Optimal Asset Allocation and Risk Shifting in Money Management Suleyman Basak (LBS), Anna Pavlova (LBS), and Alex Shapiro (Azimuth Trust) (1) Motivation and Objective (2) Model (3) Empirical Analysis (4) Costs of Active Management to Investors 1. Motivation and Objective Page 1 1. Motivation and Objective • Mutual fund managers’ compensation is linked to the value of assets under management • Implicit incentives due to fund flows to performance relationship • The flow-performance relationship is – positive – exhibits convexities • Question: How does a fund manager respond to these incentives? 1. Motivation and Objective Fund Flow - Performance Relationship (Chevalier and Ellison (1997)) Page 2 1. Motivation and Objective Page 3 Summary of Main Testable Implications • Taking risk = increasing volatility of portfolio • Gambling entails either an increase or a decrease in portfolio volatility – a sufficiently risk averse manager decreases volatility – manager manipulates systematic risk rather than idiosyncratic – gambling intensifies towards year-end • Incentives to gamble are state-dependent. For example, the manager’s risk-taking incentives are year-end flow fH fL 0 6 Highest Y relative return Lowest 1. Motivation and Objective Page 4 Related Literature • Risk-taking of fund managers in response to fund flows: Chevalier and Ellison (1997) • Managerial incentives and portfolio choice: Brennan (1993), Carpenter (2000), Cuoco and Kaniel (2000), Berk and Green (2005), Hugonnier and Kaniel (2002), Gomez and Zapatero (2003), Ross (2003) • Empirical literature on risk-taking by mutual fund managers: Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996), Busse (2001), Reed and Wu (2005) 2. Model Page 5 2. Model • Finite horizon, [0, T ], Black-Scholes economy • Assets: – Money market account with rate r – Stock follows dSt = µSt dt + σSt dwt • Fund manager: – evaluated relative to the index Yt (fraction β in stock) – receives flows at T at rate fT – chooses a trading strategy θ and terminal portfolio value W T (WT fT )1−γ max E[u(WT fT )] = E θ, WT 1−γ subject to dWt = [r + θt (µ − r)] Wt dt + θt σWt dwt 2. Model Page 6 Flow-Performance Relationship (Simplest) fT fH fL 0 η relative return How does one measure risk-taking incentives? • Conventional view: – sensitivity of the payoff’s value to volatility (vega): Y ∂V (σtW ; RW t −Rt ) ∂σtW • This paper: W – optimal volatility σ̂t = θ̂t σ . That is, Y ∂V (σtW ; RW t −Rt ) ∂σtW =0 ⇒ σ̂tW . 2. Model Page 7 Manager’s Optimal Risk Exposure θ̂t θ̂t 1 4 θY 0.8 3 θN 0.6 2 1 0.4 0.2 θY -0.3 -1.5 -1 -0.5 η (a) Economies with θ θN 0.5 N Rt − Rt W > θY θN : risk exposure in Merton’s problem, Y -0.2 -0.1 0.1 -0.2 η 0.2 0.3 N < θY (b) Economies with θ θY : risk exposure of the index RtW − RtY 2. Model Page 8 An Alternative Flow-Performance Relationship (Collar-Type) fT fH fL 0 ηL ηH relative return Can also be reinterpreted as an 80/120 annual bonus plan. 2. Model Page 9 Manager’s Optimal Risk Exposure (Collar-Type) θ̂t θ̂t 1 4 θY 0.8 3 θN 0.6 2 1 0.4 0.2 θY -0.3 -1.5 -1 -0.5 ηH 0.5 N > θY (a) Economies with θ θN Rt − Rt W θN : risk exposure in Merton’s problem, Y -0.2 -0.1 0.1 -0.2 ηH 0.2 0.3 N < θY (b) Economies with θ θY : risk exposure of the index RtW − RtY 2. Model Page 10 Further Alternative Flow-Performance Specifications • Linear-convex (Sirri and Tufano (1998)) year-end flow fL 0 relative return • Linear-linear (asymmetric fee structure) year-end flow fL 0 relative return 2. Model Page 11 Manager’s Optimal Risk Exposure: Dynamics 9 T -tmed T -thigh -0.5 θY 7 0.8 5 0.6 θ N 3θ 1 -1 θ̂t 1 T -tlow -1.5 θ̂t 0.4 N T -tmed θY η (a) Economies with θ 3 0.2 -0.4 -0.3 -0.2 -0.1 0.5 N T -thigh Rt − Rt > θY W Y -0.2 T -tlow 0.1 η (b) Economies with θ • Manager engages in risk shifting well before the year-end • Risk shifting more pronounced as the year-end approaches 0.2 N 0.3 RtW − RtY < θY 2. Model Page 12 Multiple Stocks Stock 1 Stock 2 θ̂1t θ̂2t 3 2 3 θ1N 2 1 Y Y θ1 -1 1 θ2 η -0.5 θ2N 0.5 RtW − RtY N (a) Economies with θ1 -1 η -0.5 0.5 RtW − RtY > θ1Y and θ2N > θ2Y Stock 1 Stock 2 θ̂1t θ̂2t θ1Y 0.6 4 0.4 3 N θ1 θ2N2 0.2 -1 η -0.5 -0. 2 0.5 1 Y Rt − Rt W Y θ2 -1 N (b) Economies with θ1 -0.5 η 0.5 < θ1Y and θ2N > θ2Y RtW − RtY 2. Model Page 13 Idiosyncratic versus Systematic Risk Economic setup: dS1t = µ1 S1t dt + σ11 S1t dw1t + σ12 S1t dw2t dS2t = µ2 S2t dt + σ21 S2t dw1t + σ22 S2t dw2t 1 0 1 0 0 µ1 σ A , Y = S1 A , σ = @ 11 µ=@ 0 σ22 r θ̂1t θ̂2t 4 0.6 3 0.4 θ1N 2 0.2 θY 1 θ2N 1 -1 -0.5 -1 η 0.5 RtW − RtY -0.5 η -0. 2 0.5 RtW − RtY 3. Empirical Analysis Page 14 3. Empirical Analysis Existing Work • Brown, Harlow, and Starks (1996) – find that underperforming managers increase volatility towards the year-end • Busse (2001) – shows that the above test fails on daily data • Chevalier and Ellison (1997) – look at σ(R W − RY ) towards the year-end; find an increase – use monthly data • Reed and Wu (2005) – test the results of this paper on daily data – distinguish between tournaments- vs. benchmarking-induced incentives 3. Empirical Analysis Page 15 Data • Daily mutual fund returns from Will Goetzmann and Geert Rouwenhorst (International Center for Finance at Yale SOM). • Data range: 1970 through 1998 (comparable with Chevalier-Ellison, Sirri-Tufano). • Merged with CRSP to find out mutual funds objective codes – left only actively managed US equity mutual funds in the aggressive growth, growth and income, and long-term growth categories. • Used the S&P 500 index as the benchmark. 3. Empirical Analysis Page 16 Tracking error and standard deviation tests Hypothesis 1: Tracking error variance is higher for underperforming managers. W LHS: σm (Ri, t OVERi,m × 103 − RtY ) W LHS: σm (Ri, t ) Point Estimate t-Statistic Point Estimate t-Statistic -0.1819 -4.73 0.1058 2.38 Fund-year FE Yes Yes R2 0.39 0.36 N 40721 40721 W Y σm (Ri, t − Rt ) – standard deviation of tracking error for month m; Y is S&P 500 W σm (Ri, t ) – standard deviation of fund returns for month m OVERi,m – relative performance indicator prior to month m 3. Empirical Analysis Page 17 Beta tests Hypothesis 2: Sufficiently risk-averse managers decrease their portfolio betas when underperforming the market. W F Y F Ri, t − Rt = a + (bF und−Y ear 1F Y + bM onth 1M + bU UNDERi,w )(Rt − Rt ) + εi, t Dependent Variable: BetaT below 1 W F Ri, t − Rt BetaT −1 below 1 (1) (2) (3) (4) -0.017 -0.020 -0.018 -0.021 (-6.61) (-7.72) (-6.99) (-8.22) Month fixed effects No Yes No Yes Fund-year fixed effects Yes Yes Yes Yes R2 0.37 0.37 0.37 0.37 Number of observations 808642 UNDERi,w × (RtY − RtF ) 816783 3. Empirical Analysis Page 18 Robustness • Tried several alternative definitions of the OVER/UNDER indicator • Included lagged dependent variables to deal with autocorrelation • Clustered errors by month/day and fund objective code 4. Costs of Active Management to Investors Page 19 4. Costs of Active Management to Investors • Define a measure of gain/loss, λ̂, in units of investor’s initial wealth: V I ((1 + λ̂)W0 ) = V̂ (W0 ) – V I (·) is investor’s indirect utility under θ I – V̂ (·) is investor’s indirect utility under delegation • Decompose λ̂ into two components: 1 + λ̂ = (1 + λN )(1 + λY ) – λN : gain/loss due to explicit incentives, solves V I ((1 + λN )W0 ) = V̂ (W0 ; fT =1) – λY : gain/loss due to implicit incentives 4. Costs of Active Management to Investors Page 20 Costs of Active Management in Economies (a) (θ N > θY ) γ = 1, γI = 2, fL = 0.8, fH = 1.5, fL + fH = 2.3, β = 1, = 0.08, ηL + ηH = 0, µ = 0.06, r = 0.02, σ = 0.29, W0 = 1, T = 1. Fixed parameter values: ηL = −0.08, ηH Cost-benefit measures λY , λN λ̂ (%) Effects of Managerial risk γ aversion Implicit reward fH -fL for outperformance Risk exposure θY of the benchmark Flow threshold differential ηH -ηL 0.5 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 -8.13, -4.19 -5.12, -0.47 -3.31, 0.00 -2.56, -0.05 -2.15, -0.11 -11.98 -5.61 -3.31 -2.61 -2.27 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1.1 -3.33, -0.47 -4.29, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -6.01, -0.47 -6.88, -0.47 -3.79 -4.74 -5.61 -6.46 -7.32 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.25 1.50 -5.43, -0.47 -4.63, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -6.69, -0.47 -8.45, -0.47 -5.88 -5.08 -5.61 -7.13 -8.88 0.08 0.12 0.16 0.20 0.24 -4.33, -0.47 -4.70, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -5.67, -0.47 -6.21, -0.47 -4.78 -5.15 -5.61 -6.12 -6.65 4. Costs of Active Management to Investors Page 21 Costs of Active Management in Economies (b) (θ N < θY ) γ = 1, γI = 2, fL = 0.8, fH = 1.5, fL + fH = 2.3, β = 1, = 0.08, ηL + ηH = 0, µ = 0.06, r = 0.02, σ = 0.29, W0 = 1, T = 1. Fixed parameter values: ηL = −0.08, ηH Cost-benefit measures λY , λN λ̂ (%) Effects of Managerial risk γ aversion Implicit reward fH -fL for outperformance Risk exposure θY of the benchmark Flow threshold differential ηH -ηL 0.5 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 -8.13, -4.19 -5.12, -0.47 -3.31, 0.00 -2.56, -0.05 -2.15, -0.11 -11.98 -5.61 -3.31 -2.61 -2.27 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1.1 -3.33, -0.47 -4.29, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -6.01, -0.47 -6.88, -0.47 -3.79 -4.74 -5.61 -6.46 -7.32 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.25 1.50 -5.43, -0.47 -4.63, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -6.69, -0.47 -8.45, -0.47 -5.88 -5.08 -5.61 -7.13 -8.88 0.08 0.12 0.16 0.20 0.24 -4.33, -0.47 -4.70, -0.47 -5.12, -0.47 -5.67, -0.47 -6.21, -0.47 -4.78 -5.15 -5.61 -6.12 -6.65 5. Conclusion Page 22 5. Conclusion • Characterized the manager’s optimal behavior in response to incentives induced by the fund flow-performance relationship. • Identified circumstances in which the manager would like to gamble. • Gambling may be associated with a decrease in the fund’s volatility. • Adverse incentives of the manager result in an economically significant cost to the investor.