Introduction Macroeconomics IV Ricardo J. Caballero MIT Spring 2011 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 1 / 43 References 1 2 Caballero, R.J.,“Macroeconomics after the Crisis: Time to deal with the Pretense-of-Knowledge Syndrome." JEP Fall 2010, 85-102. Caballero, R.J. "A Caricature (Model) of the World Economy," MIT WP 10-17, November 2010. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 2 / 43 The Pretense of Knowledge “Of course, compared with the precise predictions we have learnt to expect in the physical sciences, this sort of mere pattern predictions is a second best with which one does not like to have to be content. Yet the danger of which I want to warn is precisely the belief that in order to have a claim to be accepted as scientific it is necessary to achieve more. This way lies charlatanism and worse. To act on the belief that we possess the knowledge and the power which enable us to shape the process of society entirely to our liking, knowledge which in fact we do not possess, is likely to make us do much harm.” Hayek (1974) R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 3 / 43 The Pretense of Knowledge The subject of macroeconmics is inmensily complex (both for researchers and economic agents!) The core of the field (DSGE) has become so mesmerized with its own internal logic that it has began to confuse the precision it has achieved about its own world with that it has about the real one The periphery (intersection of macroeconomics and corporate finance) has been chasing many of the issues that played a central role during the current crisis... We have a tension between a type of answer we aspire to but that has limited connection with reality (the core), and more sensible but incomplete answers (the periphery). Solution? Do NOT abandon models... but understand their proper place... and incorporate complexity (in the sense of extremely complicated) into the analysis and its limitations R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 4 / 43 Introduction The aftermath of a huge global financial crisis has left us with a very confusing economic environment I want to discuss one organizing framework that has helped me to navigate through some of this complexity I will do this by presenting an extremely stylized model of the workings of a global economy, which I will integrate with a discussion of current events and facts The basic perspective is one of the macroeconomics of asset shortages Much of what I will say has a formal "micro-founded" model in the background but I do not make any major effort to draw those connections here. That’s what the rest of the course is for R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 5 / 43 Introduction The key driving factor in this perspective is economic agents’continuous struggle to find assets to park financial resources This struggle comes with euphoria and disappointments, as many of the "parking lots" are built too quickly or are not of the desired size There are also global asymmetries, as some countries are endowed with more empty “land” and growth potential than others I use this caricature of the world economy to describe several of the main driving forces behind recent global macroeconomic events For now, I will focus on financial markets and fiows, and downplay the important impact of these on the real side. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 6 / 43 A "Model" Time is continuous. At each instant: Ct = θWt . (1) There are two assets, A and B, in which to store wealth. There are β of the former and 1 − β of the latter Agents want to hold a share α of their wealth in asset A and, (1 − α) in asset B Differences between assets stem from agent’s perception or tastes. This is just a "catch all" reduced form for the many factors that determine portfolio decisions in reality, that are not purely return-driven Asset A is in relatively short supply: α > β R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 7 / 43 A "Model" Aggregate financial wealth is: Wt = ptA xtA + ptB xtB . (2) In equilibrium: xA x R.J. Caballero (MIT) B = β = 1−β Introduction Spring 2011 8 / 43 A "Model" Aggregate output is exogenous and grows at rate g : Yt = Y0 e gt . (3) A fraction δ of this output is pledgable (i.e., its present value can be used to produce assets) and the rest is not Equilibrium in goods and financial markets require that: Ct ( ptA ptB R.J. Caballero (MIT) β 1−β = θWt ) = Yt = Introduction α . 1−α Spring 2011 9 / 43 A "Model" Solving out endogenous variables, we have: ptA = ptB = α Yt , β θ 1 − α Yt . 1−β θ (4) The interest rates, r A and r B , that are consistent with these asset prices and the standard arbitrage condition are (from r i = (δY + ṗ )/p) β α rtA = g + δθ rtB = rtA + λt (5) And the scarcity premium of asset A over asset B is: λt = R.J. Caballero (MIT) δθ (α − β) > 0 α (1 − α ) Introduction Spring 2011 10 / 43 Discussion and apology The distinction between type A and type B assets captures the fact that there are assets that seem scarcer than others The reasons for these scarcities are complex and change over time. During the years between the Nasdaq crash and the recent financial crisis, type A assets were almost any AAA bond or tranche When the crisis hit, suddenly only AAA-bonds issued by sovereigns, especially the U.S., made the type A cut. On the other extreme, at times, commodities, real estate, or the NASDAQ may become type A assets (All the examples in this section have some concept of risk in the background while the model has none! I apologize but move on...) R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 11 / 43 Disgression: Solow’s insight... R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 12 / 43 Global Force 1: Gradual decline in delta*theta There has been a sharp rise in the relative income of the largest EM economies and commodity producers, coupled with their enormous desire to save for a “rainy day.” These are economies that have limited capacity to produce financial instruments (low δ) and most of them have a higher propensity to save than developed economies (low θ). This pattern amounts to a decline in the global (income-weighted) δ and θ. Recall that: = g + δθ rtB = rtA + λt δθ = (α − β) > 0 α (1 − α ) λt R.J. Caballero (MIT) β α rtA Introduction (6) (7) Spring 2011 13 / 43 Global Force 1: Gradual decline in delta*theta Three effects (present before the crisis): Very low equilibrium interest rates, rtA and rtB Risk compression (λ drops), as there is a proportional shift in demand for all assets which dilutes the relative scarcity of assets type A. Rise in asset prices ("bubbles," etc.), ptA and ptB R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 14 / 43 Global Force 1: Gradual decline in delta*theta Asian crisis Subprime crisis 5 Percent 4 US long real 3 2 1 World-short real 0 -1 08 20 06 20 04 20 02 20 00 20 98 19 96 19 94 19 92 19 19 90 -2 Worlds and US real interest rates, 1990:1 - 2008:2. Data source: IFS, WDI, OECD & SPF. Authors' calculations. The world short real rate is a GDP-weighted of the 4-quarter average ex-post 3-months treasury bill real rates for the G-7 countries. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. Spring 2011 15 / 43 Global Force 2: Gradual rise in alpha Not only has the net demand for assets risen over time but also this rise has been concentrated on AAA-assets (the type A assets of this episode) In the model, the direct effect of a rise in α is an increase in the price of assets type A and a decrease in the price of assets of type B, and the opposite behavior for rates The combination of forces 1 and 2 through this period led to a generalized rise in the cap value of both fixed (type A in that period) and variable income (type B in that period), but with a much stronger rise in the former R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 16 / 43 Global Force 2: Gradual rise in alpha U.S. Financial Assets Percentage of GDP 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan- Jan52 57 62 67 72 77 82 87 92 97 02 07 Debt R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Equity Spring 2011 17 / 43 Global Force 3: Temporary (artificial?) rise in beta Forces 1 and 2 led to attempts to "arbitrage" λ by transforming B into A assets (and partly by transforming non-pledgeable assets into pledgable ones). During much of the 1990s artificial assets were created in emerging markets until the sequence of crises starting with the Asian crisis destroyed a large share of these assets. The pressure then moved to U.S. assets, and the Nasdaq in particular, which also culminated with a crash; to then be followed by the financial system’s rapid rise in the production of AAA tranches from the securitization of lower quality loans. This also came to an abrupt end during the so called "subprime" crisis R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 18 / 43 Global Force 3: Temporary (artificial?) rise in beta Assets Liabilities AAA tranche AA tranche A tranche BBB tranche BBB- tranche Toxic waste R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 19 / 43 Global Force 3: Temporary (artificial?) rise in beta A shift toward CDOs 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009* CDO issuance as a share of corporate debt issuance R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 20 / 43 Global Force 4: Spikes in alpha over beta From a systemic point of view, this new-found source of triple-A assets was much riskier than the traditional single-name highly rated bond The triggering event was the crash in the real estate “bubble” and the rise in subprime mortgage defaults that followed it. Confidence vanished and perceived complexity spiked. Eventually, even super-senior tranches were no longer perceived as invulnerable (A assets turned into B assets). The underlying structural deficit of safe assets worsened as the newly found source of triple-A assets from the securitization industry dried up (β declined), and the spike in perceived uncertainty further increased demand for these assets (α increased). During this episode safe interest rates plummeted to record low levels and all forms of risk-premia (λs) skyrocketed R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 21 / 43 Global Force 4: Spikes in alpha over beta 3-Month Treasury Bill rate 1 5.00 Lehman bankrupcy Money funds break the buck AIG bailout WaMu seized TARP US buys bank equity Fed rescues money market funds 4.00 3.00 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 Countrywide rescue 0.4 2.00 Monolines downgrade 0.3 0.2 1.00 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Oct-09 Sep-09 Jul-09 Aug-09 Jun-09 Apr-09 May-09 Mar-09 Jan-09 Feb-09 Oct-08 Dec-08 Nov-08 Sep-08 Jul-08 Introduction Aug-08 Jun-08 Apr-08 May-08 0.1 Mar-08 Jan-08 Feb-08 Dec-07 Oct-07 Nov-07 Sep-07 Jul-07 Aug-07 Jun-07 Apr-07 May-07 Jan-07 Feb-07 0.00 Mar-07 Bear Stearns collapse 0 Spring 2011 22 / 43 Jan-07 0 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Sep-09 Aug-09 Jul-09 Jun-09 May-09 Apr-09 Mar-09 Feb-09 Jan-09 Dec-08 Nov-08 Oct-08 Sep-08 Aug-08 Jul-08 Jun-08 May-08 Apr-08 Mar-08 Feb-08 Jan-08 Dec-07 Nov-07 Oct-07 Sep-07 Aug-07 Jul-07 Jun-07 May-07 Apr-07 Mar-07 Feb-07 basis points Global Force 4: Spikes in alpha over beta 450 TED Spread 400 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 Spring 2011 23 / 43 Global Force 4: Spikes in alpha over beta Initially, the fiight to quality was a boon for money market funds, which suddenly found themselves facing a herd of new clients. In order to capture a large share of this expansion in demand from these new clients, some money market funds began to invest in short-term commercial paper issued by the investment banks in distress (that is, they found their own temporary mechanism to transform B into A assets). This strategy backfired after Lehman’s collapse, when the Reserve Primary Fund “broke-the-buck” as a result of its losses associated with Lehman’s bankruptcy. Perceived complexity reached a new level as even the supposedly safest private funds were no longer immune to contagion. Widespread panic ensued and led to an even more extreme rise in α/β. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 24 / 43 Regions There are limits to how far we can go without referring to the heterogeneity, both ex-crisis and post-crisis, in the world economy Next I highlight some of these differences, pointing to their broad implications rather than focusing on the mechanics of global equilibrium R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 25 / 43 Force 5: Asymmetric delta*theta One of the key differences between emerging and developed economies is the institutional development supporting financial markets and contracts. That is, δ is higher in developed economies than in emerging markets The acute asset shortage in EMs is reinforced by the high propensity to save (low θ) of some EMs, in particular from Asia and some commodity producing economies As is apparent in the model, these forces lead to lower pledgable return relative to asset demand in the "South" than in the "North", and hence justify the seemingly paradoxical direction of net capital fiows from emerging markets to developed economies in recent years R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 26 / 43 Force 5: Asymmetric delta*theta Current Account 1.5 % of World GDP 1.1 0.7 0.3 -0.1 -0.5 -0.9 -1.3 -1.7 -2.1 USA EU Rest of World 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 27 / 43 Force 6: Asymmetric alpha over beta The relative weakness in financial development of emerging market economies is particularly severe in the production of type A assets Other things equal, this asymmetry in α/β means that r A is higher in developed economies while r B is higher in emerging markets Given net fiows, this mechanism helps to explain why the typical gross capital fiows pattern is one in which emerging markets buy "safe" assets from developed economies, while the latter buy "risky" assets from emerging markets The U.S. as a venture capitalist (Gourinchas and Rey) R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 28 / 43 Force 6: Asymmetric alpha over beta Ratio of debt to equity and FDI 0.90 0.80 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 19 91 19 92 19 93 19 94 19 95 19 96 19 97 19 98 19 99 20 00 20 01 20 02 20 03 20 04 19 90 0.00 Gross liabilities of US R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Gross assets of US Spring 2011 29 / 43 Force 7: Asymmetric growth (decoupling) While emerging markets typically grow at a faster pace than developed economies, this gap has become very pronounced in the post-crisis phase This effect raises the expected return of all emerging market assets over those in developed economies This is probably a key factor behind the surge in capital fiows to emerging markets until very recently (i.e., until the US began to look a lot better) (Reinforcing this effect, the many adjustments EMs made in response to their own crisis in previous decades paid off. Developed economy investors took notice and have began to upgrade type B emerging market assets into type A assets) R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 30 / 43 Force 7: Asymmetric growth (decoupling) Equity Prices (January 4, 2007 = 100) 250 200 FTSE Latin America 150 S&P 500 S&P 500 Financials 100 50 0 2007 2008 2009 2010 Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 31 / 43 Force 8: Transitions In this new environment of safe assets scarcity, it makes a great difference to countries, and their sovereigns in particular, whether they are perceived as primarily type A or type B asset producers The PIIGS have seen the consequence of the bad transition, from A to B , while many emerging markets, such as Indonesia or Chile, are on the other side of the spectrum These transitions, when involving a large group of countries, have global equilibrium consequences: The CHF and JPY appreciations owe much to the fall in expected return in other developed economies The surge in capital fiows to many EMs owes much to the relative weakness of the developed world These general equilibrium sources of capital fiows are important to keep in mind when assessing strengths and weaknesses of particular recoveries R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 32 / 43 Force 8: Transitions 10 - Year Spreads with German Bund (Basis Points) 180 1000 160 900 140 800 120 700 600 100 500 400 80 60 300 40 200 20 0 Jan 06 Feb 07 Mar 08 Italy Belgium Apr 09 May 10 100 0 Jan 06 -100 Feb 07 Mar 08 Spain Ireland France Austria Apr 09 May 10 Portugal Greece Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. The Irish guarantee.... and now the EFSF guarantee... R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 33 / 43 QE The ultimate financial goal of such a policy is to reduce r B , as most private sector produced assets (borrowing by corporations and households) have a large component of type B assets In the early stages of QE, r B was targeted directly through the purchase of MBS and other distressed assets. This "credit-easing" policy was instrumental in stabilizing the economy, but as the recovery took hold, a series of political constraints and concerns brought that unorthodox strategy to an end The faltering in the recovery during 2010 (post-Euro crisis) was not severe enough to make it politically feasible to go back to credit-easing policies, which left the FED and other central banks with the second best policy of lowering r A (Treasury rates) and hoping that this would indirectly reduce r B R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 34 / 43 QE Let βΔ denote the purchases of type A assets by the Fed, which reduces the net supply of these assets faced by the private sector from β to β(1 − Δ) It is easy to see in the stark model that QE targeted at assets type A have no effect on r B : Since the share of income invested in assets type B is constant and the net supply of assets type B is not changed by QE, there is no effect of the policy on the price and return of this asset. Instead, all that happens is that p A rises by (approximately) Δ percent, and r A drops correspondingly: ptA,QE = α Yt ≈ (1 + Δ)ptA , β (1 − Δ ) θ (8) β rtA,QE − rtA = −δθ Δ. α R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction (9) Spring 2011 35 / 43 QE Thus, in order for QE to have an effect on r B , there needs to be a leak out of demand for assets type A. As r A drops to extremely low levels, it triggers a search for yield process that lowers r B . (The fear that this leak would lead to massive capital fiows to EM led to heated debates!). Assume that the minimum return investors are willing to accept for assets type A is r A,min . Then, there is a maximum QE, Δmax , such that any further increase in QE: ptA,QE = α Yt ; β(1 − Δmax ) θ rtA,QE = r A,min and ptB ,QE = 1 − α + β(Δ − Δmax ) Yt ; 1−β θ R.J. Caballero (MIT) rtB ,QE = g + δθ Introduction 1−β . 1 − α + β(Δ − Δmax ) Spring 2011 36 / 43 QE Some of this search for yield is concerning, as agents that should not be holding certain risks begin to do it (this is what caused the demise of Reserve Primary Fund at the worst point of the subprime crisis). Initially the search goes to marginally riskier assets, but as the progression continues the private sector loads increasing amounts of risks into its balance sheet In fact, this pattern is already building up, as some pension funds that traditionally have invested in type A assets are now being forced to move into type B assets since r A is too low for them to honor their future contingent liabilities On net, a good policy, but it has risks... mostly because it pushes the private sector into taking more risks R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 37 / 43 The near future and some financial policy considerations At the world level, g , δ, θ, β have declined while α has risen. The most immediate consequence is an extremely low r A for the few assets that are considered type A (a few sovereigns and corporations), and an enormous reluctance to hold macroeconomic risk (a sharp rise in λ). It is not that interest rates are low in developed economies because central banks have decided to keep them there. The causality runs the other way around: they have to set low policy rates because the equilibrium rates are so low that if they didn’t, the economy would experience strong defiationary forces (this is by Walras’Law, since an excess demand for assets must mean an excess supply of goods) R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 38 / 43 The near future and some financial policy considerations An extreme example of how tough it has gotten for type B assets is in the market for long-dated macro volatility Currently, the price for insurance against "Black Swan" type events is so high, that is pricing in the possibility of an event worst than the great depression in the next few years In the model, this price of insurance is exactly λ, once we think of B assets as those that are particularly exposed to a large systemic event. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 39 / 43 The near future and some financial policy considerations 50% Dec 20 SPX variance swap bid 40% 30% Dec 15 SPX variance swap bid 5-Year SPX realized vol. 20% 10% 10-Year SPX realized vol. 43 Ja n 48 Ja n 53 Ja n 58 Ja n 63 Ja n 68 Ja n 73 Ja n 78 Ja n 83 Ja n 88 Ja n 93 Ja n 98 Ja n 03 Ja n 08 38 Ja n Ja n Ja n 33 0% Source: Morgan Stanley Quantitative and Derivative Strategies Image by MIT OpenCourseWare. This situation is worrisome not only because it refiects a major dislocation, but also because it provides potentially dangerous incentives for the distribution of aggregate risk holding (a sort of AIG on steroids). R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 40 / 43 The near future and some financial policy considerations The counterpart of the tough environment for B assets is the enormous reward from being a type A asset producer, which is precisely what has maintained very low deficit funding costs for prime sovereigns. The knee-jerk policy reaction after a crisis takes place is to attempt to prevent further private transformations from B to A For example, by increasing capital requirements R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 41 / 43 The near future and some financial policy considerations Unfortunately that kind of policies ignores the structural deficit of type A assets that drives the perverse incentives... There is a complementary policy reaction which is for the government to provide (paid) insurance against the panic component of systemic crises This has the potential to expand the effective supply of A assets (i.e., β) and thereby reduce the λ that is behind much of the incentives to create macroeoconomically fragile instruments. (TIC proposal) When governments cannot offer any credible guarantee, the private sector has to build up a buffer to prevent panic-driven asset perception swings. But this is not an objective in itself, rather it is one of the many costs of chronic fiscal misbehavior. R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 42 / 43 Final remarks The model has no nominal assets. Adding these would show that defiation is a complementary mechanism to restore equilibrium in financial markets when real interest rates do not converge quickly enough (although this Pigou mechanism may not be strong enough to pull the economy out of a recession) What makes an asset type A or type B? This varies from time to time. There are "super"-A assets that remain immutable though crises (such as U.S., German or Swiss treasuries). On the opposite extreme there are those that are type B par-excellence, such as the illiquid equity of small caps The great majority of assets lies in between. "Bond vigilantes" and their relatives live from and in this region; while hawkish policy reactions are often motivated in terms of the distance from it. The soundest reforms are those that shrink the region of instability while maximizing the availability of A type assets. I’m not sure policymakers are giving much weight to the latter goal... R.J. Caballero (MIT) Introduction Spring 2011 43 / 43 MIT OpenCourseWare http://ocw.mit.edu 14.454 Economic Crises Spring 2011 For information about citing these materials or our Terms of Use, visit: http://ocw.mit.edu/terms.