.1 The Risk Shifting Problem and Leverage Ratio The analysis hitherto does not depend on how the risks of individual projects correlate. To bring forth the risk shifting problem, in this section we assume that the risks of projects are correlated and cannot be diversi…ed away.23 To simplify the exposition, actually, we assume the risks of projects are perfectly correlated. Speci…cally, ex ante there are three possible states of the world, f ; 1; 2g, with probability 1 q; q q, and q: In state ; no projects succeed; in state 1, only high type projects succeed and low types fail; and in state 2, both types succeed. So high type projects succeed in both states 1 and 2, thus with probability q; and low types succeed in state 2 only, thus with probability q: Suppose a banker borrows D units fund from households at face rate f , namely, by repaying them overall Df whenever possible. When D is too large, the banker could invest in evaluated bad projects at a lower expected return rate but a higher face rate than would be obtained by investing in evaluated good projects. Let F be the face rate of investing in evaluated good projects, that is F R ; qg and F 0 be that of investing in evaluated bad projects, which succeed with probability qb : Then, for some 21 22 2 (0; 1); F 0 = ((1 ) qg + )F; qb (14) If it instead occurred afterwards, the results of this section would not be qualitatively a¤ected. In the paper, bankers are assumed not to issue outside equities to laymen, possibly due to some friction of costly state veri…cation in the manner of Townsend (1979), Diamond (1984), and Gale and Hellwig (1985). 23 Otherwise, as each banker …nances a continuum of projects and issues debt contracts to households, the risks on her asset side will be completely diversi…ed away and no risk shifting problems will arise. 19 because F 0 lies somewhere between F and qg F . qb On the one hand, the banker rejects any face rate below F ; on the other hand, evaluated bad entrepreneurs reject any face rate above qg F ; qb which gives the banker the same expected rate R, and thus by the argument for Lemma 1, makes them get 0 pro…t by mimicking good entrepreneurs. Lemma 6 A banker who borrows D; obtains accuracy p and charges R(p) does not invest in evaluated bad projects if and only if D K (1 (q q)f 1 )R(p) d(p) 1 )R(p) (1 d(p) L(p): (15) If the inequality holds, the banker repays her debt with probability q: By the lemma, the expected return rate to the households who lend to bankers is qf: Households are satis…ed with expected return rate 1. Hence 1 f= : q 5.2 (16) The Characterization of Equilibrium with Leverage b the leverage ratio, L; b Proposition 3 (i): In equilibrium, the amount of borrowing, D; and the screening accuracy, pbL ; solve for (D; L; p) of the following simultaneous equations: (17) D=K L 1 S(p) d0 (p) S(p) ( + 1)[S 0 (p) + ( d(p) K + D d(p) d(p) 1 L= K 1)( S(p) + 1) K (d(p) q q d(p)2 q (d(p) 1) : D)] = C 0 (p) (18) (19) (ii): The expansion of credit supply by all bankers through leverage lowers all their screening accuracy and their asset quality: pbL < pbs : (iii): Households’ fund ‡ows to entrepreneurs both directly and via bankers, that is, direct …nance and intermediated …nance coexist. Equation (17) holds because given the positive rate gap, each banker wants to borrow as much as possible, thus reaching the upper bound commanded by the risk shifting problem. 20 The formula of (18) shows that debt capital, D; plays the same role as equity capital, K, in determining equilibrium choice of accuracy. The accuracy choice, intuitively, results from the balance between two forces: the increasing return to fund scale and the equilibrium e¤ect, in both of which D and K play the same role. The latter is driven by the increasing of b with the aggregate supply of the informed capital, to which how it is …nanced by debt and equity is irrelevant. For the former, by Lemma 6, the probability of debt being repaid, …xed at q; is independent of the accuracy choice, p. Hence so is the cost of debt (D), as is the (opportunity) cost of equity (K). On the other hand, debt and equity contribute in equal terms to a banker’s revenue ((K + D)R) and thus to her marginal revenue ((K + D)R0 (p)): Therefore, D and K contribute in equal terms to the increasing return to fund scale, which implies that, given b ; a banker’s choice of accuracy is p = (K + D; b ): (20) As borrowed capital plays the same role as equity capital in determining equilibrium choice of accuracy, the expansion of credit supply through leverage produces the same e¤ect as an increase in K does, which, by Proposition 2, is the lowering of accuracy. So arises result (ii). Result (iii) arises because entrepreneurs want bank …nance only to the extent of certifying they are evaluated good by bankers, which is in turn because bank …nance, as the informed capital, is more expensive than the uninformed capital, otherwise bankers have no incentives to spend in screening expertise and become informed. 6 Heterogeneous Bankers In this section, we remove the assumption of identical bankers and deliver two points. (i) The increasing return to fund scale advantages big banks: the bigger the bank, the higher the level of screening expertise and the asset quality. (ii) There is a complementarity between leverage and screening expertise: the higher the level of screening expertise, the more the bank can borrow; then the larger the scale of its fund, which, due to the increasing return to fund scale, feedbacks to drive the bank to choose a higher expertise level. This complementarity strengthens the scale advantage explained by point (i). These 21 two points bear on the industrial organization of the banking sector. So far all bankers have the same amount of fund. Now in this section we consider the case where banker j has fund Kj for j 2 [0; 1]: For banker j, her problem of deciding on accuracy is sill described by (11), with K replaced by Kj . Therefore, her choice of accuracy is pj = (Kj ; b ): (21) We put the remainder of the characterization of the equilibrium in the proof of the following lemma, which extends Proposition 2(ii) to the case of heterogenous bankers. Lemma 7 If fKj gj2[0;1] are increased in such a way that leaves bankers’ market shares unchanged, then the screening accuracies of all bankers go down. But the focus of the section is the comparisons across banks within an economy. By (21) and Lemma 5, if Kj > Ki ; then pj > p: This is our point (i). Intuitively, within an economy, all the banks face the same market conditions (characterized by b ); the comparison between them is thus not subject to the general equilibrium e¤ect, but ruled by the increasing return to fund scale only; and therefore, the larger the scale, the higher the level of screening expertise. Let us further incorporate the borrowing by bankers. Then by (20), banker j’s choice of accuracy is pj = (Kj + Dj ; b ); where her borrowing Dj = Kj L(pj ) by (17). Therefore, Substitute (16) for f into (15), pj = (Kj (1 + L(pj )); b ): L(p) = (1 (1 q ) q 1 )R(p) d(p) : 1 (1 d(p) )R(p) (22) (23) And L0 (p) > 0 because both d0 (p) > 0 and R0 (p) > 0: Intuitively, the higher the screening accuracy (p), the starker the di¤erence in quality between evaluated good and bad projects (d) and the higher the rate charged (R); both leading to a bigger value destruction by risk shifting (R qb F 0 = (1 1 )R d by 14) and therefore a smaller incentive to do that, which allows for a larger leverage ratio. 22 Equation (22) then points to a complementarity between screening accuracy and leverage: A higher accuracy (p) induces a higher leverage (L) due to L0 (p) > 0; while a higher leverage induces a higher accuracy due to the increasing return to fund scale. This is our point (ii). The complementarity implies: Proposition 4 If Kj > Ki ; then the leverage ratio Lj > Li : The proposition delivers: Prediction (a): The bigger the bank, the higher the leverage ratio. It is empirically supported by Liang and Rhoades (1991), McAllistera and McManus (1993), Akhavein et al. (1997), Demsetz and Strahan (1997), and Berger (1998). This literature, however, explains it via the bene…t of diversi…cation á la Diamond (1984). These two lines of argument diverge at the implication on the link between the size of a bank and the quality of individual loans it issues. The argument of diversi…cation implies no links between the two, whereas in the present paper loans of bigger banks are of higher quality, because the borrowers are evaluated good to a bigger accuracy, due to the increasing return to fund scale. That is, Prediction (b): The bigger the bank, the higher the quality of its individual assets (measured by the default probability) and the higher the level of certi…cation it provides in the sense that obtaining its fund means a higher quality. It is empirically supported by Ross (forthcoming) who documents that the loans from three US dominant banks (J.P. Morgan Chase, Bank of American, and Citigroup) induce the borrowers’stock prices to jump higher and are issued at lower interest rates and "less likely to be protected by a borrowing base", and the stock price jump is larger when the borrower is opaque, altogether suggesting that these banks "provide a higher level of certi…cation". Also Hao (2003) documents an inverse correlation between bank size and loan yield spread, suggesting bigger banks pick higher quality borrowers. Finally, the increasing return to scale commands small banks are edged out of the banking business. Banker i’s pro…t, ( b ; Ki ); de…ned in (11), is increasing with the scale 23 of her fund, Ki : If the scale is too small such that ( b ; Ki ) 0; then the banker is edged out of business and choose to be uninformed. Leverage, by Proposition 4, ampli…es the increasing return to scale and exacerbates the disadvantage of small banks. Moreover, they are squeezed further if due to some technological or institutional shocks, all banks could be leveraged more. This occurs, in the paper, with a decrease in is the common factor for all bankers’leverage. The paper …nds that j @L j= @ increases with p and thus with the scale of the banker. That is, if 1 q=q; which (1 ( (1 1 )R(p) d(p) 1 )R(p))2 d(p) decreases, the bigger the bank, the larger is the increment in leverage ratio and the further is its scale advantage augmented, consequently the more small banks are edged out and the more concentrated the banking sector becomes. That is: Prediction (c): A common shock allowing bigger leverage for all banks edges small banks out. Therefore, the upward trend of bank leverage is a driving force for the trend of consolidation in the banking sector. Both trends are well empirically documented.24 Especially, consistent with the paper’s explanation, one important reason Berger, Demsetz and Strahan (1999) attribute to the consolidation in the US over 1988-1997, when the number of banks falls by 30%, is the improvement in the …nancial conditions, like low interest rates, which makes it easier to raise debt for M&As; and Berger, Kashyap and Scalise (1995) …nd deregulation of deposit ceiling rate contributes to the consolidation over 1979-1994 because it allows banks to absorb more deposit. 7 Further Discussions In this section we characterize for the case of identical bankers the equilibrium when it is mixed and discuss the assumption that the screening accuracy of a banker is her private information. 24 The former is documented by Berger et al (1995) (…gure 1, for US over 1840-1990), Saunders and Wilson (1995) (…gures 4-6, for UK, Canda and US over 1893-1991), Hortlund (2005) (…gure 2; for Sweden 1870-2001), and Miles et al (2011) (for UK over 1880-2004), the latter by Berger, Kashyap and Scalise (1995) (for US over 1979-1994), Saunders and Wilson (1995) (…gures 2 and 3, for Canada and UK over 1893-1991), Berger, Demsetz and Strahan (1999) (for US over 1988-1997), and Jones and Critch…eld (2004) (for US over 1984-2003). 24 7.1 The Case Where the Equilibrium Is Mixed By Proposition 2, if ( b s ; K) < 0; the symmetric equilibrium does not exist, so in equilibrium not all the bankers invest to be informed, whereas by Lemma 3, it is not possible that no bankers invest. Therefore, the equilibrium, if it exists, must be mixed, with 2 (0; 1) fraction of bankers choosing to be informed while the remainder to be uninformed. The equilibrium is characterized as follows. First, ex ante, bankers are indi¤erent between the two choices, that is, ( b m ; K) = 0; (24) where b m is the ex ante pro…t to entrepreneurs in the mixed equilibrium. Second, those bankers who choose to be informed solve the same problem, (11), and their choice of accuracy is, as denoted, (K; b ): With b = b m in the equilibrium, the equilibrium accuracy is then pbm = (K; b m ): (25) Third, in the mixed equilibrium, the aggregate informed capital is K instead of K: Therefore, by (13), the equilibrium pro…t to entrepreneurs, b m ; satis…es: pm ) 1 b m = d(b (S(b pm ) + K) d(b pm ) (26) The mixed equilibrium, ( b m ; pbm ; ); is characterized by the simultaneous equations of (24), (25) and (26). Lemma 8 If ( b s ; K) < 0; then the mixed equilibrium exists uniquely. Proposition 2(i) and Lemma 8 imply that the equilibrium always exists and is unique. b 1) = q nV Note that in Section 2, banker’s economic pro…t is K(R q q q K q and decreasing with K, which is driven by the equilibrium e¤ect that the more amply is the informed capital supplied, the cheaper it becomes and the smaller the pro…t to bankers. Suggested by this feature, the symmetric equilibrium is likely to be the case when K is small, the mixed equilibrium the case when K is big. Intuitively, when the aggregate bankers’fund is scarce, the competition between bankers is weak, the interest rate of the informed capital is high, and all this fund is transformed into the informed capital. With the bankers’ 25 fund becoming more and more abundant, not all of it become informed capital, bringing us into the domain of the mixed equilibrium In the mixed equilibrium, the change of screening accuracy with respect to K is not monotonic any more, as was described in Proposition 2(ii). Lemma 9 db pm dK < 0 if and only if for which a su¢ cient condition is: Sb bm bm (log R)0p < ; (log S)0p (27) Sb ); Sb b m b > min(2; R (28) b is its value in the equilibrium where R as a function of p and b is de…ned by (9), and R and Sb is the equilibrium social surplus of a project. An intuition for (28) is that as we saw after Proposition 2, the decrease in screening accuracy with K is driven by the general equilibrium e¤ect; and in the mixed equilibrium, the strength of this e¤ect could be measured by the expected return rate of the informed capital, R. To see this point, bear in mind that the e¤ect is due to the increasing of the ex ante pro…t to entrepreneurs, b ; with K. Suppose K increases by K: Were b …xed, the pro…t of bankers who invest in screening expertise would be increased by (R 1) K by the envelop theorem. However, in the mixed equilibrium, their pro…t is settled at 0. Therefore, this supposed increment all goes to entrepreneurs (as households always break even). That is, the increases in b is roughly (R 1) K; and is thus proportional to R 1: Therefore, if R is big enough, as (28) is satis…ed, the general equilibrium e¤ect will be so strong as to overwhelm the force of the increasing return to scale, and thus push the screening accuracy down. Actually, this intuition suggests that db pm dK > 0 if K is large enough; therefore, overall, the equilibrium screening accuracy as a function of aggregate bankers’fund is in a U shape. To see that inequality (27) will be reversed, thus a large K implies a small db pm dK > 0; when K is large, note that ; the proportion of bankers who invest to be informed, and 26 thus a big 1 ; the mass of the entrepreneurs served by each banker. Therefore, from each project screened, a banker only gets a small surplus (in order to compensate the cost of investing in screening). That is, Sb be reversed. 7.2 bm 0 and b m b whereby inequality (27) will S; Unobservability of Screening Accuracy Above we assume every banker’s screening accuracy is publicly observed. This assumption is made mainly to gain tractability, but also because it reasonably captures real life. There are reasons to believe that a bank’s screening accuracy is public information in real life. First, this accuracy could be recovered from the data of its balance sheet, particularly the default rate of the loans it made to the real sectors. Second, it is re‡ected in the reputation of the bank, particularly their reputation of hunting good deals. Third, if the spending in screening expertise consists mainly in hiring reputably talented bankers, the relocation of them is often exposed by the media, for example, Financial Times. If the accuracy is assumed private information of the banker, the major di¢ culty is that the equilibrium will be very sensitive to o¤ equilibrium assumptions. Suppose a banker thinks all the other bankers obtain accuracy pb: For it to be the equilibrium accuracy , the banker must get more from choosing the same accuracy , pb; than from choosing an o¤-equilibrium accuracy . The o¤-equilibrium pro…t, however, is very sensitive to what is assumed on how the banker invests her residual fund if she could not …nd enough evaluated good projects from the entrepreneurs coming to her in equilibrium.25 Two possibilities have been explored. One is that the banker could lower the face rate a little, by which she attracts more entrepreneurs than is supposed in equilibrium (i.e. a continuum of measure 25 If p is private information, in and o¤ the equilibrium path, the banker screens a measure 1 continuum of entrepreneurs, of whom ng (p) are evaluated good, each demanding $I(b pe ); such that ng (b p)I(b p) = K: Note the demand only depends on pbe ; laymen’s rational expectation of pb (all this is to convince them) and hence does not change with the actual screening quality of the banker. Therefore, if ng (p) < ng (b p); the overall demand of her capital by all the evaluated good entrepreneurs, ng (p)I(b p); is smaller than K and she needs to consider how to invest the residual K ng (p)I(b p) units of her fund. By contrast, if p is publicly observed, as we studied, in the subgame where ng (p) < ng (b p); there will be measure continuum of entrepreneurs coming to the banker such that ng (p)I(p) = K, that is, the overall demand of her capital equals K on and o¤ equilibrium path. 27 1); the other is that she has to invest the residual fund in the risk free asset. The two assumptions lead to opposite results.26 Another di¢ culty in connection with the assumption of the accuracy being private information is that however a banker invests her residual fund if she has chosen an o¤equilibrium accuracy, her asset will be di¤erent from that of all the other bankers (who obtain the equilibrium accuracy). Then what stops households (and entrepreneurs) inferring from this di¤erence her actual accuracy? If they do, the accuracy will, in e¤ect, become observable to households and entrepreneurs, as was assumed. 8 Conclusion In a general equilibrium framework where bank …nancing certi…es the good type of the borrower, the paper examines the choice of banks on the level of screening expertise and identi…es two causal links between scale and quality of bank assets. One is the increasing return to fund scale in attaining screening expertise, which commands that the bigger the bank, the higher the level of its screening expertise and thus the higher the quality of its assets. The other is the general equilibrium e¤ect, which commands that the larger the aggregate supply of bank …nance, the smaller the rate it earns, which dampens the incentives of all banks to spend in screening expertise and consequently lowers all their asset quality. If each and every bank enlarges credit supply simultaneously, the two forces are in con‡ict; the paper shows that the latter force dominates and thus in net the asset quality of each and every bank goes down. Furthermore, the paper shows that banks are driven to enlarge credit supply through leverage, by the gap in rate between the informed capital and the uninformed capital. In the paper this intermediated …nance stands side by side with the direct …nance of entrepreneurs by households. Lastly, the paper …nds a positive feedback between a bank’s leverage and its level of screening expertise: a higher level of the expertise enables it to be leveraged more and to enlarge its asset scale further, which, due to the increasing return to scale, feeds back to drive it to choose a higher level of screening expertise. This positive feedback has 26 The detailed analysis could be obtained upon request. 28 important implications on the industrial organization of the banking sector. Particularly, it implies that leverage uprising is a force driving consolidation in the sector. Appendix: The Proofs For Lemma 1: Proof. Two considerations pin down I(R): First, high types can sort themselves out by demanding I I(R) of the banker’s fund. If a low type mimics by demanding $I of her fund, then the banker, knowing the low quality of his project, will charge him face rate R q and ask him to repay $ RI when he succeeds. By mimicking, the low type at best q convinces households that his project is of high type, so that they are willing to …nance the shortfall, $(B I); at face rate 1q ; thus for face value $ B q I . Therefore, by mimicking, the low type obtains, in the case of success, Z RI q B I : q Mimicking delivers zero pro…t to him if Z RI q B I q 0,I I(R): (29) Second, as R > 1; the banker’s fund is more expensive than households’. Therefore, the high types only demand the minimum of the amounts by which they can sort their type out (and …nance the short fall with the cheap households’fund). By (29), they demand exactly I = I(R): Low types, as their types is sorted out, will get zero pro…t if they enter …nancing. Then, they do not even enter …nancing as we assumed, that is, they demand nothing of the banker’s fund. By demanding I(R) of the banker’s fund, a high type sorts himself out and is not mixed with low types, whereby he surrenders 0 surplus to household investors, but a surplus of I(R)(R 1) to the banker. (Note that If the high type were mixed with low types, households would demand a surplus from him to compensate their loss in the low types mixed with him.) His expected pro…t is thus V I(R)(R 1); which times n; the probability of being among high types, gives the ex ante pro…t of the entrepreneurs who come to the banker. For Lemma 2: 29 Proof. Note that for entrepreneurs coming to a particular banker who o¤ers (p; R), the circumstance in this section is isomorphic to that studied in Section 2, by rede…ning the signal observed, g or b, as the type. Therefore, we have: (MapB): The results concerned with individual bankers, such as (3), (4), and (29), can be applied here by substituting high type there with good evaluation here, low type with bad evaluation, n with ng ; q with qg , q with qb ; and V with Vg : Applying (MapB) to (4), we …nd the ex ante pro…t of the entrepreneurs coming to her, (R; p); is ng Vg R( qqgb 1) R qqgb 1 Then with notations S(p) = ng (p)Vg (p) and d(p) = : qg (p) ; qb (p) (7) arises. Similarly, applying (MapB) to (3), we …nd the demand of the evaluated good entrepreneurs is as given by (8). For Lemma 3: Proof. If all bankers choose to be uninformed, then no projects will be …nanced by assumption (1) and thus b = 0: We show that if b < d(1) 1 S(1), d(1) a banker gets an in…nitely large pro…t –impossible in equilibrium –in the sense that the value of problem (10) is in…nite. Mathematically, that is obvious for b > 0; because the denominator in the objective function, d(p) b (d(p) 1)S(p); equals 0, at some p0 < 1; and therefore the value of the problem is in…nite. Let us provide an economic argument also. If b < q q nV q ; then b = d(p0 ) d(p0 ) 1 S(p0 ) for some p0 2 [p; 1) because d( ) 1 S( d( ) d(1) 1 S(1) d(1) = ) is increasing as both d0 ( ) > 0 and S 0 ( ) > 0: Then a banker can both charge R = 1; thus reaping an in…nitely large pro…t, and attract all the entrepreneurs by giving them more than b . On her deal (p; R); the entrepreneurs coming to her expect to obtain, by (7), (R; p) = which increases with p; decreases with R, and is thus always bigger than limR!1 (R; p): Therefore, if she o¤ers p = p0 + coming to her get more than b : d( ) 1 S( d( ) (1; p0 + ) = ) is increasing as noted above. (d(p) 1)R S(p); d(p)R 1 d(p) 1 S(p) = d(p) < 1 and R = 1; the entrepreneurs d(p) 1 S(p)jp=p0 + d(p) > d(p0 ) 1 S(p0 ) d(p0 ) = b , as For Lemma 4: Proof. In the case of symmetric equilibrium, note that for the whole economy, the circumstance from stage 1 onward is isomorphic to that studied in Section 2, if we map 30 the signal observed, g or b, to the type, high or low. Therefore, the results of Section 2 concerned with equilibrium, such as (5) and (6), can be applied here by substituting high type with good evaluation, low type with bad evaluation, n with nbg ; q with qbg , q with qbb ; and V with Vbg :27 Apply this mapping to (6), and we …nd the ex ante equilibrium pro…t of entrepreneurs is b = qbg qbg qbb (b ng Vbg + K); which becomes, with notations S(p) = ng Vg and d(p) = qg (p) , qb (p) (13). For Proposition 2: Proof. for (i): The proof applies @ ( b ;K) @b < 0; a property given in Lemma 5. It su¢ ces to show that the following simultaneous equations of (b p; b ) have a unique solution: ( b ; K) p) 1 b = d(b (S(b p) + K) d(b p) pb = g(b p; K) Or equivalently, the following equation has a unique solution for p over [0; 1] : p = (g(p; K); K): This is equivalent to f (p) p (g(p; K); K) has a unique root over [0; 1], which we are going to prove by showing the following three claims. (a) f 0 > 0: Actually f 0 = 1 @g @p @ ( b ;K) @b @g @p > 1 because > 0 since both d0 ( ) > 0 and S 0 ( ) > 0: (b) f (1) > 0 : At p = 1; b = b 1 d(1) 1 (S(1) + K) d(1) > @ ( b ;K) @b < 0 by Lemma 5, and d(1) 1 S(1): d(1) For this value of b , the LHS of (12) < 1 with p ! 1; whereas the RHS goes to 1, and therefore its solution ( b 1 ; K) < 1: It follows that f (1) = 1 (c) f (p0 ) < 0; where p0 is the root of ( b 1 ; K) > 0: g(1; 0) = g(p0 ; K): First, p0 < 1: This, given forward, as 27 @g @K @g @p > 0; is equivalent to g(1; 0) < g(1; K); which is straight- > 0: Second, we show that since we assumed C 0 (p) = o( (1 1p)2 ) at p For f (p) (a function of p), fb f (b p): 31 1; (g(1; 0); K) = 1: For b = g(1; 0) = 1 , (1 p)2 order of d(1) 1 S(1); d(1) at p 1; the LHS of (12) is in the whereas the RHS, by the assumption, is in the order of o( (1 1p)2 ) and thus dominated by the LHS. It follows that the solution of problem (11) is p = 1: The two points put together, f (p0 ) = p0 (g(p0 ; K); K) = p0 (g(1; 0); K) = p0 1 < 0. By claims (a), the root of f (p) = 0 is unique. By claims (b) and (c), it exists in (p0 ; 1): For (ii): In the symmetric equilibrium, the accuracy of all bankers, pbs ; is to be found by substituting b from (13) into (12); that is, pbs is the root for p of the following equation: d0 (p) S(p) 1 S(p) 0 ( + 1)(S (p) + ( d(p) K d(p) d(p) 1 It implicitly de…nes pbs as a function of K: K)) = C 0 (p): (30) Denote the left hand side term by X(p; K). Then, by implicit function theorem, db ps dK = db ps dK < 0; it su¢ ces to prove @X @K [ ( @X @p @X @K C 00 )] 1 : Obviously @X @p < 0 as S(p) > 0 and d0 ( ) > 0. To prove d(p) 1 (S(p) d(p) C 00 < 0: Let g(p; K) + K), that is, b = g(b p; K): Then, X(p; K) = Y (p; g(p; K)); where Y (p; b ) denotes the left hand side of (12). Therefore, Lemma 5) and @g @p @X @p = @Y @p + @Y @g @ b @p < > 0: It follows that @Y @p , because @X @p C 00 < @Y @p @Y @b < 0 (to be shown in the proof of C 00 : And @Y @p C 00 < 0 holds true, as it is the second order condition of maximization problem (11). For Lemma 5: Proof. Denote the left hand side term of (12) by Y (p; b ) as we did in the last @ ( b ;K) @K proof. Then, by implicit function theorem, @Y @b [ ( @Y @p that show that @Y @p @Y @K Y K = C 00 < 0 at p = ( b ; K) [ ( @Y @p C 00 )] 1 and @ ( b ;K) @b = @Y < 0. @b (d(e p) 1)S 0 (e p) b + [d(e p) b (d(e p) 1)S(e p)]2 > 0 and d(1) 1 S(1) d(1) pe. Therefore, to prove the lemma, it su¢ ces to The former is straightforward. To show the latter, note d0 (e p) (S b ) b ; [d b (d 1)S]2 1)S 0 (e p) > 0 and b ) b f[d b both terms are to be shown decreasing b [d(e p) b (d(e p) 1)S(e p)]2 decreases with b for (shown in the proof of Lemma 3) and thus bigger than For the second, d0 (e p) > 0 and f [d b(S(d (S @Y @K C 00 )] 1 : The second order condition of the maximization problem (11) implies with b : For the …rst, (d(e p) b > = (d 1)S]2 g0 , (S b)b 1)S]2 g0b < 0 , f(S 2 b )[d b (d 1)S] < 2d(S only if S > b , namely if bankers get positive surplus S screened and that d b (d b ) b g0 [d b (d(e p) 1) S(e p): d(e p) (d 1)S]2 < b ) b : Note that >0 b from each and every project 1)S > 0 in equilibrium by Lemma 3. Therefore, the last inequality of the chain holds true if S 2 b < 0: If S 32 2 b > 0; the left hand side of that 2 b )d b < d(S inequality is smaller than (S b ) b < 2d(S b ) b ; the right hand side. For Lemma 6: Proof. Suppose out of K + D units of fund under her deployment (K of her own and D borrowed) the banker invests M in evaluated bad projects and K + D M in evaluated good ones. In state , no projects succeed and no one gets anything. In state 1, high type projects succeed, but low types fail. By the law of large numbers, out of all the evaluated good projects, the proportion of high types is Pr(e q = qje s = g), s = b): Hence, in while that proportion out of the evaluated bad projects is Pr(e q = qje state 1; proportion Pr(e q = qje s = g) of the investment in the evaluated good projects succeeds, so does the proportion Pr(e q = qje s = b) of the investment in the evaluated bad projects. Success delivers $F for each dollar put in the former investment and $F 0 for each dollar put in the latter investment. Therefore, the revenue of the banker in state 1 is (K + D M ) Pr(e q = qje s = g) F + M Pr(e q = qje s = b) F 0 . And her liability is Df: Her pro…t is then: maxf(K + D s = g) F + M Pr(e q = qje s = b) F 0 M ) Pr(e q = qje Df; 0g b (M ): In state 2, all her projects succeed. A dollar invested in an evaluated good project returns $F and a dollar invested in an evaluated bad one returns $F 0 . Hence the banker’s pro…t is M )F + M F 0 (K + D Df g (M ): Altogether, her expected pro…t, by investing M 2 [0; K+D] units fund in the evaluated bad projects, is (M ) = (q q) b (M ) + q g (M ). This function has two local maximizer, M = 0 and M = K + D, as follows. If M is small enough such that b (M ) 0, then (M ) = (K+D M )F f(q q) Pr(e q = qje s = g)+qg+M F 0 f(q q) Pr(e q = qje s = b)+qg D qf: Note that (q similarly (q q) Pr(e q = qje s = g) + q = q Pr(e q = qje s = g) + q(e q = qje s = g) = qg and q) Pr(e q = qje s = b) + q = qb : Therefore, in this case, 33 (M ) = (K + D)qg F M (qg F qb F 0 ) D qf and decreases with M because qg F > qb F 0 by (14) (namely risk shifting brings about a lower expected return rate). Thus the maximum occurs at M = 0: If M is not so small that b (M ) = 0; then (M ) = q((K + D)F + M (F 0 F) Df ) and increases with M because F 0 > F by (14) (namely risk shifting brings about a higher face rate). Thus the maximum occurs for this case at M = K + D: To prevent the banker from investing in the evaluated bad projects, it commands (0) (K + D), which, by substituting (14) for F 0 and noting F = R , qg gives rise to (15). The argument above shows also that, so long as bankers do not invest in any evaluated bad projects, their debt is fully repaid in both states 1 and 2; thus with probability q: For Proposition 3: Proof. (i): As was seen at the beginning of the section, each banker wants to borrow as much as possible, given there is a positive rate gap. Therefore, each banker borrows to the upper bound, that is, D = K L(pe ); (31) where pe is households’s expectation of the accuracy; it is a functions of pe because borrowing is assumed to occur before the accuracy choice is made.28 A particular banker then has K + D units of fund in hand to invest in entrepreneurs. Her economic pro…t is (K + D) qg F D qf K: The expected rate charged, R = qg F; as was shown in Section 3, is given by (9), in order to attract entrepreneurs coming to her. Her problem of choosing accuracy p is: max(K + D) p d(p) b b (d(p) 1)S(p) D qf K C(p): The accuracy chosen, denoted by pbL ; satis…es the same FOC as (12) except that K there is replaced by K + D here, that is, It implies (20). 28 (K + D) b 1)S 0 (p) a0 (p)( b S(p)) = C 0 (p): 2 b [a(p) (a(p) 1)S(p)] (a(p) (32) If borrowing occured after the investment (but before the charging of rate), then D would be a function of p (namely D = KL(p)) in the banker’s problem of choosing the quality. The results would be qualitatively the same, though the analysis would be more complex. 34 On the other hand, the aggregate fund under bankers’deployment is expanded through leverage from K to K + D, by (13), the equilibrium pro…t of entrepreneurs is pL ) 1 b = d(b (S(b pL ) + K + D): L d(b p ) (33) Note that both in (32) and in (33), which capture respectively the increasing return to scale and the general equilibrium e¤ect, D plays the same role as K. Thus, the accuracy choice depends only on the asset sizes of bankers, not on the composition of their liabilities. Put (32) and (33) together. The same characterization of equilibrium accuracy as (30) is derived, except that K there is replaced with K + D here, which gives (18). The last piece needed to complete the characterization of the equilibrium is to …nd L: For this purpose, we …nd R by substituting (33) into (9), which gives b b = 1( S R + 1): db K + D This together with (15), (16), (31), and pe = pbL , gives (19). b L; b pbL ) is characterized by simultaneous equations of (31) (with pe Altogether, (D; replaced by pbL due to rational expectation), (18), and (19). (ii): Equation (18), which determines pbL ; can be derived from (30), which determines pbs ; by substituting K + D for K: And K + D > K because L > 0: Hence by Proposition 2(ii), pbL < pbs : (iii): It su¢ ces to show that in equilibrium the demand of bankers’fund by evaluated b (given by 8), is smaller than the investment need, B: This good entrepreneurs, I(b pL ; R) b It follows from (a) R b > 1 and (b) qbb Z < B: R b > 1 because is equivalent to qbb Z < RB: otherwise no bankers will spend in screening expertise, that is, all bankers choose p = 0; which, by Lemma 3, cannot arise in equilibrium. (b) is equivalent to that evaluated bad projects have a negative NPV, which holds true, otherwise the project of prior mean quality would have a positive NPV and assumption (1) would be violated. For Lemma 7: Proof. First we complete the characterization of the equilibrium for this case of heterogenous bankers. The demand of each evaluated-good entrepreneur for banker j 0 s fund, by subscripting variables in (8) with j, is Ij (Rj ) = Vj : Rj dj 1 35 And the banker will induce neither over-subscription to her fund nor under-subscription. Therefore, j nj Ij (Rj ) where j (34) = Kj ; is the mass of the entrepreneurs who come to banker j, out of whom, proportion nj is evaluated good and each demands $Ij of her fund. The ex ante pro…t to the entrepreneur coming to her, ables in (7), is Sj (dj 1)Rj ; dj Rj 1 (Rj ; pj ); by subscribing vari- which equals b in equilibrium, that is, Sj (dj 1)Rj = b: dj Rj 1 Given b ; the banker’s deal (pj ; Rj ; j) (35) is characterized by the simultaneous equations (21), (34), and (35), with b settled down by the following market clearing condition: Z j = 1: Then, to prove the lemma, it su¢ ces to show that if j is given, then dpj dKj < 0: pj is determined by (21), or equivalently the FOC, (12), with K replaced by Kj ; that is, Given j, Kj b 1)S 0 (p) + d0 (p)(S(p) b ) = C 0 (p): 2 b [d(p) (d(p) 1)S(p)] (d(p) b is related to Kj through (34) and (35): b = d(p) 1 (S(p) + Kj )jp=p : j d(p) j (36) (37) Substitute it into (36), and then …nd pj is related to Kj through j d2 (p) ( j S(p) Kj d0 (p) S(p) + 1)[S (p) + ( d(p) d(p) 1 0 Kj )] = C 0 (p): j The left hand side decreases with Kj : Therefore, in the same way we proved Proposition 2(ii), we can show dpj dKj < 0: For Lemma 8: Proof. It su¢ ces to show (a) that the if satis…es (24); and (b) the For (a): Note maxp d(p) 1 S(p): d(p) ( b s ; K) < 0; there is a unique b m that found above is strictly between 0 and 1. (K; b ) decreases with b : By Lemma 3, (K; b ) = 1; if Therefore, given (K; b s ) < 0; there exists some b m between maxp 36 < d(p) 1 S(p) d(p) and b s such that with b : (K; b m ) = 0. Moreover, this b m is unique because For (b): Let f (p; x) d(p) 1 (S(p) d(p) is the root of f (b pm ; x) = b m : Note + xK): Then f (p; x) increases with x: Therefore, that 1 > (K; b ) decreases > 0 is equivalent to that f (b pm ; 1) > b m > f (b pm ; 0): The latter inequality holds because b m > maxp d(p) 1 S(p) d(p) = maxp f (p; 0) > f (b pm ; 0): The former, due to b m < b s and b s = f (b ps ; 1); is implied by f (b ps ; 1) < f (b pm ; 1); which is equivalent to pbs < pbm ; as fp0 > 0: And pbs < pbm , (K; b s ) < (K; b m ) ,Lemma 5 b s > b m ; which was shown in the …rst half of the proof. For Lemma 9: Proof. Let f (K; b ; p) K ( d(p) b b 1) C(p): Then (K; b ) = max0 (d(p) 1)S(p) p 1 f (K; b ; p): And pbm satis…es the FOC fp (K; b m (K); p) = 0; where b m (K) is implicitly de…ned by (K; b m ) = 0: Therefore, by the implicit function theorem, The second order condition implies that fpp < 0: Therefore, fpK + fp b By the implicit function theorem, db dK = = f b : Therefore, (38) is equivalent to fpK b fpK < fK because fK > 0 and f b = and @Y @b db pm dK = db pm dK < 0 is equivalent to 1 fpp (fpK + fp b db < 0: dK K b (38) : By the envelop theorem, fp b fb (39) < 0 (see the proof of Lemma 5). Note that fpK = fKp ( Then, fK fb = B( b B) : K(d 1)S (fK )0p fK 0 , (B(1 Sp S b< Rp (S R b 0 )) S p fK 0 ) < 0: fb p d(p) b 1, where B Therefore, (40) is equivalent to: ( Furthermore, ( b B) = (d < 0 , b ) , (27): 1)(S Sp S = fK and ; = (log fK )0p and the RHS equals (log f b )0p : Therefore, (39) is equivalent to (log fK )0p < (log f b )0p , (log b B K fp b ffKb < 0 , fp b = ( f b )0p : Then the LHS of (39) equals Calculate and …nd fK = db ): dK b < fK 0 ) fb p <0, (d(p) 1)S(p), and f b = K B( b B) 0 ) < 0: (d 1)S p b ); which, since 37 (d 1)S : B2 (41) b ). Therefore, (41) is equivalent to ( B(S S Bp (S B (40) b B b) 0 )p < = R; is equivalent to To see the su¢ cient condition, (28), …rst, note that both d and S increases with p, 1)S: Therefore (41), and thus (27), is implied by (B( b and so does (d (b 2B)Bp < 0jBp <0 , b Lemma 5, (R B))0p < 0 , 2B > 0jB= b , R > 2: Second, as we explained following R 1)K = N (p; b )(S(p) b ); where N is the measure of entrepreneurs screened by a banker with accuracy p, and Np > 0: Therefore, Rp K > N Sp , which Rp b 1 R b S : b S bm implies b> R > Sp b b S , (log R)0p (log S)0p > b 1 R b R b S b b: S Then, (27) is implied by b 1 R b R b S b b S > bm b bm S , References [1] Abreu, D., D. Pearce, and E. Stachetti (1986), "Optimal Cartel Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring", Journal of Economic Theory, 39, 25— 269. [2] Abreu, D., P. Milgrom, and D. Pearce (1988), "Information and Timing in Repeated Partnerships", Econometrica, 59 (6), 1713-1733. [3] Akhavein, J.D., A. N. Berger, and D. B. Humphrey (1997), "The E¤ects of Megamergers on E¢ ciency and Prices: Evidence from a Bank Pro…t Function", Review of Industrial Organization, 12, 95-139. [4] Allen, F., E. Carletti, and R. Marquez, "Credit Market Competition and fund Regulation", forthcoming in Review of Financial Studies. [5] Athey, S. and A. Schmutzler (2001), “Investment and Market Dominance”, RAND Journal of Economics, 32, 1–26. [6] Berger, A.N. (1998), "The E¢ ciency E¤ects of Bank Mergers and Acquisition: A Preliminary Look at the 1990s Data", In Amihud, Y. and G. Miller (Eds.), Bank Mergers and Acquisitions, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht, pp. 79-111. [7] Berger, A., R. Demsetz and P. Strahan (1999), "The Consolidation of the Financial Services Industry: Causes, Consequences, and Implications for the Future," Journal of Banking and Finance, 23, 123–94. 38 [8] Berger, A., R. Herring, and G. Szegö (1995), “The Role of Capital in Financial Institutions,”Journal of Banking and Finance, 19, 393–430. [9] Berger, A., A. Kashyap and J. Scalise, (1995), "The Transformation of the U.S. Banking Industry: What a Long, Strange Trip It’s Been," Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 54–219. [10] Berger, A.N. and L. J. Mester (1997), "Inside the Black Box: What Eplains Di¤erences in the E¢ ciencies of Financial Institutions?" Journal of Banking and Finance, 21, 895-947. [11] Besanko, D., U. Doraszelski, Y. Kryukov, and M. Satterthwaite (2011), "Learningby-Doing, Organizational Forgetting, and Industry Dynamics", Econometrica, 78, 453–508. [12] Besanko, D., and G. Kanatas (1993), "Credit Market Equilibrium with Bank Monitoring and Moral Hazard", Review of Financial Studies, 6(1), 213-32. [13] Best, R., and H. Zhang (1993), "Alternative information sources and the information content of bank loans", the Journal of Finance, 48(4), 1507-1522. [14] Billett, M. T., M. J. Flannery, and J. A. Gar…nkel (1995), "The E¤ect of Lender Identity on a Borrowing Firm’s Equity Return," Journal of Finance, 50, 699–718. [15] Booth, J. and R. Smith (1986), "Capital raising, underwriting and the certi…cation hypothesis," Journal of Financial Economics, 15, 213-232. [16] Budd, C., C. Harris, and J. Vickers (1993), “A Model of the Evolution of Duopoly: Does the Asymmetry Between Firms Tend to Increase or Decrease?”, Review of Economic Studies, 60, 543–573. [17] Cantillo, M. (2004), "A Theory of Corporate fund Structure and Investment", Review of Financial Studies, 17(4), 1103-1128. [18] Cantillo, M. and J. Wright (2000), “How do …rms choose their lenders? An empirical investigation”, Review of Financial Studies, 13, 155-189. 39 [19] Cabral, L. (2002), “Increasing Dominance with No E¢ ciency E¤ect”, Journal of Economic Theory, 102, 471–479. [20] Cabral, L. (2011), "Dynamic Price Competition with Network E¤ects," Review of Economic Studies, 78, 83–111. [21] Cabral, L. and M. Riordan (1994), “The Learning Curve, Market Dominance and Predatory Pricing”, Econometrica, 62, 1115–1140. [22] Coleman, A. F., N. Esho, and I. G. Sharpe (2002), "Do Bank Characteristics In‡uence Loan Contract Terms?" Working Paper, Australian Prudential Regulation Authority. [23] Daniel, K. and S. Titman (1995), "Financing investment under asymmetric information", In: R. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic and W. Ziemba ed. Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science, Vol. 9, Finance, North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands. [24] Dell’Ariccia, M. and R. Marquez (2006), "Lending Booms and Lending Standards," Journal of Finance, 61, 2511-2546. [25] Demsetz, R. S. and P. E. Strahan (1997), "Diversi…cation, Size, and Risk at Bank Holding Companies", Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29, 300-313. [26] Demyanyk, Y. and O. Van Hemert (forthcoming), "Understanding the Subprime Mortgage Crisis", Review of Financial Studies. [27] Diamond, D. (1984), "Financial Intermediation and Delegated Monitoring", Review of Economic Studies, 51 (3) 393-414. [28] Diamond, D. and P. Dybvig (1983), “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 401–419. [29] Diamond, D. and R. Rajan (2001), "Liquidity risk, liquidity creation and …nancial fragility: A theory of banking," Journal of Political Economy, 109, 287-327. [30] Flaherty, M. (1980), "Industry Structure and Cost-Reducing Investment." Econometrica, 48, 1187-1209. 40 [31] Gale, D. and M. Hellwig (1985), "Incentive-Compatibility Debt Contracts: The OnePeriod Problem", Review of Economic Studies, 52, 647-663. [32] Gilber, R. and D. Newbery (1982), “Preemptive Patenting and the Persistence of Monopoly Power”, American Economic Review, 72, 514–526. [33] Gorton, G. and A, Winton (2003), "Financial Intermediation," in The Handbook of the Economics of Finance: Corporate Finance, G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz, eds. Elsevier Science. [34] Halbheer, D., E. Fehr, L. Goette, and A. Schmutzler (2009), "Self-reinforcing market dominance", Games and Economic Behavior, 67, 481–502. [35] Hao, L. (2003), "Bank E¤ects and the Determinants of Loan Yield Spreads," working paper. [36] Hauswald, R. and R. Marquez (2006), "Competition and Strategic Information Acquisition in Credit Markets," Review of Financial Studies, 19, 967-1000. [37] Holmstrom, B., and J. Tirole (1997), "Financial intermediation, loanable funds, and the real sector", Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII, (3), 663-691. [38] Hortlund, P. (2005), "The Long-Term Relationship between Capital and Earnings in Banking: Sweden 1870–2001," SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance 611. [39] Ja¤e, D., A. Lynch, M. Richardson and S. Van Nieuwerburgh (2009), Mortgage Origination and Securitization in the Financial Crisis, in: Viral V. Acharya and Matthew Richardson ed. Restoring Financial Stability: How to Repair a Failed System, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., NJ. [40] James, C. (1987), "Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans, Journal of Financial Economics 19, 217-235. [41] Jensen, M. C., and W. H. Meckling (1976), "Theory of the …rm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure", Journal of Fianacial Economics, 3, 305-360. 41 [42] Jones, K. and T. Critch…eld (2006), "Consolidation in the U.S. Banking Industry: Is the ’Long, Strange Trip’About to End?" FDIC Banking Review. [43] Keys, B., T. Mukherjee, A. Seru and V. Vig (2010), "Did Securitization Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence from Subprime Loans," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125, 307-362. [44] Klepper, S. (1996), "Entry, Exit, Growth, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle," American Economic Review, 86, pp. 562-583. [45] Kreps, D. and J. Scheinkman (1983), "Quantity precommitment and Bertrand competition yields Cournot outcomes," Bell journal of Economics, 14, 326-337. [46] Leland, E. and D. Pyle (1977), Informational asymmetries, …nancial structure, and …nancial intermediation," Journal of Finance, 32, 371-387. [47] Liang, J. N. and S. A. Rhoades (1991), "Asset Diversi…cation, Firm Risk, and RiskBased fund Requirements in Banking", Review of Industrial Organization, 6, 49-59. [48] Loutskina, E. (forthcoming), "The Role of Securitization in Bank Liquidity and Funding Management," Journal of Financial Economics. [49] Lummer, S., and J. McConnell (1989), "Further evidence on the bank lending process and the fund-market response6 to bank loan agreements", Journal of Financial Economics, 25, 99-122. [50] Mas-Colell, M. D. Winston, and J. R. Green (1995), Microeconomic Theory, New York and Oxford, Oxford University Press. [51] Maskara, P. K. and D. J. Mullineaux, "Information Asymmetry and Self-Selection Bias in Loan Announcement Studies", Journal of Financial Economicis, forthcoming. [52] Mayer, C., K. Pence and S. Sherlund (2009), "The Rise in Mortgage Defaults", Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23, 27–50. [53] McAllister, P.H. and D. A. McManus, (1993) "Resolving the Scale E¢ ciency Puzzle in Banking", Journal of Banking and Finance, 17, 389-405. 42 [54] Mian, A. and A. Su… (2009), “The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expansion: Evidence from the U.S. Mortgage Default Crisis,”Quarterly Journal of Economics,124, 1449–1496. [55] Mikkelson, W. H., and M. M. Partch (1986), "Valuation E¤ects of Security O¤erings and the Issuance Process", Journal of Financial Economics, 15, 91-118. [56] Miles, D., J. Yang and G. Marcheggiano (2011), "Optimal Bank Capital," Bank of England Discussion Paper No. 31. [57] Morrison. A. D. and L. White (2005), "Crises and fund Requirements in Banking", American Economic Review, 95(5), 1548-1572. [58] Parlour, C. and G. Plantin (2008), “Loan Sales and Relationship Banking,”Journal of Finance, 63, 1291–1314. [59] Pozsar, Z., T. Adrian, A. Ashcraft and H. Boesky (2010), "Shadow Banking," Federal Reserve Bank of New York Sta¤ Reports, no. 458. [60] Purnanandam, A. (forthcoming), "Originate-to-Distribute Model and the Subprime Mortgage Crisis," Review of Financial Studies. [61] Rajan, R. (1994), "Why bank credit policies ‡uctuate: A theory and some evidence," Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109, 399–441. [62] Rajan, U., A. Seru and V. Vig (2008), “The Failure of Models That Predict Failure: Distance, Incentives and Defaults,”Chicago Booth School of Business Working Paper No. 08-19. [63] Ross, D (forthcoming), "The ”Dominant Bank E¤ect:”How High Lender Reputation A¤ects the Information Content and Terms of Bank Loans", Review of Financial Studies. [64] Rucks, M. (2004), "Bank Competition and Credit Standards," Review of Financial Studies, 17, 1073-1102. 43 [65] Saunders, A. and B. Wilson (1999), “The Impact of Consoli-dation and Safety-Net Support on Canadian, US and UK Banks: 1893–1992.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 23, 537–571. [66] Townsend, R. (1979), "Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Auditing", Journal of Economic Theory, 21, 265-293. [67] Vickers, J. (1986), "The Evolution of Market Structure When There Is a Sequence of Innovations," Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, 1-13. [68] Williamson, S. D. (1986a), "Costly Monitoring, Financial Intermediation, and Equilibrium Credit Rationing", Journal of Monetary Economics, 18, 159-179. [69] Williamson, S. D. (1986b), "Increasing Returns to Scale in Financial Intermediation and the Nonneutrality of Government Policy," Review of Economic Studies, 53, 863875. 44