VOL. 20, NO. 2 SUMMER 2007 BENEFITS LAW JOURNAL Real Health Care Reform Starts with the Tax Deduction T he goal of health care reform is a cost-effective system in which everyone can get the medical care they need. Many things need fixing, including an outdated approach to information and record management; a medical malpractice environment that induces overly defensive medicine; an underdeveloped market for nongroup insurance coverage; a Medicaid/welfare system focused on emergency care; the high cost of dying; and a payment bureaucracy that purportedly controls costs through a labyrinth of billing codes but creates an incentive for providers to perform added tests and procedures rather than promoting good health. Yet, serious as these problems are, reform should begin with the Tax Code. Think about it: Health care is the only basic necessity that can be purchased with pre-tax dollars. Employer-paid health insurance is income, and FICA tax-free—ditto for employees’ share of premiums—while flexible spending accounts also allow employees to pay unreimbursed costs with pre-tax dollars. Employer-provided retiree health coverage similarly avoids the tax man. In contrast, individuals who must purchase coverage on their own or who pay for their medical care out-of-pocket must use after-tax dollars to foot the bills. (Special rules apply to the self employed and HSAs.) This approach not only is inherently unfair, it also serves as an incentive for people to buy too much insurance coverage and to think of health care as an almost no-cost entitlement. The federal tax subsidy for employer-provided health care is over $208 billion a year. With graduated tax rates, this subsidy is tilted towards the high earners who can most easily afford to buy their own coverage. A top earner living in a high-tax state gets the government to pay for roughly half of his or her health care, while the income tax savings to someone on the bottom of the pay scale with employerprovided health coverage is much lower. Lower-income employees From the Editor do benefit more heavily from the FICA tax savings (because FICA is a flat tax that only applies to earnings up to the wage base). But this savings is largely illusory since, assuming no changes to Social Security, these employees will see a roughly equivalent reduction in the value of their future Social Security benefits. Besides favoring the highly paid, the tax rules also subsidize workers who receive health care through their employers. This encourages employers to offer health benefits, but penalizes workers whose employers do not offer health care, as well as the unemployed and those who prefer to purchase coverage outside of their company plan. Even worse, the subsidy encourages employees to buy extra coverage: It is actually cheaper for an employee in the 40 percent federal and state bracket to pay $100 in additional premiums for a more generous plan that will save $70 in out-of-pocket expenses. Just about any health care economist will tell you that the Code’s promotion of such over-insurance leads to higher costs for all of us. Perhaps worse than the basic inequity of favoring high-wage earners over lower earners and favoring employer-provided group coverage over individual insurance is that the Code hides the actual cost of insurance from employees. Decades ago, when many employers offered no-cost health benefits, workers did not place much value in the coverage—perhaps somewhere between free office coffee and an extra paid holiday. Now that virtually every employer health plan is contributory, employees tend to view the cost of health benefits as their share of the premiums, not the total employer/employee cost. Not appreciating the real cost of their health benefits makes workers much more resistant to any changes to reduce costs. The national firestorm that arose over attempts to cut unnecessary care through managed care programs is Exhibit A for the disconnect between employees and the actual cost of health care. So, what to do? The obvious and most simple answer is to treat the entire value of employer-provided health care as W-2 income, while eliminating FSAs and requiring that employees pay their share of premiums with after-tax dollars. Unfortunately, while this prescription would eliminate the misdirected incentives built into the Tax Code, it is also unworkable. Consider the prospect of a worker earning $30,000 suddenly having to pay taxes on an extra $10,000 in income for employer-paid family coverage. Since the worker certainly could not afford the added income and FICA taxes, he or she would probably have to decline the free coverage. The Bush Administration and other officials favor an alternative approach to address the problems with the Tax Code without clobbering the lower-paid and middle class. They seek to use the Code to subsidize the purchase of insurance, without the bias towards employer-sponsored coverage and the incentive to over insure. As BENEFITS LAW JOURNAL 2 VOL. 20, NO. 2, SUMMER 2007 From the Editor proposed, the cost of employer-paid coverage would be taxable for income and FICA purposes and Section 125 FSAs and pre-tax premium payments would be eliminated. Additionally, anyone with a minimum level of health insurance would be entitled to an above-theline standard tax deduction of $15,000 for family coverage and $7,000 for single coverage, regardless of the actual cost of their insurance. While this approach might solve the problem of misguided tax incentives, it misses the mark. The new standard tax deduction is regressive because it would provide the largest tax subsidy for those in the highest brackets. This defect would actually be easy to fix by simply turning the deduction into a tax credit of equivalent value. That would level the playing field, since every taxpayer with health insurance would receive the same government subsidy. (Both the tax deduction or credit approach would increase employer costs since the value of health premiums would be taxed for FICA purposes. Employers also may need a credit to stay whole.) Some wonks criticize any attempt to remove the Tax Code’s tilt towards employer-provided coverage, fearing that many employers would drop their health benefits and force employees to purchase individual coverage on the open market, which can be very expensive for those with health problems or who are just older. There also is a risk that the altered tax incentives would encourage younger and healthier employees to opt-out of their employer plans and purchase cheaper individual health insurance, making employers’ claims experience less favorable and driving up costs. These are legitimate concerns. But these problems with the nongroup health insurance market will not be exacerbated by making the tax deduction rules fair and market neutral. If anything, the Tax Code’s preferential treatment of group insurance has retarded the development of the market for individual coverage. Amending the Tax Code will not fix health care. But, taking taxes out of the equation, while still providing a uniform subsidy for purchasing health insurance, is the critical first step on the way to genuine health care reform. David E. Morse Partner K&L Gates LLP New York, NY Reprinted from Benefits Law Journal Summer 2007, Volume 20, Number 2, pages 2-4, with permission from Aspen Publishers, Inc., Wolters Kluwer Law & Business, New York, NY, 1-800-638-8437, www.aspenpublishers.com