1 Investment • Neo-Classical (Jorgenssen) • irreversability (Bentolila-Bertola / Bertola-Caballero) • Fixed costs (Caballero-Engle) — firm level — aggregation — general equilibrium 2 User Cost Value with complete markets X t,st ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ qt0 st dt st ¡ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ dt st = π kt st−1 , st − c kt st−1 , it st , st − pt st it st ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ kt+1 st = (1 − δ) kt st−1 + it st subsituting ¡ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¢ dt st = π kt st−1 , st − c kt st−1 , kt+1 st − (1 − δ) kt st−1 , st | {z } “blat (st )” • value ¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¢ −p (st ) kt+1 st − (1 − δ) kt st−1 X t,st ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¢¢ qt0 st blat st − pt st kt+1 st − (1 − δ) kt st−1 1 • if pt+1 (st+1 ) = pt (st ) then ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ X 0 ¡ t+1 ¢ ¡ ¢ qt+1 s (1 − δ) kt+1 st qt0 st kt+1 st − st+1 ¶ 1−δ Rt,t+1 ( st ) ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ q 0 (st ) = t t kt+1 st R st − 1 + δ R (s ) X ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ qt0 st kt+1 st R st − 1 + δ = µ ¡ t¢ ¡ t¢ 0 = qt s kt+1 s 1− st+1 • where risk-free rate • or at t + 1 simply ¡ ¢ R st = P qt0 (st ) 0 t+1 ) st+1 qt+1 (s ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ kt+1 st R st − 1 + δ • user cost (rental rate) ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ ν st ≡ pt st R st − (1 − δ) • assume pt (st ) 6= pt+1 (st , st+1 ) = pt+1 (st , ŝt+1 ) i.e. prices are not constant but predictable ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ X ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ pt st qt0 st kt+1 st − pt+1 st+1 qt0+1 st+1 (1 − δ) kt+1 st st+1 ¶ µ ¡ t¢ ¡ t¢ ¡ t¢ ¡ t+1 ¢ 1 − δ 0 = qt s kt+1 s pt s − pt+1 s R (st ) X ¡ t+1 ¢ ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¢ 0 = qt+1 s kt+1 st R st pt st − (1 + δ) pt+1 st+1 st+1 • user cost (rental rate) ¶ µ ¡ t¢ ¡ t¢ ¡ t¢ pt+1 (st+1 ) ν s ≡ pt s R s − (1 − δ) pt (st ) → physical and economic depreciation 2 • thus... ¡ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¢¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢¢ dt st = π kt st−1 , st −c kt st−1 , it st , st −p st kt+1 st − (1 − δ) kt st−1 ...equivalent to ¡ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ ¢ ¡ ¢ d˜t st = π kt st−1 , st − c kt st−1 , it st , st − ν (st ) kt s t−1 3 Irreversability or Costly Reversability Discrete example (see Dixit-Pindyck) • three periods t = −1, 0, 1 t = −1 invest k0 t = 0 invest k1 • at t = 0 learn A1 ∈ {AH , AL } • irreversability k1 ≥ k0 (1 − δ) • risk neutral pricing ¡ ¢ ¡ ¢ qt0 st ≡ R−t Pr s t • constant user cost v Firm problem µ µ −1 p max A0 F (k0 ) − vk0 + R k0 max k1 ≥k0 (1−δ) equivalently ¡ H ¢ A F (k1 ) − vk1 + (1 − p) max A0 F (k0 ) − vk0 + R−1 E V (k0 , A1 ) k0 V (k, A) = max AF (k 0 ) − vk0 k0 ≥k(1−δ) • unconstrained optimum max AF (k0 ) − vk0 0 k ¢ ¡ ⇒ AF 0 k# (A) − v = 0 3 max k1 ≥k0 (1−δ) ¶¶ (AL F (k1 ) − vk1 ) • if k1∗ (AL ) = k0 (1 − δ) AF 0 (k1 ) − v ≤ 0 ⇒A0 F 0 (k0 ) − v + 1−p (AL F 0 (k1 ) − v) (1 − δ) = 0 {z } R | − ⇒ k0∗ < k0# (A0 ) • another way of seeing this: A0 F 0 (k0 ) − v + E [Vk (k0 , A1 )] = 0 but Vk ≤ 0 and Vk < 0 in some state... • irreversability ⇒ lower investment • if kt ∈ {0, 1} ⇒ option value intuition [Dixit&Pyndick] • Q: lower average capital? A: NO • investment rule k0 ≥ k1∗ → don’t invest k0 < k1∗ → invest until k1 = k1∗ → barrier control • costly reversability capital sells at discount →upper barrier control • comparative statics increase uncertainty 4 4 Bentolila and Bertola • homogenous return π (k, z) = k α z 1−α • Bellman V (k− , z− ) = E ½ ¾ max [π (k, z) − rk + βV (k, z)] k≥(1−δ)k− • guess µ ¶ µ ¶ k k V (k, z) = zV , 1 = zv z z ½ µ µ ¶ ¶ ∙ µ ¶¸¾ µ ¶ k k k k− z π ,1 −r + βE zV ,z z− V ,1 = E max z k k z− z z z ≥(1−δ) − − z z z− • normalized v (k− ) = E ε max[π (k) − rk + βv (k)] k k ≥ ε−1 (1 − δ) k− s.t. • FOC π 0 (k∗ ) = r − βV 0 (k∗ ) • lower investment V 0 (k) ≤ 0 ⇒ k∗ < k# • Example: ε = { b , g } prob. λ, 1 − λ • no adjustment ⇒ k = (1 − δ) ε−1 k− then g b (1 − δ)2 = 1 ⇒ g = −1 b (1 − δ)−2 keeps us on a grid k∗ , k∗ −1 b (1 − δ)−1 , k ∗ k ∗ ( b (1 − δ))−n 5 −2 b (1 − δ)−2 , ... n = 0, 1, 2, ... • invariant pn = (1 − λ) pn+1 + λpn−1 p0 = (1 − λ) p1 + (1 − λ) p0 • solving 1 = (1 − λ) n = 1, 2, ... p1 p1 λ + (1 − λ) ⇒ = p0 p0 1−λ substituting pn+1 pn−1 pn+1 λ +λ ⇒ = pn pn pn 1−λ µ ¶n λ ⇒ pn = p0 1−λ 1 = (1 − λ) • costly reversability: regulate k from above as well • from Bertola-Bentolila Figure removed due to copyright restrictions. See Figure 1 on p. 388 in Bentolila, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola. "Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?" Review of Economic Studies 57, no. 3 (1990): 381-402. • Abel and Eberly (1999; JME) 6 5 Labor: Firing Costs • effects of firing costs on labor demand? • Bertola and Bertolila (1990) • Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993) Figure removed due to copyright restrictions. See Figure 2 on p. 392 in Bentolila, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola. "Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?" Review of Economic Studies 57, no. 3 (1990): 381-402. Figure removed due to copyright restrictions. See Figure 3 on p. 392 in Bentolila, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola. "Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?" Review of Economic Studies 57, no. 3 (1990): 381-402. 7 Higher uncertainty Figure removed due to copyright restrictions. See Figure 4 on p. 393 in Bentolila, Samuel, and Giuseppe Bertola. "Firing Costs and Labour Demand: How Bad is Eurosclerosis?" Review of Economic Studies 57, no. 3 (1990): 381-402. • Hopenhayn-Rogerson → ergodic distribution of shocks • entry and exit of firms • ergodic distribution of labor demand • compare steady states with and without 6 Aggregate Shocks • concerted shocks in z • distribution is state variable • average reaction depends on distribution 7 Fixed Costs • fixed cost if it > 0 8 • don’t invest unless its important → innaction (fixed cost is irreversable) • avoid fixed costs: lump investment (no small investments) • Ss rule • other end: generalized Ss 8 Generalized Hazard Caballero-Engle • probability of investing depends on distance from preferred point • previous case: discontinuous hazard • Calvo: constant hazard • example 1 aggregate firms with different sS rules • example 2 firms with random fixed cost 9 Aggregation • state: distribution of firms • evolution of distribution aggregate vs. idiosyncratic shocks • non-linear response • history matters 9 10 General Equilibrium Julia Thomas → small effects in GE Bachman-Caballero-Engle → large in recalibrated model 10