The Valuation of M&A Targets by Relative Indifference Prices Carolin Mauch ∗ Stefan Rostek † University of Tuebingen May 10, 2012 Abstract In this paper, we apply the technique of indifference pricing to the valuation of investment projects or businesses. We suggest that indifference pricing is the intuitive approach to overcome the conceptual drawbacks of classical real options theory when facing market incompleteness. Though assuming identical information about future states of nature, we show that the sell side on the one hand and any potential buyer on the other hand may derive different values. It may come as no surprise that these values differ by the investor’s degree of risk aversion. However, beyond that, our approach reveals another source of investor specific prices: The relative indifference price depends on the investor’s current level of engagement in the very business field. ∗ University of Tuebingen, Department of Economics and Business Administration, Chair of managerial Accounting, Nauklerstr.47, 72074 Tübingen, Germany, carolin.mauch@uni-tuebingen.de † University of Tuebingen, Department of Economics and Business Administration, Chair of Corporate Finance, Sigwartstr.18, 72076 Tübingen, Germany, stefan.rostek@uni-tuebingen.de 1 I Introduction Valuation of investment projects and whole businesses by means of real option approaches had been very popular in the 90s of the last century. When Stewart C. Myers introduced the term ’real option’ in 1977 to the economics literature, he described this type of option as ’opportunities to purchase real assets on possibly favorable terms’ (Myers(1977), p. 163). He stressed that DCF methods would systematically undervalue projects and businesses due to limited consideration of strategic options. A multitude of real option approaches as well as different valuation methods were suggested afterwards. Early approaches as Brennan and Schwartz (1985) for the valuation of natural resources or Kemna (1993) for the valuation of growth and abandonment options conceptually refer to the seminal work of Black and Scholes (1973) and Merton (1973) for the valuation of financial options using a ’twin security’ for replication purposes. From today’s perspective where seemingly even financial markets only sometimes happen to be complete, extending this analogy to project valuation is known to be heroic. In order to value real options in the presence of incomplete markets, further approaches such as superhedging, minimal distance measures, coherent and convex risk measures as well as indifference pricing, have been proposed that are more or less tractable(see for example Rouge/El Karoui (2000), Goll/Rüschendorf (2001), Musiela et al.(2008), Artzner et al. (1999) or Föllmer/Schied (2002)). However, all of these techniques are rather driven from a mathematical viewpoint and therefore seem to be not economically intuitive enough to convince practitioners to apply them. The concept of indifference pricing fills that gap by explicitly readdressing to the funda- 2 mental principle of utility maximization. The approach was introduced by Hodges and Neuberger (1989). The basic idea is to find an option price which makes the investor, in consideration of his initial wealth and his utility function, indifferent between holding and not holding the option. As a very general result, the pricing functional is convex, which leads to the fact that the option’s price does not increase linearly by scale and a seller’s price may deviate from a buyer’s price even though they share the same information. Notably, both characteristics seem to be tailor-made to describe price features of M&A targets. Despite this intuitive and economic sound idea, until now, the scientific debate mainly took place within the field of mathematical finance. Consequently, most of the literature related to indifference pricing deals with continuous models (see e.g. Rouge/El Karoui (2000), Henderson (2002), Musiela/Zariphopoulou (2003), Stoikov/Zariphopoulou (2005), and Davis (2006)), whereas approaches of discrete indifference pricing are rather scarce. As a commendable exception, Smith and McCardle (1998) as well as Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2004) develop discrete indifference pricing models. Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2002) were also the first ones to intensely discuss the nonadditive character of indifference prices, which leads to the concept of relative indifference prices. Most easily, the idea behind is that a buyer may not be willing to pay double the price for a project of double extent as risk may increase in a non-linear way. By means of this paper, we want to draw the attention to practical applications of relative indifference pricing within the field of project or business valuation. We promote the technique of relative indifference pricing for at least three reasons: its easy-to-grasp 3 and economic intuitive concept, its ability to deal with incompleteness as a fundamental inherence of M&A target valuation, and last but not least its ease of tractability. The rest of the paper is structured as follows: In the following section, we shortly introduce the concept of indifference pricing in a quite general way. In section III, we specify the target model as well as investor’s preferences and derive the indifference prices in a similar way as Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2005). We then motivate the use of relative indifference prices in section IV. We apply the results to an easy example where relative indifference pricing is used to derive potential sell prices and buy prices for an oil platform. II The concept of indifference pricing in a discrete setting The approach of indifference pricing introduced by Hodges and Neuberger (1989), aims to find the optimal hedging strategy which maximizes expected utility. By comparing the indirect utility for the case of holding and the case of not holding the option, the indifference price can be computed. Assume a one-period setting, i.e. t ∈ {0, T }, with a traded asset St , a non-traded asset Yt as well as a riskless asset Bt . Without any options traded a rational investor with utility function U (x) maximizes his expected utility with respect to the physical measure P. He does so by optimally splitting his initial wealth x into a number of α shares in St and β shares in Bt . Consequently, at the two relevant points in time, the investor’s 4 wealth is given by: X0 = αS0 + βB0 = x XT = αST + βBT . The investor’s indirect utility function or value function V without option trading is then: V 0 (x) = max E (U (XT )) α Furthermore, we assume that there is an option contract C which is written at time t = 0 and generates payments C at the end of the planning horizon. These payments may depend both on the traded asset ST and on a non-traded asset YT . An investor who is invested in St and Bt and additionally is short this option has to solve a shifted optimization problem which is expressed by the seller’s value function VSC : VSC (x) = max E [U (XT − CT )] α while the same investor being long the option will have the buyer’s value function VBC : VBC (x) = max E [U (XT + C)] α In order to calculate the indifference price, the value functions V C for holding and V 0 for not holding the option are compared. The seller’s indifference price υS (C) is the additional amount of initial wealth an investor requests for taking a short position in the option, i.e. VSC (x + υS (C)) = V 0 (x) , ∀x ∈ R (1) On the other hand, the buyer’s indifference price υB (C) is the amount of initial wealth an investor is accepting to waive for having a long position in the option, i.e. VBC (x − υB (C)) = V 0 (x) , ∀x ∈ R 5 (2) III Specifying asset evolution and risk preferences Our valuation model is based on the discrete time indifference pricing model introduced by Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2005). The latter specifies the riskless asset to have zero interest rate as well as the two risky assets (traded and non-traded) to be of random walk type which may be correlated. We slightly extend that framework assuming that the binomial process of the traded risky asset will be mean-reverting. We do so having in mind the practical application of the valuation of an oil field, where the dynamics of the related traded commodity, i.e. the oil price, is usually assumed to be of mean-reverting type. The value of the traded asset S(t) is given by ST = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + ε, S0 > 0 where S ∗ is the mean reversion level or the long run equilibrium price to which the asset will converge to, δ the mean reversion rate, and ε = εu , εd the random shock to price from t = 0 to t = T . To avoid riskless arbitrage opportunities the condition −1 < δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εd δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εu <0< S0 S0 must hold.1 The value of the non-traded asset Y is also binomially distributed, i.e. YT ∈ YTu , Ytd These values of the non-traded asset do not need to be measured in monetary units (see example in section V) and may be correlated to the evolution of the traded asset. 1 In line with Cox/Ross/Rubinstein (1979), p.232. 6 The probability space is denoted by (Ω, F, P), where Ω = {ω1 , ω2 , ω3 , ω4 } defines the four possible states in t = T and P is the real (historical) probability measure on the σ-algebra Ω allocating the probabilities pi = P (ωi ). Note that in a one-period setting the following four possible states may occur: I STu = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εu YTu II STu = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εu YTd III STd = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εd YTu IV STd = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εd YTd The option value at maturity is a random variable defined on Ω with values C (ωi ) = ci ∈ R , for i = 1, ..., 4. We complete our setting by specifying the utility functions of the market participants. Both the seller and a potential buyer are assumed to have exponential utility functions that only differ with respect to the risk aversion parameter: and US (x) = −e−γS x for the seller UB (x) = −e−γB x for the buyer. Proposition 1 Let Q be the probability measure of the following form: qi = Q (ωi ) = q pi p1 + p2 qi = Q (ωi ) = (1 − q) ∗ pi p3 + p4 , i = 1, 2 , i = 3, 4 d 0 )+ε where q = − δ(S ε−S . Then, the seller’s indifference price of an investor with risk ( u −εd ) aversion parameter γS is given by the conditional certainty equivalent υS (C) = EQ γ C 1 S T ln EP e | ST . γS 7 (3) Furthermore, the buyer’s indifference price of an investor with risk aversion parameter γB is given by the conditional certainty equivalent υB (C) = −EQ −γ C 1 ln EP e B T | ST . γB (4) Proof We first derive the seller’s indifference price. Substituting the possible values for ST and C into the value function we obtain ∗ u VSC (x) = e−γS x max EP −e−γS α(δ(S −S0 )+ε ) (p1 eγS c1 + p2 eγS c2 ) α −e−γS α(δ(S ∗ −S )+εd 0 i ) (p eγS c3 + p eγS c4 ) 3 4 Maximizing over α yields the optimal number of shares 1 (δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εu ) (p1 eγS c1 + p2 eγS c2 ) ln − = γS (εu − εd ) (δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εd ) (p3 eγS c3 + p4 eγS c4 ) 1 1 − q p1 eγS c1 + p2 eγS c2 = ln · γS (εu − εd ) q p3 eγS c3 + p4 eγS c4 αS∗ ∗ d 0 )+ε . As a result the value function takes the form with q = − δ(S ε−S u −εd VSC (x) = e −γS x p1 eγS c1 + p2 eγS c2 q q p3 eγS c3 + p4 eγS c4 1−q 1−q When the investor is not holding the option the value function VS0 is obtained by setting c1 = c2 = c3 = c4 = 0. Using the defining equation (1) the indifference sell price results in υS (C) = q 1 p1 eγS c1 + p2 eγS c2 1 p3 eγS c3 + p4 eγS c4 + (1 − q) ln ln γS p1 + p2 γS p3 + p4 Based on the evolution of the traded asset, we define the following events: A = {ω1 , ω2 } = {ω : S1 (ω) = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εu0 } Ac = {ω3 , ω4 } = ω : S1 (ω) = S0 + δ (S ∗ − S0 ) + εd0 , 8 which allows us to write 1 1 ln EP eγS CT | A + (1 − q) ln EP eγS CT | Ac γS γS 1 = EQ ln EP eγS CT | ST . γS υS (C) = q On the other hand, using the defining equation (2) one can show in a perfectly analogous way that the buyer’s indifference price is given by υB (C) = −EQ −γ C 1 B T ln EP e | ST γB which completes the proof. Proposition 1 shows that calculating the indifference price is a two-step process. Each of the steps can be associated with one of the two different types of risks that are present in the incomplete market. As a first step, for each possible value of the traded asset the conditional expectation 1 γS ln EP eγS CT | ST is calculated. It is easy to show that this expression represents the conditional certainty equivalent (see Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2005)). Most evidently, investor’s individual preferences influence this part of the price. Moreover, this part of the pricing functional apparently is non-linear. As a second step, the remaining hedgeable risk is valued through making use of arbitrage free pricing characteristics. This is possible as with respect to the tradeable asset St , the market is assumed to be complete. The value q hence represents the unique risk-neutral probability for an upward move of St and is solely based on market information instead of individual preferences. As an immediate consequence of proposition 1, we receive the following corrolary. 9 Corrolary 1 For identical risk aversion parameters γS = γB we have the following relationship: υB (C) = −υS (−C) . IV Relative indifference prices The basic setup implicitly assumes that both the seller and the buyer initially are not invested in the project, i.e. after the deal the seller of the option C will be short in the project and the buyer long. When applying this to real projects, it seems to be reasonable to assume that an investment project cannot be sold without possessing it in advance. From now on, we will therefore assume that before the deal the seller has a long position of aS C with a ≥ 1, i.e. he sells a fraction of 1/a of the project. Definition The relative indifference price of a seller with current position aS C is the amount the seller postulates when reducing his position from aS C to (aS − 1)C) and is denoted by υSrel (C; aS ): υSrel (C; aS ) = υS ((1 − aS )C) − υS (−aS C) . (5) In the same way, we allow the buyer to be already invested to an extent of aB C, where aB ≥ 0 defines the range of possible parameters. Following the same idea, we define the relative indifference price of a buyer with current position aB C: Definition The relative indifference price of a buyer with current position aB C is the amount the buyer is willing to pay when enlarging his position from aB C to (aB + 1)C) 10 and is denoted by υBrel (C; aB ): υBrel (C; aB ) = υB ((aB + 1)C) − υB (aB C) (6) Based on these definitions, we can derive the following proposition: Proposition 2 If the seller and the buyer show the same level of risk aversion, they agree on the same indifference price if and only if they exactly interchange their level of investment. Proof By this, the seller’s relative indifference price is the (positive) difference between the (negative) amount he would postulate for holding a short position of (1 − a)C and the (negative) amount he would postulate for holding a short position of (−a)C. The idea of the definition becomes much clearer when transforming the sell prices with negative short positions (which basically are long positions) into buy prices: υSrel (C; aS ) = υS ((1 − aS )C) − υS (−aS C) = υB (aS C) − υB ((aS − 1)C) = υBrel (C; aS − 1) . Consequently, seller and buyer agree on the same price if and only if aB = aS − 1. In this case the seller’s relative indifference price for reducing his position from aS C to (aS − 1)C equals the incremental amount the same investor would pay as a buyer for enlarging his position from (aS − 1)C to aS C, i.e. the parties interchange their positions. For the practical application in the next section, we provide further characteristics of the relative indifference prices. 11 Proposition 3 For aS ≥ 1, the seller’s relative indifference price is a decreasing function both with respect to the risk aversion parameter γS and with respect to the level of current position aS . For aB ≥ 0, the buyer’s relative indifference price is a decreasing function both with respect to the risk aversion parameter γB and with respect to the level of current position aB . Proof We recall the characteristics of the function of absolute indifference prices stated by Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2005): The seller’s indifference price function is continuous, increasing and convex with respect to payoffs, while the buyer’s indifference price function is continuous, increasing and concave with respect to payoffs. The proposition then is a straightforward consequence of the definitions given by equations (5) and (6). V An Example: Relative indifference prices of an oil field In this section, we illustrate the concept of indifference pricing by a simplified example: We assume that the target is an unconventional oil reserve whose future possible exploitation is contingent on technological progress and/or legal framework. The future benefit for an investor is determined by two key influences. First, the mere exploitability plays the role of our non-traded asset and has a typical go/no go character taking a value of one or zero. Second, in case that exploitation is possible, the main driver of profits is assumed to be the level of the oil price which represents the traded 12 % Y0 & YTu = 1 % Stu = 110 & Std = 90 S0 = 105 YTd = 0 Figure 1: Evolution of the traded and the non-traded asset. Parameters of the oil price evolution are S0 = 105, S ∗ = 90, δ = 13 , εu = +10, εd = −10. % {STu , YTu } : ω1 = 0.3 & {STu , YTd } : ω2 = 0.2 % {STd , YTu } : ω3 = 0.2 & {STd , YTd } : ω4 = 0.3 % {Ω, F, P} & Figure 2: Joint distribution of the traded and the non-traded asset. asset. Figure 1 shows the evolution of the traded as well as of the non-traded asset. Note that the traded asset was modeled to be of mean-reverting type. Moreover, we assume that the joint probability distribution is given by Figure 2: Here we implicitly assumed a slight positive correlation between oil price and exploitability, as higher oil prices might cause an enhancement of research efforts. The net profits (in Mio USD) to be earned from the target are assumed to have the form given by Figure 3 (the profit formation here is treated as a black box): Let the seller of the target be a company that holds a multitude of similar oil reserves all dependent on this same type of risks and with potential net profits linearly related to project C. Consequently, we can assume that the portfolio of the seller is a multiple of project C and can be modeled to be of the shape aS C. Here, we assume aS = 3, i.e. the vendor is selling one third of his potential oil reserves. The 13 % C(ω1 ) = c1 = 50 & C(ω2 ) = c2 = 0 % C(ω3 ) = c3 = 20 & C(ω4 ) = c4 = 0 % C & Figure 3: Distribution of net profits of the target. risk aversion parameter of the seller’s utility function2 is assumed to be γS = 0.005. We can now start calculating the seller’s indifference price. υSrel (C; aS ) = υS ((1 − aS )C) − υS (−aS C) −0.005∗2∗C 1 T = EQ ln EP e | ST 5 −0.005∗3∗C 1 T ln EP e | ST −EQ 5 The values of the conditional certainty equivalents are: 1 1 ln EP e−0.005∗2∗CT | ST = S u = ln 0.6 ∗ e−0.01∗50 + 0.4 ∗ e−0.01∗0 0.005 0.005 = −53.86 1 1 ln EP e−0.005∗2∗CT | ST = S d = ln 0.4 ∗ e−0.01∗20 + 0.6 ∗ e−0.01∗0 0.005 0.005 = −15.05 1 1 ln EP e−0.005∗3∗CT | ST = S u = ln 0.6 ∗ e−0.015∗50 + 0.4 ∗ e−0.015∗0 0.005 0.005 = −76.13 1 1 ln EP e−0.005∗3∗CT | ST = S d = ln 0.4 ∗ e−0.015∗20 + 0.6 ∗ e−0.015∗0 0.005 0.005 = −21.89 2 Note that x is measured in Mio USD. 14 ∗ d 1 0 )+ε = −3 With q = − δ(S ε−S ( u −εd ) (90−105)−10 10+10 = 34 , the seller’s relative indifference price equals υSrel (C; aS ) = 0.75 ∗ (−53.86) + 0.25 ∗ (−15.05) − (0.75 ∗ (−76.13) + 0.25 ∗ (−21.89)) = −44.16 + 62.57 = 18.41 Mio USD From the theoretical considerations of section IV, we know that a potential buyer with the same risk aversion parameter γB = 0.005 and a risk exposure aB = 2 would derive the same indifference price. All potential buyers with the same risk aversion but lower risk exposure as well as any buyer with same risk exposure but lower risk aversion will certainly also agree on the seller’s price and may still have room for higher offers in case of competing bids. However, the combination of higher risk aversion but lower risk exposure or vice versa are not clear in advance and have to be computed. For example, the buyer B1 with combination γB1 = 0.008 and aB1 = 1 yields an relative indifference price of υBrel (C; aB1 ) = 18.66 Mio USD which is slightly above the amount the seller requires. On the other hand, an investor B2 with lower risk aversion γB2 = 0.002 but already high exposure aB2 = 8 would only be willing to pay a maximum amount of 16.26 Mio USD. Figure 4 shows the function of buyer’s relative indifference price depending on risk aversion and risk exposure. For the seller’s relative indifference price of 18.41 Mio USD given in the example above, it is easy to derive graphically the range of parameter combinations that can lead to a successful transaction. Figure 5 shows the very plot. The red area depicts the combinations where buyer’s relative indifference price is above the one of the seller. The combinations of investors B1 and B2 are marked. 15 Figure 4: Buyer’s relative indifference price depending on risk aversion γB and risk exposure aB . VI Conclusion We suggested the approach of relative indifference prices to valuation in incomplete markets. We showed that this concept is based on a very intuitive economic idea. By the concavity of risk-averse utility function, the price function of an option is non-linear as soon as the option payoff contains an undhedgeable part. The approach is in line with the existing theory: In the limit case where the market is complete and the option is perfectly hedgeable, the function will be linear again and of Cox-Ross-Rubinstein type. However, 16 Figure 5: Parameter combinations of potential buyers the far more general approach of indifference pricing treats this limit case of complete markets as what it is: an exception that most of the cases will not be appropriate for modeling the characteristics of investment projects or M&A targets. Our easy example showed how the technique can be implemented in the context of real world applications. Such applications certainly have to be modeled by a slightly more complex structure allowing for multi-period decisions and introducing interest rates. We decided to abstain from these extensions in order to ease the understanding of the main concept. However, the mathematical framework for such extensions has already been 17 developed (see e.g. Musiela and Zariphopoulou (2002)) and is basically the same as in our setting. A next step to extend this model could be to introduce imperfect information about risk exposure and risk aversion of the counterparty. A game-theoretic approach may then be appropriate to model auction type M&A processes in a more realistic way. References Artzner, Philippe et al. (1999): Coherent measures of risk, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 9(3), 203 - 228 Black, Fischer/ Scholes, Myron (1973): The pricing of options and corporate liabilities, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 81(3), 637 - 654 Brennan, Michael J./ Schwartz, Eduardo S. (1985): Evaluating natural resource investments, Jounral of Business, Vol. 58, 135 - 157 Cox, John C./ Ross, Stephen A./ Rubinstein, Mark (1979): Option pricing: a simplified approach, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 7, 229 - 263 Davis, Mark H. A. (2006): Optimal hedging with basis risk, in: Kubanov, Yuri/ Liptser, Robert/ Stoyanov, Jordan: From stochastic calculus to mathematical finance: The Shiryaev Festschrift, Berlin, Heidelberg et al.: Springer, 169 - 187 Föllmer, Hans/ Schied, Alexander (2002): Convey meausres of risk and trading constraints, Finance and Stochastics, Vol. 6 (4), 429 - 447 Goll, Thomas/ Rüschendorf, Ludger (2001): Minimax and minimal distance martingale measures and their relationship to portfolio optimization, Finance and Stochastics, Vol. 5, 557 - 581 Henderson, Vicky (2002): Valuation of claims on nontraded assets using utility maximization, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 12 (4), 351 - 373 18 Hodges, Stewart D./ Neuberger, Anthony (1989): Optimal replication of contingent claims under transactions costs, Review of Futures Markets, Vol. 8, 222 - 239 Kemna, Angelien G. Z. (1993): Case studies on real options, Financial Management, Vol. 22, 259 - 270 Merton, Robert C. (1973): Theory of rational option pricing, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 4 (1), 141 - 183 Musiela, Marek/Zariphopoulou, Thaleia (2002): A pricing algorithm for incomplete markets, preprint Musiela, Marek/ Zariphopoulou, Thaleia (2003): Indifference prices and related measures, preprint Musiela, Marek/ Zariphopoulou, Thaleia (2004): A valuation algorithm for indifference prices in incomplete markets, Finance and Stochastics, Vol. 8, 399 - 414 Musiela, Marek/ Zariphopoulou, Thaleia (2005): The backward and forward dynamic utilities and the associated pricing systems: Case Study of the binomial model, The University of Texas, preprint Musiela, Marek et al. (2008): Indifference valuation in incomplete binomial models,The University of Texas, preprint Myers, Stewart C. (1977): Determinants of corporate borrowing, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 5, 147 - 175 Rouge, Richard/ El Karoui, Nicole (2000): Pricing via utility maximization and entropy, Mathematical Finance, Vol. 10 (2), 259 - 276 Smith, James E./ McCardle, Kevin F. (1998): Valuing oil properties: integrating option pricing and decision analysis approaches, Operations Research, Vol. 46(2), 198 217 Stoikov, Sasha F./ Zariphopoulou (2005): Optimal investment in the presence of unhedgeable risks and under CARA preferences, The University of Texas, preprint 19