Transatlantic Financial Liberalization and Regulation: Capital Markets and the Role... Central Banks in the Light of Recent Financial Market Events

advertisement
Transatlantic Financial Liberalization and Regulation: Capital Markets and the Role of
Central Banks in the Light of Recent Financial Market Events
Willi Semmler1 and Brigitte Young2
GARNET Working Paper No: 57/08
September 2008
ABSTRACT
This paper addresses issues that are involved in the financial market liberalization and
transatlantic regulation. Whereas the discussion in previous years has concentrated on the
benefits of the financial market liberalization for both sides of the Atlantic, due to recent
credit and financial market crises, the cost of fast and excessive financial liberalizations has
come into focus. In the literature on Capital Market Liberalization (CML) it has become clear
in the last two decades that the issues of CML are more complex than for example trade
liberalization of goods and services. In contrast to the theory of perfect capital markets, we
here start from the more realistic assumption of imperfect capital markets. We deal with the
benefits but also the potential shortcomings of CML. Too fast liberalized capital markets, for
example a CML with a wrong sequencing, can trigger financial instability, contagion effects
and strong negative effects on the real side of the economy. Thus, capital market
liberalization – at least in the short run—does not necessarily show the same beneficial
effects as product market liberalization. We also show that what is understood under CML
appears to differ on both sides of the Atlantic. In particular, this perspective seems to hold
true on oversight and regulation of the financial markets. In the US, regulatory institutions are
more akin to represent some type of self-control of the market and are market friendly,
whereas politicians in Europe seem to support more public regulations and oversight. We
discuss the causes and effects of the current financial market melt down and the role the
Central Banks and how they have react to the currently evolving financial market turmoil on
both sides of the Atlantic. Finally we discuss and analyse in detail the proposed financial
market regulations as they were triggered by the recent financial market crisis.
1
2
Department of Economics, New School, 79 Fifth Ave, New York, NY 1003, email:semmlerw@newschool.edu
Department of Political Science, University of Muenster, Germany , email: byoung@uni-muenster.de
1
I:
INTRODUCTION
This paper addresses some major issues that are involved in the financial market
liberalization and regulation. Whereas the discussion in previous years has concentrated on
the benefits of the financial market liberalization for both sides of the Atlantic (see Council
on Foreign Relations, 2002), due to recent credit and financial market events, the cost of fast
and excessive financial liberalizations has come into focus.
In the literature in the last two decades on Capital Market Liberalization (CML) it has
become clear that the issues of CML are more complex than for example trade liberalizations
of goods and services. In contrast to the theory of perfect capital markets, we here start from
the more realistic concept of imperfect capital markets. It is from this perspective that both
possible benefits as well as costs of CML can appropriately be evaluated. Much of this
concept of imperfect capital markets is developed in Semmler (2006).
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section II of the paper discusses
important issues of CML and sketches briefly the history of the successes and failures of
CML. Section III studies the capital markets on both sides of the Atlantic. Section IV deals
with the currently ongoing financial market crisis. Section V studies the central bank policies
and the issues they face arising from the financial market turmoil. Given the recent financial
market instabilities in the US, and its world wide spill-over effects, section VI explores the
challenges that regulators now face. We here discuss new regulatory proposals that have
come into the public discussion on financial market crises and regulation. Section VII draws
some conclusions. The Appendices 1 and 2 present the data and figures describing the current
financial market melt down, triggered by the US subprime crisis.
II:
CAPITAL MARKET LIBERALIZATION AND ITS PITFALLS
a)
Role of Financial Markets in Market Economies
We first want to discuss the benefits but also the potential shortcomings of Capital Market
Liberalization (CML). Let us remind ourselves what the functions are that the financial
market has in a market economy. The financial market performs the essential role of
channelling funds to firms that have potentially productive investment opportunities.
Moreover, they also permit households to borrow against future income and allow countries
2
to access foreign funds and, thus, accelerate economic growth. As financial markets have
expanded across borders, they have significantly impacted not only on economic growth, but
employment and policy as well.
Financial deepening is usually accompanied by waves of financial innovations. Recent new
financial innovations are hedge funds and options and derivative instruments. Collateralized
debt obligations (CDOs) and Collateralized loan obligations (CLOs) are financial instruments
where households’ and companies’ loans are turned into tradable securities. These are
relatively new financial instruments that diversify risk for the issuer of households`
mortgages or commercial credits. The number of such innovative financial products have
grown rapidly, in fact credit derivatives in the form of credit default swaps, mortgage-backed
securities, or loan backed securities have expanded exponentially, but so too have financial
markets for them which have greatly enlarged.
Given the modern financial markets and the new financial innovations and instruments what
general issues do they raise:
•
What are the specifics of the major financial markets and do they differ in
importance as to how they impact economic activity? Does the deepening and
liberalization of the financial marketplace stimulate or retard economic growth?
Will developed financial markets and new financial innovations lead to a more
efficient use of resources?
•
Has the deepening and liberalization of the financial marketplace decreased or
increased the volatility of macroeconomic variables, e.g., output, employment,
balance of trade, interest rate exchange rates, money wages, the price level, and
stock prices? Has, in spite of the fact that risk is diversified for the individual
issuer by financial market innovations, financial risk economy-wide
increased and will financial liberalization lead to booms and bust cycles?
•
Are asset price inflation, deflation, and volatility harmful to economic activity?
How do asset prices, alone or through credit channels, affect business cycles?
Can an asset price boom also lead to an economic boom? Do asset price booms
have a persistent effect on economic growth?
•
Do monetary and fiscal policies influence the financial market and how do
financial markets influence government policies?
3
How effective are these
policies in open economies with free capital flows and volatile exchange rates?
Should governments or monetary authorities intervene to stabilize asset prices
or credit markets? How effective can central banks’ monetary policies be, given
the innovation and also risk of then financial market instruments.
To
what extent should financial markets be constrained and regulated?
These are important questions that are also relevant in thinking about opening up the
Transatlantic financial markets for unrestricted capital flows. But let us first go back the
history of capital market liberalization (CML).
b)
A Historical Note on the CML
As above indicated CML has been a popular topic since the 1980s and 1990s. Financial
liberalization has actively been advocated by such organizations as the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB) and has been pursued by many
governments since 1980s. Even under the Clinton government CML has been strongly
pursued, in particular when Larry Summers became Undersecretary of Treasury and when
NY Wall Street rose to an influential institution in the Clinton Government, for example after
the appointment of Rubin as Secretary of Treasury. At the same time, the Fed Governor Alan
Greenspan was strongly promoting globalization, in particular globalization of the capital
markets. After the fall and breaking up of the of the Soviet Union he thought there will be a
long period of expansion of the world economy due to the establishment of global markets
for products and financial services.
Yet, others have maintained that it is not surprising, that the rapid enlargement of the
financial market has led to more financial instability which, in turn, can be devastating, see
for example Stiglitz et al (2006). For example, the Mexican (1994), Asian (1997/8) and
Russian (1998) financial crises demonstrated the degree to which a too-rapid market
liberalization could lead to a currency crisis wherein a sudden reversal of capital flows was
followed by financial instability and a consequent decline in economic activity.
Again, during the period from 2001 through 2002, the United States and Europe experienced
a significant decline in asset prices, commonly referred to as the bursting of the Information
Technology (IT) Stock Market Bubble. Here, the combination of a decade of dubious
accounting practices, short-sighted investment, and outright fraud (as in the Enron case, for
4
an evaluation of the latter events, see MacAvoy and Millstein, 2004) led to a situation in
which the public-at-large became suspicious of accounting practices and equity valuations
with consequent high volatility and negative pressure on asset prices became the not so
surprising result. It is interesting to note that this very volatility and lack of trust, especially
when combined with the increasing globalization of the markets, have led to new financial
products and new excitement in these same markets. The post-crash phenomena were seen as
opportunities by clever traders, for new financial innovations and for globally operating
investment firms.
Usually the operations were undertaken with little or un-checked
collaterals on the borrowers side. From this followed another financial market crash, the
subprime and credit market crises starting in 2007 and still continuing these days, see the
figures in the Appendix 1.
On the other hand, the liberalization of financial markets has been more positively evaluated
by other circles. An emphasis of the benefits of financial globalization in general can be
found with the American business and financial community, and also the Council on Foreign
Relations. The Report by the Council on Foreign Relations for example is emphasising what
has been viewed as positive effects by supporters of CML since the 1990s. The Report is
strongly pushing for transatlantic liberalization, citing mainly the possible benefits of free
capital mobility such as:
•
reducing trading cost, and in particular low cost of financial transaction,
•
increase of investment returns,
•
lowering the cost of capital when firms invest
•
increasing liquidity in the financial market and
•
increasing economic growth and positive employment effects on both sides of the
Atlantic.
Surely, CML has benefits. Yet, as aforementioned, there are also costs of fast CML, in
particular CML with inappropriate sequencing.
Often the theory of perfect capital market has been used in order to justify fast and radical
market liberalizations, i.e., product and capital market liberalizations. Also the above stated
report by the Council on Foreign Relations is not free of such a charge. We here do not want
to go further into the political motivation and strategic thinking behind the fostering of quick
5
capital CML. Yet, whereas some part of the academic profession broadly continues to see
benefits outweighing the costs of market liberalization for goods and services, other see
problems and the strategy of rapid CML has recently become under scrutiny. Too fast
liberalized capital markets, for example a CML with a wrong sequencing, can trigger
financial instability, contagion effects and strong negative external effects on the real side of
the economy. Thus, capital market liberalization -- at least in the short run-- does not
necessarily show the same beneficial effects as product market liberalization.
c)
The Negative Externalities of fast CML
Negative externalities of fast CML are stated in the recently published book by Stiglitz et al.
(2006). This book gives a fair account of the pro and cons of fast CML. The major argument
of the authors is that too fast a CML leads to financial instability and boom and bust cycles,
hampering economic growth in the long run. Taking the view that capital markets are
basically imperfect, they argue that free capital markets have significantly different effects
than free trade. CML might not produce the promised benefits but as Stiglitz et al (2006)
summarize:
•
National fiscal and monetary policies become difficult to pursue, since national
government have to exclusively respond to the signals of the capital market, when
pursuing policy objectives
•
Boom and bust cycles may be emerging instead of steady development (booms in
housing sector, in land prices and equity prices as well as consumer purchases of
imported good lead to distortions of balanced growth, and are usually corrected by
periods of busts)
•
Financial instability and credit crises, leading to a general contraction of credit and
higher risk premia for loans, hamper the economic development
•
There are strong contagion effects of financial busts, since capital movements – the
inflow and outflow of capital -- are fast as compared to the change in trade flows
•
The low income segment of the population as well as small businesses cannot
insure and protect themselves against the risk that arises when bubbles burst and
recessionary periods occur (or are prolonged). Indeed, those groups are mostly
affected.
6
Thus the proponents of (fast) CML frequently overlook the imperfectly working of capital
markets and attribute too much of a self-correcting mechanism to the capital markets.
Frequently there is also mentioned insufficient regulatory or supervisory institutions for the
banking system, the stock market or real estate market such that there are no stabilizing
forces or safety nets for certain countries--- this in particular holds, as recent history of
financial events have shown, for emerging markets and developing economies. Yet, even
advanced countries with a long tradition of regulatory institutions such as banking and stock
market regulations are also not protected from such events and the negative externalities of
financial crashes and busts --- as recent history, after the introduction of a new wave of
financial innovations, has shown.
d)
How does Economic Theory see CML?
Both theoretical and empirical work on the relationship of financial and real activities has
been undertaken by different schools of economic thought. One currently prominent school
refers to the theory of perfect capital markets. Perfect capital markets are mostly assumed in
intertemporal general equilibrium theory (stochastic growth and Real Business Cycle (RBC)
theory). Yet they include no explicit modelling for the interaction of credit, asset prices, and
real activity. In contrast to this, many theoretical and empirical studies have applied the
theory of imperfect capital markets. Moreover, there are other traditions,
e.g., the Keynesian tradition as revived by Minsky (1975, 1986, 1998) and Tobin (1980) that
have been very influential in studying the interaction between financial markets and
economic activity. There is, currently, also another important view on this interaction and this
is represented by Shiller's (1991, 2001) overreaction hypothesis.
The research that has influenced our thinking here is heavily influenced by Keynesian
tradition, yet one can also draw upon recent developments in information economics, as
developed by Stiglitz and others wherein systematic attempts have been made to describe
how actual financial markets operate. Many studies of financial markets, for example this is
Stiglitz`s view, claim that a crucial impediment to the functioning of the financial system is
asymmetric information. In this situation, one party to a financial contract has much less
information than the other. Borrowers, for example, usually have much better information
about the potential returns of their investment projects and the associated risks than do the
potential lenders.
Asymmetric information leads to two other basic problems: adverse
selection and moral hazard.
7
Adverse selection occurs when those borrowers with the greatest potential for default actively
seek out loans. Since they are not likely to repay the loan anyway, they may offer a high
interest rate. Thus, those borrowers who lenders should most avoid are most likely to obtain
loans. If the percentage of potentially "bad" borrowers is perceived as too high by the lender,
he/she may simply decide to ration loans or to make no loans at all.
Moral hazard takes place after a transaction has taken place. Here, lenders are subject to
hazards since the borrower has incentives to engage in activities that are undesirable from the
lenders point of view. Moral hazard occurs if the borrower does well when the project
succeeds, but the lender bears most of the cost when the project fails. Borrowers may also
use loans inefficiently, e.g., personal expenses. Lenders may impose restrictions, face
screening and enforcement costs, and this may lead, in turn, to credit rationing for the entire
population of borrowers.
The existence of asymmetric information, adverse selection, and moral hazard also explains
why there is an important role for the government to play in the regulation and supervision of
the financial marketplace. To be useful, regulation and supervision mechanisms must aim
towards the maximization of access to information, while minimizing adverse selection and
moral hazard. This requires the production of information through screening and monitoring.
Firms and banks need to be required to adhere to standards of accounting and to publicly state
information about their sales, assets, and earnings. Additionally, safety nets for institutions
as well as for individuals are necessary to avoid the risks of a rapid liberalization of financial
markets.
Already in the 1990s much critical work on this was published. Mishkin (1998), for example,
has posited an explanation of the Asian financial crisis of 1997/8 using the above
information-theoretic ideas. A similar theory by Krugman (1999, 2000) laid the blame on
banks' and firms' deteriorating balance sheets. Miller and Stiglitz (1999) employ a multipleequilibria model to explain financial crises in general. Now, whereas these theories point to
the perils of too fast a liberalization of financial markets and to the role of government bank
supervision and guarantees, Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (2001) view government
guarantees as actual causes of financial crises. These authors argue that the lack of private
hedging of exchange rate risk by firms and banks led to financial crises in Asia. Other
authors, following the bank run model of Diamond and Dybvig (1983) argue that financial
8
crises occur if there is a lack of short-term liquidity. Further modeling of financial crises
triggered by exchange rate shocks can be found in Schneider and Tornell (2004) and Edwards
(1999) and Rogoff (1999), the latter discuss the role of the IMF as the lender of last resort.
Recent work on the roles of currency in financial crises can be found in Aghion et. al. (2004),
Corsetti et al. (1998), Flaschel and Semmler (2007), Proano, et. al., (2006), Kato and
Semmler (2005) and Roethig, Semmler and Flaschel (2007). The latter authors pursue a
macroeconomic approach to model currency and financial crises and consider also the role of
currency hedging in mitigating financial crises. Recently, since 2007/8, many research papers
in the same vain have piled on the web-site of the Fed, in particular papers by Bernanke and
Mishkin, see Bernanke et al (1983; 1994; 1998) and Miskin (1998, 2008).3
III:
THE DIFFERENT CAPITAL MARKET REGULATORY REGIMES
IN THE
US
AND
EUROPE
While the US and EU play the dominant role in global financial markets as both the largest
and most liquid financial markets worldwide, they operate under quite different regulatory
regimes. Despite these continuing regulatory differences, the degree of market integration
between the two transatlantic markets has increased over the last two decades, as formal
barriers to trade and investment have been reduced and financial markets have been
increasingly liberalized on both sides of the Atlantic. The recent subprime crisis is a good
illustration of how quickly the effects of the leveraged loan market failures were transmitted
to Europe and elsewhere. The subsequent joint transatlantic policy response to the financial
crisis was a further indicator of the increasing transatlantic interdependence of financial
markets. But despite the fact that formal barriers to free flows of capital have been removed,
differences in licensing rules for financial service providers and products, conduct of
business, investor protection, and reporting requirements continue to restrict the free market
3
As shown above, many observers of the financial crises in emerging markets during the period 1997 - 1999
were very quick to blame loose standards of accounting, the lack of safety nets, etc. as being root causes. Yet,
the years 2001 - 2002 have already shown that even advanced countries e.g. the United States, Europe, and
Japan cannot escape excessive asset price volatility and financial instability. As things have turned out,
however, the same loose accounting practices, the lack of supervision by executive boards and regulatory
institutions, and the role of big banks in helping to disguise huge corporate debt has led to a general distrust by
shareholders and the general public with respect to “fair” asset prices. Moreover, the experience of the most
recent financial market disruption point to a host of additional failures in the financial market oversight and
regulation, to be further discussed below.
9
access on both sides of the Atlantic, which increases the transaction costs for market
participants and investors in Europe and the US (Deutsche Bank Research 2008).
Historically, the US regulatory regime has relied more on market-control whereas in Europe,
until the capital market reforms in the latter half of the 1990s, financial market regulation and
supervision was the domain of national public authorities. Today’s regulatory frameworks in
the US and, until recently, in member states of the European Union, are the result of policy
rules formulated in national capitals for purely national financial markets. Only with the
reform of the EU capital markets along the Financial Service Action Plans (FSAP), tabled by
the EU Commission in May 1999, and the new decision-making procedures known as the
‘Lamfalussy process”, accepted at the Stockholm Council Meeting in 2001, has the more
restrictive European national-state-based regulatory system of the early 1990s given way to
the supranationalization of capital markets in the EU (Mügge 2008). To integrate and
Europeanize the financial markets, the Lamfalussy Plan proposed central bodies in the form
of the European Securities Committee (ESC) and the Committee of European Securities
Regulators (CESR), staffed by member state representatives and an advisory committee of
national experts (Donnelly 2007). In particular, the CESR has since been recognized as one
of the central bodies in EU capital market regulation. As a result of the new rule making
authority in the EU, capital market regulation has changed fundamentally. Its novelty lies in
its supranationalization supplanting the fragmented national regulatory rule-making of
individual member states (Mügge 2008; Donnelly 2007; Posner 2008; Bieling 2003).
In contrast to this more centralized institutional EU regulatory framework (Posner 2008), the
United States still relies on regulatory institutions created in response to the financial
meltdown of the 1930s. The goal was to create independent regulatory institutions, such as
the Security and Exchange Commission (SEC), to take politics out of national regulation and
ensure a more market-oriented regulatory environment. But this independent regulatory
framework has had the effect of creating regulators who tenaciously defend their autonomy
against political intervention, and are reluctant to give up their independent powers (Evenett
and Stern 2008).
To overcome the fragmented regulatory environment across the Atlantic and reduce the
impediments to transatlantic financial integration, Angela Merkel as President of the
European Council, and George W. Bush, President of the United States, put forward an
initiative in April 2007 for joint transatlantic cooperation and risk control. The Framework
10
for Advancing Transatlantic Economic Integration Between the European Union and the
United States of America, Annex 6 explicitly addresses the differences in the financial market
structure and regulations on both sides of the Atlantic and its intent to advance convergence
and cooperation between EU and US financial regulators. It is estimated that the greater
integration could result in savings in transaction costs per year USD 48 billion in securities
trading alone, and create the basis for annual transaction volume to rise from USD 21 trillion
to USD 31 trillion (Deutsche Bank Research 2008: 1). The US, according to Al Hubbard,
director of the White House National Economic Council, fully supports the call by Angela
Merkel, to use political pressure “to convince the bureaucrats to make regulatory reforms that
will result in a reduction in barriers between the European Union and the US” (Financial
Times 2007).
Even if the United States and the EU are “condemned to co-operate” as Charlie McGreevy,
the European Commissioner responsible for the Internal Market suggested (Evenett and Stern
2008), it is much too early to evaluate the likely outcome of this ambitious goal to strengthen
economic integration across the Atlantic. The informal Financial Markets Regulatory
Dialogue has met regularly and served as a platform for discussing policy responses to the
subprime crisis. At their recent meeting in June 2008, the SEC and the EU Commission
agreed to pursue mutual recognition as the main instrument for further integration and to
develop an agenda in order to review the current positions of the US and EU in global
financial markets and the remaining regulatory barriers, discuss the strategies to resolve these
issues and the institutional framework in place, and address the policy initiatives going
forward. Mutual recognition, which in fact the EU Commission had also chosen over full
harmonization as an approach to integrate the EU capital markets, means that each country
recognizes regulation of the other country as fully equivalent, and “allows market participants
or products licensed in country B to move freely in the host market without additional
requirements” (Deutsche Bank Research 2008: 14).
It remains to be seen, if US regulators are willing to consider the cross-border consequences
of their actions and share regulatory powers multilaterally (Evenett and Stern 2008). Due to
the US hegemony in global financial markets, there is, as Simmons (2001) has pointed out,
little incentive for the US to adjust its own policies in response to external pressures.
However, the gross deficiencies in the US regulatory system which have surfaced during the
11
recent subprime crisis may open a window of opportunity and a policy space to change the
present regulatory power equation.
CAUSES AND EFFECTS OF THE CURRENT FINANCIAL MARKET CRISIS
IV:
Next it is worth focusing more in detail on the current financial market events, in particular
the US subprime crisis, how it evolved as financial market melt down and created contagion
effects for Europe. Both Central Banks, the Fed and the ECB --- and regulatory institutions-face new challenges, given the spread of the financial market crisis on both sides of the
Atlantic. Yet, let us first survey briefly what has led to the financial market melt down since
the middle of last year.
As recent events have shown, reflected also in recent academic debates, there are large
externalities and contagion effects arising from financial instabilities -- either arising from
the stock market (as in the 1990s) or from the credit market, for example as now triggered by
the subprime crisis. The evolution of the subprime crisis and its effect on the financial sector
in the US is described by using some detailed figures in the Appendices 1 and 2. There it is
shown that
•
the current financial market crisis originated in low interest rates, rapidly rising
household debt, and a bubble in the housing market (high housing prices compared to
fundamentals),
•
the bubble is accelerated by the outsourcing of risk due to the securitization of
mortgages (that have been packaged and sliced in risky securities of different types,
CDOs),
•
expectation of returns from investment in real estate and CDOs were rising (due to
low interest rates, low default rates and high discovery rates)
•
liquidity in the housing sector (and financial market) was pumped up by capital
inflows
•
the burst of the bubble was triggered by Bear Stearns` hedge funds` failure,
triggering a credit crunch in the banking sector
•
suddenly default risk and risk premia were shooting up and a credit crunch occurred
(as at the beginning of all town-turns),
12
•
the feedback to the real sector makes then the growth rate of the GDP falling, with
further feedback effects from the real to the financial side (a recession is defined by
the NBER as negative growth rates for two quarters)
Indeed, one can show that this time the financial market crisis originated in the housing
market and then was transmitted to the banking sector. This has not been always so. Often a
stock market crash triggers the downturn, but not this time. The stock market reaction came
later. When the investors in subprime mortgages felt the first fall out, the holders of those
securities felt a massive credit crunch (starting with the two Bear Stearns` hedge funds in the
Summer 2007). Subsequently many big investment banks in the US –and in Europe-- where
threatened by insolvency (see Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Citibank, Morgan and Stanley,
but see also the two German Banks, and the BLB). Thus, now the credit crisis appears to also
spreading to Europe.
V:
FINANCIAL MARKET CRISIS AND MONETARY POLICY
As the financial market melt down evolved, this became a great challenge to the central
banks. Often the central banks, in spite of their initial denial, are forced to heavily intervene
in the financial markets (in the stock market or credit market). Although traditionally only
inflation targeting was the proclaimed goal of the central banks, yet recently both the Fed and
the ECB have moved away from this and heavily intervened in the financial market.
We want to note that a strong sporadic intervention has already been undertaken under
Greenspan, since the 1990s. A detailed evaluation of the central banks’ action with respect to
the stock market, during the technology bubble, and their potential success or failure can be
found in Greenspan`s recent book. As it was well understood at that time, of course,
monetary authorities can and should not target specific levels of asset prices. There are
fundamentally justified movements in asset prices -- for bond prices, credit cost, stock prices
and exchange rates. Although asset price misalignments, see the BIS survey, are difficult to
measure, as are potential output, future inflation rates and equilibrium interest rates, this
should be no reason to ignore them. For a more detailed analysis and for the issues involved,
see Cecchetti, Genberg, Lipsky and Wadhwani (2000) and Semmler and Zhang (2002).
Monetary authorities should help to provide stability for the financial market and reduce the
13
likelihood of financial instability. In the earlier literature, with a view on the 1990s, this was
discussed with respect to the extreme changes in asset prices, in particular stock prices.
Now, with the outbreak of the credit crisis triggered by the subprime sector and the entailing
financial melt down, in particular in the credit sector, central banks intervention in the credit
sector became a major issue. As abovementioned, though traditionally only inflation targeting
was the proclaimed goal of the central banks, yet recently both the Fed and the ECB
undertook drastic actions --- and also coordinated world wide actions--- to prevent the credit
crisis from spreading and a financial market melt down. In November 2007 a joint action of
Western central banks were undertaken to provide more liquidity for the private sector, in
particular for the banking sector, given the clear sign of a credit crunch. Moreover, the US
Fed provided more liquidity in the first quarter of 2008, first a plan of inject $200 bill and
then actually assisted in bailing out Bear Stearns by JP Morgan in the middle of March.
Moreover, overall, up to the time this paper was written in September 2008, the short term
interest rate in the US had been taken down from 5.25 % to 2.00%.
For the interested observer this change in direction of monetary policy from inflation
targeting to heavy intervention in the financial market did not come without surprise. Ben
Bernanke, now the Fed Chair, had already written academic papers that advocated a strong
intervention of the central bank in case of a financial market melt down, see Bernanke et al
(2004). Already in his earlier papers Bernanke and co-authors had put forward the view that
the central bank should buy private assets if it had come to an end of its interest rate policy.
This not only would prevent further fall in asset prices but in particular drive down the long
term interest rate. Though the paper originally was written with an eye on the Japanese long
period of stagnation, starting in the 1990s, when the zero inflation rate and almost zero
interest rates, did not leave any room for monetary policy, Bernanke and co-authors hint
already at a possible US application. Now, in fact the US central bank had been applying this
non-traditional monetary policy, the success of which still has to be judged in the future.
On the other hand, the European Central Bank the ECB, was always more conservative in its
monetary policy stands, first by applying the two pillar concept and second giving more
attention to the inflation rate than to output or the financial market and its possible
externalities to the real economy. The two pillar concept is that the ECB kept the tradition of
controlling the money supply, as advocated by the Bundesbank, but at the same time it
14
pursued direct inflation targeting through discretionary interest rate setting. Further
development in the financial market sector and spillovers of the financial meltdown to the EU
will test whether the ECB is equipped to deal with severe financial market turmoil. Peter
Praet, an official of the Belgium Central bank, stated on March 17, 2008 at the London
school of Economics “If a major European (financial) institution were to get into trouble, the
institutional mechanism that are in place could be too weak to handle it” (FT, March 18)
Overall, the claim of the recent monetary concept, that the central banks should restrict
themselves to inflation targeting, giving some weight to output targeting, came under stress
not only in the 1990s already but particular since the outbreak of the subprime crisis and the
ensuing credit crisis and financial melt down. It would indeed be a too easy a concept that the
modern central bank undertake some fine tuning of the economy, engineering interest rate
changes in some direction and steering the economy toward some steady employment, or
“natural rate of unemployment”. As Ned Phelps, the Nobel Laureate in Economics of 2006
often writes, in a dynamic capitalist market economy there is too much uncertainty of what
the natural rate of interest is, and what the medium run natural unemployment rate will be, in
order that the economy could be steered, with not much inflation rate, close to it: both
“natural rates” are “always shifting, temporarily or permanent, with new developments”
(Phelps , in Wall Street Journal, March 14, 2008). Now a new uncertainty is added to the
central bank challenges: the uncertainty of an evolving financial market melt down.
VI:
FINANCIAL MARKET CRISIS AND FINANCIAL MARKET REGULATIONS
As we have shown in section II of the paper the role of financial markets has grown due to
deregulation, liberalization of capital accounts in many countries, financial innovations and
development of new financial instruments such as financial derivatives, CDS, CDOs, LDOs
and so on. For some countries CML has been accompanied by an economic boom. On the
other hand, numerous countries have experienced major episodes of financial instability,
some times with devastating effects on economic activity, and thus boom and bust cycles,
often entailing declining economic activity, large output losses and strong negative effects on
the low income segment of the population and small businesses, which cannot insure
themselves against those large financial and real shocks.
As we have stressed, a particularly great concern of our study are the externalities that the
financial markets can create when financial bubbles burst. As we currently can observe, the
15
burst of the real estate bubble in the US and the fall-out for the US banking system had severe
real effects, triggering a recession in the US.
Traditionally, for most advanced countries such negative externalities of the burst of financial
market bubbles have been observed a long time ago. In order to prevent this, it had not only
required regulatory institutions and public screening and monitoring of the financial market,
but firms and banks were required to adhere to strict standards of accounting and publicly
reveal information on assets, debt and earnings. As has been realized, fast liberalization of the
financial market entails that there is a great risk if there is insufficient financial market
regulation, inexperienced and loose supervision, no disclosure requirement, no screening and
monitoring of financial institutions and no secure safety net for the financial institutions (for
example, insurance for bank deposits (as enacted in the 1930s). Yet, weak accounting
standards and loose supervision cannot only be found in emerging markets, but also in the US
and advanced countries, as the book by MacAvoy and Millstein (2004) demonstrates. The
latter authors have strongly endorsed additional regulation, by testifying in front of congress
when the Sarbanes-Oxley act was initiated after the Enron-collapse.
Now, the recent financial market event, in particular the subprime financial crisis in the US,
has transformed itself into a credit crisis and financial market melt down. This has triggered a
new discussion on financial market regulation and oversight. In the US, due to the recently
triggered huge financial losses of investment banks, mortgage firms and commercial banks,
the media, regulatory institutions, (such as the SEC) and the congress (see the testimony by
Robert Kuttner) have vigorously put forward new ideas on the oversight and regulation of the
financial markets. A similar discussion has started in Europe. Recently, for the G7 meeting
on April 12, 2008, the Financial Stability Committee (a Committee initiated by the G7
Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors in October 2007) has recommended actions to
“Enhance Market and Institutional Resilience”. Also, Congress in the US has held many
hearings and suggested many measures to improve regulation and oversight of the financial
market.
Now, after numerous discussion and studies the following consensus as to financial boombust cycles seems to be widely emerging:
16
1) Bubbles are common in financially driven market economies, and the subprime case has
all the makings of a typical financial market bubble.
2) Bubbles have huge negative externalities when they burst, but they might have also
positive real effects while they are building up.
3) Bubbles should be contained by risk management, regulations and oversight; the public
should not bear the cost of insolvencies, but should bear the cost of providing liquidity.
Each of these can be spelled out further:
1) Bubbles are common in financially driven market economies, and the subprime case
has all the makings of a typical financial market bubble
The subprime crisis arose from overuse of an imperfectly understood financial innovation.
This was the securitization of credit risk through CDOs – which were supposed to make the
economy safer. Yet, instead their widespread use in the mortgage market contributed to a
typical financial market bubble very similar to others that the US and other advanced macro
economies have seen. These go back a long time: there was the Florida real estate bubble in
the early 1920s, the stock market bubble in the late 1920s, the tech stock bubble in the late
1990s, the real estate bubble in the UK in the early 1990s, and the US since 2000, and the
bubble in the futures market for oil and other resources, in recent times. These bubbles have
tended to happen more frequently, the more the financial market has been deregulated (the
Glass–Steagall Act, introduced in the 1930s, restricting the banks to hold other financial
assets than treasury bonds, was removed in the 1999. Indeed, provisions which prohibit a
bank holding company from owning other financial companies were repealed in 1999 by the
Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act.
Usually, as we have shown in section III, as a bubble develops, asset price inflation and credit
expansion usually move in tandem. The bubble will be particularly pronounced when the
financial sector expands more rapidly than the rest of the economy, as has happened in the
US. This pattern can be seen in the subprime market: with a low cost of borrowing (low
interest rates) and expected prices of the subprime assets rising (due to expected adjustable
interest rate etc.), incentives developed to hold an excessive amount of inventories of
subprime CDOs; this also created incentives for banks to finance those inventories through
loans (even though the collateral might be suspect): eventual sales of such inventories seemed
to promise huge margins. Yet, the data on returns from CDOs is scarce, and there were only a
few academic studies on how large the expected margins might be, as compared to the returns
17
on other assets. Finally, there was no specific market to evaluate such assets and the actual
profitability of those of CDOs, and the more risky tranches of it, went down to due to higher
default risk and lower recovery rates, which the actually produced the collapse to those
highly risky securities, see Bernhard and Semmler (2008).
2) Bubbles have huge negative externalities when they burst but they may have also
positive real effects while they are building up
It is a mistake to think that all bubbles are all bad; in fact some bubbles leave the economy
significantly better off - with higher productive capacity, more and better skills and higher
income. A good example is the technology bubble in the US in the late 1990s. The US had its
bubble and strong growth --- Europe had no bubbles and no economic growth. Recent
financial market innovations also enhanced economic growth and facilitated the purchase of
houses for the low income sector.
On the other hand, financial bubbles do have negative effects, even apart from the damage
when they burst. For example they may produce or enhance uneven income distribution (tides
do not lift all boats, but mainly yachts) and they may lead to misallocation of resources (e.g.
the huge build up of optical fiber in the US). And even before it bursts, the bubble creates
financial instability; other sectors may be pulled into unwarranted booms. With the bubble or
bubbles bursting then, there will be huge externality effects, falling asset prices in the bubble
will pull down other asset prices, the value of collateral will fall, and loans will be called in;
credit markets will contract, and financial institutions will suffer. Many completely
‘innocent’ agents – who made no unwarranted or speculative decisions - will be dragged
down, and this will spill over onto the real side of the economy—thus leading to a negative
impact on employment and output.
In general, and particularly for the recent subprime bubble, we can say that the risk that has
been built up has had two components:
a) Idiosyncratic risk
This applies to the individual financial institutions. This is risk from high expected margins,
cheap sources of funding for speculative or Ponzi positions, lack of adequate or internal risk
assessment and in the financial institution itself, lack of diversification (all parties follow the
same strategies, for example attempting to replicate the hedge funds’ beta), lack of sufficient
capital requirements, underrated risk by rating agencies, and lack of accountability.
18
b) Common risk
This arises from higher interest rates, falling consumption and investment demand, sudden
increases in risk perception (emerging credit defaults, swaps and spreads rising), correlated
risk and tighter credit markets with increased credit constraints.
Widespread build-up of idiosyncratic risk can then lead to the emergence, even the sudden
emergence, of a dangerous level of common risk.
3) Bubbles should be contained by risk management, regulations and oversight, and the
public should not bear the cost of insolvencies, but it should bear the cost of providing
liquidity.
There should be a revival of serious discussion on banking regulation, and on the regulation
and oversight of other financial institutions, but this discussion should not pretend to remove
or avoid all financial bubbles. First, this may be too much to ask of government, but, second
it also is not needed, given the remarks above.
A) What Academics have proposed:
a) increased personal accountability of the executive decision-makers, particularly the top
CEOs of financial institutions (see the Sarbanes- Oxley act, triggered after the Enron
collapse).
b) there should be more effort made of better risk management. Inside financial institutions
risk control divisions should be set up; proper risk assessments should also be made through
independent rating agencies, so that a proper risk assessment takes place (federal oversight of
rating agencies as introduced by the Sarbanes-Oxley act).
c) capital requirements should be increased for the financial institutions - in particular those
that are not required by law to hold reserves at the Central Bank. I has also been suggested to
enforce procyclical capital requirements, see for example the suggestion by Goodhart. Capital
requirements, in particular should be increased for the new financial products, such as certain
complex credit products.
d) incentives should be provided to financial institutions for a diversification of capital
assets, so that financial institutions should not follow the same strategies --- e.g. all holding
promising subprime CDOs with high expected margins.
19
e) better and faster enforcement of Basle II agreements (which do not seem to have been
enforced much in the US). According to State regulatory agencies, Basel II has been
approved through the federal State, at the time of the agreement, but not by the regulatory
agencies of the States (which appear to act independently)
f) there should be better information and transparency, for example, quarterly reports to
the SEC, transparency of risky exposure by banks, investment firms and Hedge funds, and
independent scholarly work on asset returns in new areas of financial innovations (the
magnitude of returns from assets are roughly known - for example equity returns, bond
returns, returns from currency and future markets - but there are no similar studies for the
new financial instruments).
g) And finally: there should not be any commitment to ‘bail outs’. The public should not
bear the cost of a bail out when insolvency arises, but the public should bear the cost of
providing liquidity so that no insolvency arises due to a lack of liquidity, often resulting
from the feedback effects to the two types of risk discussed in point 2) above. Note, that the
view expressed here is similar to a position recently taken in a draft for enhanced financial
market regulation by the European parliament.
B) What Congress, the Administration and the Financial Stability Forum (FSF) have
proposed
Senator Schumer’s office in NY has proposed several improvement on the financial
regulation of the mortgage and financial sectors and Congress has held hearings and
testimonies with experts, see Kuttner`s (2007) testimony in front of Congress. The Bush
administration has proposed a mitigation of the victims of the subprime crises by extending
the period of fixed interest rates for certain income groups, and other measures. The
remaining presidential candidates are also very active in proposing new emergency,
regulatory and oversight measures. But there does not seem to be any effective measure in
sight to stop the falling asset prices in real estate and accelerating foreclosures.
As we have discussed in section IV, the Fed had, under Greenspan, attempted to intervene in
the asset price bubbles (tech bubble), but credit and banking crises and a crisis in the bond
market are a different matter. A judgement on the real pre-emptive regulatory potentials of
central banks, the Fed in the US and the ECB in Europe, is still out. In particular, because
20
CML sets in motion a much greater contagion effect than trade liberalizations, some
international cooperation in this area, in order to avoid the contagion effects of the financial
credit crises, are strongly needed.
The latter has recently been pursued by a G7 meeting on April 12, 2008 following a proposal
by the Financial Stability Forum which has suggested actions to “Enhance Market and
Institutional Resilience”. The FSF focuses 1) increasing the capita requirements ( in
particular for complex structured credit products) and strengthening liquidity and risk
management (specially for off- balance sheet entities), 2) enhancing and improving
transparency and valuation through credit rating agencies, 3) increase the authorities`
responsiveness to risk (translating risk analysis into action, and 4) extension of the
arrangements to deal wit financial stress and disruptions (extending central banks`policy to
asset purchases and liquidity provisions for the private sector. So, far at least what the press
has reported, the increase in capital requirements seems to be high on the agenda.
VII.
CONCLUSIONS
We have addressed in this paper essential issues on the transatlantic financial market
liberalization and its possible pitfalls. Previous studies frequently have concentrated on the
benefits of the financial market liberalization on both sides of the Atlantic. Yet, due to the
recent credit and financial market crisis, the cost of fast and excessive financial liberalizations
has come into focus. In the last two decades it has become clear that Capital Market
Liberalization (CML) is more complex than, for example, trade liberalization of goods and
services. In contrast to the theory of perfect capital markets, we here start from the more
realistic framework of imperfect capital markets. Starting point here is the theory of
information economics and the Keynesian theory of the working of capital markets. We deal
with the benefits but also the potential shortcomings of CML. Whereas the academic
profession broadly seems to continue to see benefits outweighing the costs of market
liberalization for goods and services, yet fast and drastic CML has recently become under
scrutiny. Too fast liberalized capital markets, for example a CML with a wrong sequencing,
and without “safety nets” are likely to trigger boom–bust cycles, financial instability,
contagion effects and strong negative effects of financial market melt downs on the real side
of the economy. Thus, capital market liberalization – at least in the short run-- does not
necessarily show the same beneficial effects as product market liberalization. Yet, we have
21
also demonstrated that not all bubbles are bad, some may lead to higher growth rates and
result in higher level of output .
We also have shown that what is understood under CML appears to be different on both sides
of the Atlantic. In particular, this perspective seems to hold true on oversight and regulation
of the financial markets. In the US, regulatory institutions are more akin to represent some
type of self-control of the market and are market friendly, whereas politicians in Europe seem
to support more public regulations, oversight and interventions. We have discussed the causes
and effects of the current financial market melt down and the role Central Banks played to
contain the financial market melt down on both sides of the Atlantic. We have described and
studied the recent proposals on regulations, oversight and risk management. We in particular
discussed and analysed the newly proposed financial market regulations as they were
triggered by the recent financial market crisis. Yet, we want to remark that many of the
effects of the recent financial market disruption (Miskin 2008) on the real side are still
uncertain and many of the currently proposed new regulations of the financial market are still
in a preliminary stage.
Future discussions will still have to sort out what are useful
regulations in the long run.
22
References
Aghion, P., Bacchetta, P. and Banerjee, A. 2004, ‘A Corporate Balance-Sheet Approach to
Currency Crises’, Journal of Economic Theory, vol. 119, pp. 6–30.
Bernanke, B. (1983), ''Non-Monetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the
Great Depression'', American Economic Review, 73, June:257-276.
Bernanke, B., and M. Gertler (1994), ''The Financial Accelerator and the Flight to Quality''.
Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 78, no. 1: 1-15.
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and S. Gilchrist (1998), ''The Financial Accelerator in a
Quantitative Business Cycle Framework'', NBER working paper, no 6455, forthcoming in J.
Taylor and M. Woodford (eds), Handbook of Macroeconomics, Amsterdam, North-Holland
Bernanke, B., V. R. Reinhard, and B.P. Sack (2004), Monetary Policy Alternatives at the
Zero Bound: An Empirical Assessment, Federal Reserve Board, Washington. D.C. no 48.
Bernhard, L. and W. Semmler (2008), Credit Derivatives in the Housing Markets and its
Collapse, mimeo, New School.
Bieling, Hans-Jürgen (2004). The New European Economy and Transatlantic Relations.
Paper prepared for the International Studies Association, March 2004, Montreal. Canada.
Bieling, Hans-Jürgen (2003). Social Forces in the Making of the New European Economy:
The Case of Financial Market Integration, New Political Economy, vol. 8, no. 2: 203-224.
Burnside, C., Eichenbaum, M. and Rebelo, S. 2001, ‘Hedging and Financial Fragility in
Fixed Exchange Rate Regimes’, European Economic Review, vol. 45, pp. 1151–1193.
Cechetti, S.G., H. Genberg, J. Lipsky and S. Wadhwani (2000), ''Asset Prices and Central
Bank Policy'', Geneva Reports on the World Economy, no. 2, International Center for
Monetary and Banking Studies and Cener for Economic Policy Research.
Council on Foreign Relations (2002), Building a Transatlantic Security Market, authored by
Benn Stein.
Corsetti, G., P. Presenti and N. Roubini (1998), ''What caused the Asian Currency and
Financial Crisis'', NBER paper no. 2633.
Diamond, P. and P. Dybvik (1983), ''Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity'', Journal of
Political Economy.
Deutsche Bank Research (2008). EU-US financial market integration a work in progress.
Financial Market Special. EU Monitor 56.
Evenett, Simon and Robert M. Stern (2008). “Condemned to Co-Operate”? The Merkel
Initiative and Its Systemic Implications. Conference Paper at the University of Michigan, 7th
May, 2008.
23
Financial Times (2007). Transatlantic talks ‘to tackle barriers’ (27. June 2007).
Flaschel, P. and Semmler, W. 2006, ‘Currency Crisis, Financial Crisis, and Large Output
Loss’, in C. Chiarella, P. Flaschel, R. Franke and W. Semmler (eds), Quantitative and
Empirical Analysis of Nonlinear Dynamic Macromodels. Contributions to Economic
Analysis (series editors: Baltagi, B., Sadka E. and D. Wildasin), Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp.
385–414.
Kato, M. and W. Semmler (2005), ''Currency Crises and Monetary Policy Rules'',
newschool.edu/gf/cem.
Krugman, P. 1999, ‘Analytical Afterthoughts on the Asian Crisis’, mimeo. Princeton
University.
Krugman, P. 2000, ‘Crises: The Price of Globalization?’, Global Economic Integration:
Opportunities and Challenges. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 75–106.
MacAvoy, P. and I. Millstein (2004), ''The Recurrent Cirsis in Corporate Governance,
Stanford University Press.
Miller, M. and J. Stiglitz (1999), ''Bankruptcy Protection against Macroeconomic Shocks'',
The World Bank, mimeo.
Minsky, H. P. (1975), John Maynard Keynes, Columbia New York University Press.
Minsky, H.P. (1982), ''Can it Happen again?'', Armonk: ME Sharpe.
Minsky, H.P. (1986), ''Stabilizing an Unstable Economy'', New Haven: Yale University
Press.
Mishkin, Frederic S. (2008). "Monetary Policy Flexibility, Risk Management, and Financial
Disruptions," speech delivered at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, New York,
January 11.
Mishkin, F.S. (1998), ''International Capital Movement,Financial Volatility and Financial
Instability'', NBER working paper, no. 6390.
Mügge, Daniel (2008). Widen the Market, Narrow the Competition. The Emergence of
Supranational Governance in EU Capital Markets. (Unpublished Dissertation, University of
Amsterdam).
Posner, Elliot 2008. The New Transatlantic Regulatory Relations in Financial Services. Paper
presented at the Venice Workshop on Global Financial Integration Thirty Years On.
Proaño, C.R., Flaschel, P. and Semmler, W. 2005, ‘Currency and Financial Crises in
Emerging Market Economies in the Medium Run’, Journal of Economic Asymmetries, vol. 2,
pp. 105–130.
24
Reszat, Beate (2003). How has the European Monetary Integration Process Contributed to
Regional Financial Market Integration? Hamburg Institute of International Economics,
Discussion Paper 221.
Roethig, A. W. Semmler and P. Flaschel, (2007) Corporate Currency Hedging and Currency
Crises, Australian Economic Papers.
Rogoff, K. (1999), ''International Institutions for Reducing Global Financial Instability'',
NBER working paper 7265, Cambridge.
Schneider, M. and Tornell, A. 2004, ‘Balance Sheet Effects, Bailout Guarantees and
Financial Crises’, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 71, pp. 883–913.
Semmler, W. and W. Zhang (2002), ''Asset Price Bubbles and Monetary Policy Rules: A
Dynamic Model and Evidence'', CEM, Bielefeld University, working paper.
Semmler, W., Greiner, A. and W. Zhang (2006). Monetary and Fiscal Policy in the EuroArea, Elsevier.
Semmler, W. (2006), Asset Prices, Booms and Recessions: Financial Economics from a
Dynamic Perspective, Heidelberg/New York, Springer Publishing House, 2nd edition.
Shawn Donnelly (2007). The Regimes of European Integration: Constructing Governance of
the Single Market. Unpublished Habilitation, University of Bremen.
Shiller, R. J. (1991), ''Market Volatility'' Cambridge: MIT Press.
Shiller, R.J. (2001), ''Irrational Exuberance'', New York: Random House.
Simmons, Beth A (2001) International Politics of Harmonization: the Case of Capital Market
Regulation. International Organization 55 (3): 589-620.
Tobin, J. (1980), ''Asset Accumulation and Economic Activity'', Oxford: Basic Blackwell.
25
Appendix 1: Some Figures on the Causes and Evolution of the Current Financial Crisis
The following presents some figures on the causes of the current subprime crisis that has let
to a large scale financial melt down.
Real mortgage interest rates (with naive and
survey inflation expectations)
(quarterly data; percentages, A. Fincelli “House price developments and fundamentals in the US”)
Real house prices and per capita disposable income
(quarterly data; indexes: average = 100, A. Fincelli “House price developments and fundamentals in the US”)
26
Household mortgage debt and real house prices
(quarterly data, A. Fincelli “House price developments and fundamentals in the US”)
Debt service ratio
(quarterly data; percentages, A. Fincelli “House price developments …”)
27
Inflation-adjusted US home prices, Population,
Building costs, and Bond yields (1900-2005)
(R. Shiller “Irrational Exuberance”, 2nd ed.)
Immobilienboom – USA (House prices/rents)
(J. Ayuso and F. Restoy: “House prices and rents: An equilibrium asset pricing approach”)
28
House prices/rents (Ln) – UK
(J. Ayuso and F. Restoy: “House prices and rents: An equilibrium asset pricing approach”)
Typical Boom-Bust-Cycle (credit,
realestate, banks)
(Reinhart/Rogoff 2008: Is the 2007 US Sub-Prime Financial Crisis So Different?)
29
Typical Boom-Bust Cycle
Reinhart/Rogoff (2008)
Typical Boom-Bust-Cycle (GDP
growth)
Reinhart/Rogoff (2008)
30
Domino Effect of the Subprime
Crisis (has hit the US economy and
other economies)
US-Fed and Euro-Area ECB (Interest rate policies)
Appendix 2: Risk Perception and Risk Premia Triggering Recessions
In the literature on financially driven boom- bust cycles a changing risk perception and risk
premium is predicted to occur over the boom-bust cycle. The following are some preliminary
results form the analysis of the risk perception expressed by the spread between AAA and
BAA corporate bonds and the economic activities, for details see Grüne, Chen and Semmler
(2008).
31
1. The spread = AAA-BAA is always negative. The magnitude becomes larger briefly
before and during the contraction. But the magnitudes vary largely from one
contraction to the other. The reason is that the spread itself depends on the current
riskless interest rate. Therefore a better measure to study the relation between the risk
perception and the contraction is not the spread itself but the relative spread (AAABAA)/BAA
2. In the graph of Quarterly Relative Spread of AAA and BAA the decreases of the
relative spread during the contraction are about the same magnitude. The shading
areas are the official contraction dating according to NBER.
Both figures confirm our hypothesis that during the contraction the risk perception is
increasing while during the expansion the risk perception is decreasing.
32
3. Since the relative spread is informative for the contraction, we try to estimate the
probability of contraction using a Markov switching model, see Grüne, Chen and
Semmler (2008) for details
The results show that the risk perception is very informative on economic contractions. In
most cases the economic contraction are predicted with high probability.
33
Download