On the Size of the Active Management Industry Ľuboš Pástor Booth School of Business University of Chicago NBER, CEPR Robert F. Stambaugh The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania NBER Q-Group Presentation, March 23, 2010 The “Active Management Puzzle”? I Track record of the active management (AM) industry is poor I I active equity mutual funds in aggregate: α̂ :< 0 with t ≈ −2 Nonetheless, active management remains popular: I e.g., 87% of mutual funds assets are actively managed The “Active Management Puzzle”? I Track record of the active management (AM) industry is poor I I Nonetheless, active management remains popular: I I active equity mutual funds in aggregate: α̂ :< 0 with t ≈ −2 e.g., 87% of mutual funds assets are actively managed Puzzle? The “Active Management Puzzle”? I Track record of the active management (AM) industry is poor I I Nonetheless, active management remains popular: I I active equity mutual funds in aggregate: α̂ :< 0 with t ≈ −2 e.g., 87% of mutual funds assets are actively managed Puzzle? not necessarily The “Active Management Puzzle”? I Track record of the active management (AM) industry is poor I I Nonetheless, active management remains popular: I I I active equity mutual funds in aggregate: α̂ :< 0 with t ≈ −2 e.g., 87% of mutual funds assets are actively managed Puzzle? not necessarily Decreasing returns to scale in the active management industry I I I I industry’s α depends on industry’s size: α becomes more elusive as more money chases it past underperformance ⇒ industry should shrink, but uncertainty about decreasing returns ⇒ large confidence interval for the size we should expect The “Active Management Puzzle”? I Track record of the active management (AM) industry is poor I I Nonetheless, active management remains popular: I I I e.g., 87% of mutual funds assets are actively managed Puzzle? not necessarily Decreasing returns to scale in the active management industry I I I I I active equity mutual funds in aggregate: α̂ :< 0 with t ≈ −2 industry’s α depends on industry’s size: α becomes more elusive as more money chases it past underperformance ⇒ industry should shrink, but uncertainty about decreasing returns ⇒ large confidence interval for the size we should expect In contrast, industry’s size would seem puzzling if it were known that returns to scale are constant What We Do I Develop an equilibrium model of active management (AM) with I I competing utility-maximizing investors competing fee-maximizing fund managers I Solve for equilibrium size, alpha, and fees in AM industry I Relate size of AM industry to past performance I Analyze learning about returns to scale What We Find I I AM industry can be large even if the track record is poor Investors’ learning about returns to scale is endogenous I I what they invest depends on what they’ve learned what they learn depends on what they invest I Investors never learn the degree of returns to scale exactly I Industry size can be suboptimal for a long time Other features of the model I I I I industry size crucially depends on the degree of competition α>0 “investment externality” Model I I Two types of agents: I M managers of active funds (have skill but no capital) I N investors in active funds (have capital but no skill) Benchmark-adjusted return to investors from fund i = 1, . . . , M: ri = αi + ui ui = x + i σx > 0 ⇒ cannot fully diversify risk by buying many funds Model: Expected Profits I Benchmark-adjusted expected total profit to fund i’s manager and investors: S πi = s i a − b W si . . . size of manager i’s fund PM S = i=1 si . . . aggregate size of the AM industry W . . . total investable wealth of the N investors I Manager i charges a proportional fee fi ⇒ investors expect benchmark-adjusted rate of return αi = a − b I S − fi W Decreasing returns to aggregate scale: b > 0 Expected Return a ⎛S ⎞ a−b ⎜ ⎟ ⎝W ⎠ α+ f α 0 S W S W Active Allocation Figure 1. Decreasing returns to scale in the active management industry. Model: Optimization I Each manager i chooses fi to maximize fee revenue: max fi si fi I Investors know fi ’s before making investment decisions I Each investor j chooses weights δj on the M funds to maximize o n γ max δj0 E(r |D) − δj0 Var(r |D)δj δj 2 I I I All investors have same risk aversion γ > 0, same wealth, and same information set D Unrestricted allocations to benchmarks and T-bill No short sales of funds (δj ≥ 0) Equilibrium with Known a and b I We solve for a symmetric Nash equilibrium I I First for investors’ allocations, as a function of fees, then for managers’ fees In equilibrium, fees and α’s are equal across funds (fi = f , αi = α): aγσ2 2γσ2 + (M − 1)p Mb γσ2 1− α = a 1− 2γσ2 + (M − 1)p γσ2 + Mp γσ2 S Ma = 1− , W γσ2 + Mp 2γσ2 + (M − 1)p f = where p= N +1 b + γσx2 N Equilibrium Fee I M ↑ ⇒ f ↓, due to competition among managers I I I Note: f is the discretionary component of the total fee I I For M = 1, we have f = a/2 For M → ∞, we have f → 0 f = fee the manager sets while considering its effect on fund size (any competitive proportional fee is part of a) Also, f ↑ when a ↑, b ↓, σ ↑, σx ↓, and N ↑ Equilibrium Alpha I In general, the equilibrium alpha is positive, α>0 because investors 1. demand compensation for risk (σx and possibly also σ ) 2. internalize some of the “investment externality” Equilibrium Alpha & Risk I Investors demand compensation for two kinds of risk: σ : diversifiable if M → ∞ σx : non-diversifiable even if M → ∞ I When M → ∞, diversifiable risk σ drops out: (1/N)b + γσx2 α=a [(N + 1)/N]b + γσx2 When N → ∞ as well, α=a γσx2 b + γσx2 Equilibrium Alpha & Number of Investors (N) I “Investment externality”: I I new investors impose a negative externality on existing investors by diluting their returns When N is finite, investors internalize some of the reduction in profits resulting from their own investment ⇒ α > 0 even if there is no risk I When M → ∞ and σx → 0, α= I Note: α ↓ when N ↑ a N +1 Equilibrium Alpha & Number of Managers (M) I The effect of M on α is ambiguous; two opposing effects: I I M ↓ ⇒ α ↓ because fees ↑ M ↓ ⇒ α ↑ because investors demand compensation for σ Equilibrium Size of the AM Industry I When N → ∞, we obtain a familiar mean-variance result: S E (rA |D) = W γVar(rA |D) where rA is the aggregate benchmark-adjusted return I When N → ∞ and M → ∞, S α a = = W b + γσx2 γσx2 I When N → ∞ and M = 1, S α = 2 W γ(σx + σ2 ) Equilibrium Size of the AM Industry (cont’d) I S Let S ∗ = size maximizing expected total profit, S a − b W a S∗ = W 2b I The equilibrium size S ≤ S̄ = 2S ∗ Expected Return a ⎛S ⎞ a−b ⎜ ⎟ ⎝W ⎠ α+ f α 0 S* W S W S W Active Allocation Equilibrium Size of the AM Industry (cont’d) I S Let S ∗ = size maximizing expected total profit, S a − b W S∗ a = W 2b I I The equilibrium size S ≤ S̄ = 2S ∗ When M = 1, there is underinvestment, S ≤ S ∗ I Manager-monopolist charges high fee I S = S ∗ only if N → ∞ and σx2 + σ2 = 0 Equilibrium Size of the AM Industry (cont’d) I When M → ∞, S = S∗ 2b + γσx2 N+1 N b ⇒ underinvestment (S < S ∗ ) or overinvestment (S > S ∗ ) I When M → ∞ and σx2 → 0, there is overinvestment: S 2N = ∗ S N +1 I N → ∞ ⇒ S → S̄ = 2S ∗ Unknown a and b I Now suppose a and b are unknown ã a |D = E b b̃ 2 σa σab a |D = Var σab σb2 b I For simplicity, let M → ∞ and N → ∞ I I Then f → 0 and α = a − b(S/W ) Solve for a symmetric Nash equilibrium among investors Unknown a and b (cont’d) I In equilibrium, S/W is the (unique) real positive solution to 3 i S 2 S S h 2 2 2γσab − γσb2 0 = ã − b̃ + γ(σa + σx ) + W W W as long as ã > 0. If ã ≤ 0, then S/W = 0. I In this setting, E(rA |D) = ã − b̃ Var(rA |D) = ⇒ S W = σa2 + S W σx2 −2 E(rA |D) γVar(rA |D) S W σab + S W 2 σb2 Prior Beliefs for a and b I One prior for a, two priors for b I I I Prior 1: b = 0, known (constant returns to scale) Prior 2: b ≥ 0, unknown (decreasing returns to scale) Assume I I I I S/W = 0.9 is optimal under Prior 2 Prior mean of α = 10% per year at S/W = 0.9 Risk aversion of γ = 2 Volatility of aggregate active return σx = 2% per year I Close to empirical estimates for active equity mutual funds Prior for a Priors for b 7 7 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 −0.5 0 0.5 b≥0 b=0 0 1 0 0.2 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile −0.2 −0.4 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0.8 1 Priors for α when b ≥ 0 0.6 Percentiles of α Percentiles of α Priors for α when b=0 0.4 0.2 0 −0.2 −0.4 0.6 0.8 1 0 0.2 0.4 S/W Figure 2. Prior distributions. 0.6 S/W Implied Prior Beliefs for α I Implied prior for α depends on S/W when b ≥ 0 α = a − b(S/W ) I Prior 2 is more pessimistic about α than Prior 1 I I α is smaller under Prior 2 for any S/W > 0 Nonetheless, we’ll see that Prior 2 investors invest more in AM than Prior 1 investors after a negative track record Updated Beliefs I 300,000 samples of simulated AM returns and allocations I I For each sample, randomly draw a and b from their priors In each year t, beginning with t = 1, we perform three steps: 1. Solve for equilibrium allocation to AM I Restrict (S/W )t between 0 and 1 2. Construct AM return I rA,t = a − b(S/W )t + xt , where xt ∼ N(0, σx2 ) 3. Update beliefs about a and b I Regress rA on S/W and constant ⇒ intercept a, slope −b . . . then back to step 1 b ≥ 0; Posterior std dev of a b = 0; Posterior std dev of a Std(a) 0.05 0 Std(b) 0.1 0 10 20 30 40 0 50 20 30 40 Year 0.15 0.1 0.1 50 0.05 0 10 20 30 40 0 50 0 10 20 30 Year b = 0; Posterior std dev of α b ≥ 0; Posterior std dev of α Std(α) 0.05 10 20 30 Year 40 50 0.05 0 50 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile 0.1 0 40 Year 0.1 0 10 b ≥ 0; Posterior std dev of b 0.15 0 0 b = 0; Posterior std dev of b 0.05 Std(α) 0.05 Year Std(b) Std(a) 0.1 0 10 20 30 Year Figure 3. Posterior standard deviations. 40 50 Perceived a minus true a Perceived b minus true b 0.2 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.1 0.05 0 0 −0.1 −0.05 −0.1 −0.2 −0.15 −0.2 0 10 20 30 40 50 −0.3 0 10 20 Year 30 40 50 Year Perceived α minus true α Equilibrium S/W minus true S/W 0.08 0.3 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.2 0.1 0 0 −0.02 −0.04 −0.1 −0.06 −0.08 0 10 20 30 Year 40 50 −0.2 0 10 20 30 Year Figure 4. Deviations from true values. 40 50 Learning About Returns to Scale I “Endogeneity”: learn ⇒ invest ⇒ learn ⇒ invest ⇒ . . . I Learning about the intercept and slope from rt = a − b(S/W )t + t I (S/W )t+1 depends on beliefs about a and b at time t I If (S/W )t stops changing, learning about a and b stops ⇒ Never learn a and b I (S/W )t converges to optimal level quickly when b is high, but it can stay suboptimal for a long time when b is low Learning When b ≥ 0 I I I Investors learn differently under Priors 1 and 2 because (S/W )t affects learning when b ≥ 0 but not when b = 0 Representative examples of learning paths: Figure 5 I Three values of b: “low”, “median”, “high” (5th, 50th, 95th percentiles of the prior distribution) I Given b, pick a such that the “true” S/W = 0.5 I Use (a, b) to generate random samples of returns Results: I When b is high, investors find the optimal S/W quickly I When b is low, investors can get stuck at “wrong” S/W for a long time Return Low b, example 1 Median b, example 1 0.1 0.1 0 0 0 −0.1 −0.1 0 0.5 1 −0.1 0 Return Low b, example 2 0.1 1 −0.2 0 0 0 0.5 1 High b, example 2 0.1 0 −0.1 0 0.5 1 −0.1 0 Low b, example 3 Return 0.5 Median b, example 2 0.1 −0.1 0.5 1 −0.2 0 Median b, example 3 0.1 0.1 0 0 0.5 1 High b, example 3 0.1 0 −0.1 −0.1 0 0.5 1 −0.1 0 Low b, example 4 Return High b, example 1 0.1 0.5 1 −0.2 0 Median b, example 4 0.1 0.1 0 0 0.5 1 High b, example 4 0.1 0 −0.1 −0.1 0 0.5 S/W 1 −0.1 0 0.5 S/W 1 −0.2 0 Figure 5. Examples of learning paths. 0.5 S/W 1 Role of Historical Performance I Plot the posterior of the equilibrium S/W conditional on t(α̂) I I I How much is invested in AM when α̂ is significantly negative? Prior 1 (b = 0) investors invest nothing I I √ Note: t(α̂) = α̂ T /σx t(α̂) is a sufficient statistic for S/W Prior 2 (b ≥ 0) investors can invest a lot I I despite Prior 2 being more pessimistic about α than Prior 1 t(α̂) is NOT a sufficient statistic for S/W S/W after 50 years when b=0 1 0.8 S/W 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 Sample t−statistic 1 2 3 4 Distribution of equilibrium S/W after 50 years when b ≥ 0 1 Percentiles of S/W 0.8 0.6 0.4 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile 0.2 0 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 Sample t−statistic 1 2 3 4 Figure 6. Posterior distribution of the equilibrium allocation to active management conditional on the sample t-statistic. Prior for a Priors for b 7 7 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 −1 −0.5 0 0.5 1 b≥0 b=0 0 1.5 0 0.2 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0 −0.2 −0.4 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile −0.6 −0.8 −1 0 0.2 0.4 0.8 1 0.8 1 0 −0.2 −0.4 −0.6 −0.8 −1 0.6 S/W 0.6 Priors for α when b ≥ 0 0.6 Percentiles of α Percentiles of α Priors for α when b=0 0.4 0.8 1 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 S/W Figure 7. Alternative prior distribution. S/W after 50 years when b=0 1 0.8 S/W 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 Sample t−statistic 1 2 3 4 Distribution of equilibrium S/W after 50 years when b ≥ 0 1 Percentiles of S/W 0.8 0.6 0.4 95th pctile 75th pctile 50th pctile 25th pctile 5th pctile 0.2 0 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 Sample t−statistic 1 2 3 4 Figure 8. Equilibrium allocation to active management under the alternative prior. Differences from Berk and Green (2004) I Focus I I I Decreasing returns to scale I I I BG: At individual fund level We: At aggregate industry level Parameter uncertainty I I I BG: Capital flows across funds We: Size of the AM industry BG: a unknown, b known We: a and b both unknown Fund managers setting fees I I BG: Monopoly We: Competition Differences from Berk and Green (2004) (cont’d) I Equilibrium alpha I I I BG: α = 0; no explicit investor optimization We: α > 0; equilibrium outcome for optimizing investors Our model comes closest to BG when . . . I I I M = 1 (a single fund manager) ⇒ same fee setting N → ∞ (many investors) ⇒ no investment externality σ = σx = 0 (no risk) ⇒ no compensation for risk Equilibrium then features α = 0, S = S ∗ , and f = a/2, as in BG Conclusions I Size of AM industry can be large even if the track record is poor I I I I I Due to decreasing returns to scale Learning about returns to scale is “endogenous” and slow Never learn the degree of returns to scale exactly Industry size can be suboptimal for a long time Interesting features of the model 1. Industry size crucially depends on the degree of competition 2. α > 0 3. “Investment externality”