Are Off-balance Sheet Activities Risky? Evidence from G7 Countries Mamiza Haq UQ Business School, The University of Queensland, QLD 4072, Australia. Email: m.haq@business.uq.edu.au. Telephone: 61-7-3346-3090, Facsimile: 61-7-334-68166. Abstract This paper analyses the importance of off-balance sheet activities and charter value on bank risks, using an unbalanced panel dataset of publicly-listed domestic banks across Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, UK and US over the 1996–2010 period, with particular focus on the 2007/2008 global financial crisis (GFC). Overall, our results show a positive relationship between off-balance sheet activities and market-based risk measures (such as total, systematic, idiosyncratic and interest rate risks) in the post (during)-GFC period. The self-disciplinary role of charter value is observed in post (during)-GFC period, particularly for total and idiosyncratic risks. Further, charter value may substitute bank capital in reducing systematic risk. These findings have policy implications for bank safety. JEL: G21, G32 Key words: Off-balance sheet items, derivatives, charter value, risk, financial crisis. Acknowledgements: The authors wish to thank Enzo Dia, Kevin Davis, and conference participants at the 13th INFINITI International Finance Conference in 2015. The authors acknowledge 2014 AFAANZ Mid-career Research Grant. The usual caveats apply. 1 1. Introduction At the very heart of the global financial crisis (GFC) in 2007/2008, losses were associated with off-balance sheet activities created and held by financial institutions that led to overall risk exposure of banks. These losses resulted in the failure, acquisition or bailout of some of the largest institutions and a near meltdown of the world’s financial and economic systems. Financial institutions have incentives to take ‘excessive’ risk at the expense of tax-payers funds and creditors because of the well-known ‘moral hazard’ problem emanating from limited liability and mispriced deposit insurance premium (Merton, 1977). This is compounded by the ‘too-bigto-fail’ effect with large banks. A failure of a bank can have severe repercussions to the local and/or national economy unlike non-financial institutions. Such externalities impose a burden on regulators to ensure that these failures do not impose major negative externalities on the economy. The aim of this paper is to assess the effectiveness of off-balance sheet activities in reducing risk and the factors affecting off-balance sheet activities strength in the G7 countries context. Our study contributes to the existing banking literature in several ways. First, we investigate the effectiveness of off-balance sheet activities in reducing bank risk. We question whether banks that are more reliant on non-interest generating activities take less risk. Specifically, we investigate the following empirical questions. First, we test the effectiveness of off-balance sheet activities pre and post 2007/2008 financial crisis. Second, we examine whether bank regulation weakens the impact of off-balance sheet activities on bank risk taking. We assume that bank capital and charter value may have a complementary role to play in disciplining banks, while risk-based capital requirements may discourage banks to engage in off-balance sheet activities and hence reduce the risk of the banking system. Third, we analyse the moderating effect of off-balance sheet activities on bank charter value and bank’s asset quality in reducing bank risk. We assume that off-balance sheet activities provide banks with a comparative advantage and greater efficiency which can lead to an increase 2 in charter value (Reference). Further, Avery and Berger (1991) argue that safer banks with high quality assets have a greater tendency to engage in off-balance sheet activities which in turn help banks to reduce risk. The traditional banking business makes long-term loans and funds them by issuing shortterm deposits. However, in recent years in particular prior to the financial crisis 2007/2008, fundamental economic forces have undercut the traditional role of banks in financial intermediation leading to a steady decline in the importance of bank loans and deposits. Over the decades rising losses on loans, increased interest rate volatility, and squeezed interest margins for on-balance sheet lending, due to non-bank competition, induced many large banks particularly, in US to seek profitable off-balance sheet activities. By moving activities off their balance sheet banks hoped to earn more fee income to offset the declining margins on their traditional lending business. At the same time, they could avoid regulatory costs since reserve requirements, deposit insurance premiums and capital adequacy requirements were not levied on off-balance sheet activities 1. This has proved difficult for both investors and regulators to identify the actual level of risk a bank faces in a given period of time. In the banking literature (e.g.; ) there is mixed evidence as to whether off-balance sheet activities increase (decrease) risk. Thus, given increased bank competition, and divergent capital rules, banks across the world have shifted towards nontraditional activities. These activities do not appear on the balance sheet and they involve the creation of contingent assets and liabilities. Hence, due to the nature of these activities and the fact that they have become increasingly widespread it is difficult for investors and regulators to identify the actual level of risk a bank faces in a given period of time. Off-balance sheet exposures may induce banks to reduce their total and systematic risks (Brewer, Koppenhaver and Wilson 1986; Lynge and Lee 1987; Boot and Thakor 1991; Hassan, Karels and Peterson 1994; Angbazo 1997). Similarly, Esty (1998) argues that contingent liabilities can reduce equity and asset volatility as they have an impact on asset allocation and bank capital 1 Some of the non-interest income may not be part of the off-balance sheet activities. For example, commission and fees can are also charged on credit cards and other services and trading income is not exclusively generated by off balance sheet activities. 3 requirements. Thus, even at low levels of net worth (charter value), banks with lower levels of contingent liabilities may hold a smaller proportion of risky assets. Banks must honor guarantees implicit in contingent liabilities or agreements when required. 2 These liabilities help banks, particularly in times of increased competition, to expand their revenue sources without altering their capital structure. Banks with higher levels of offbalance sheet items are found to be more cost and profit efficient and it has been argued that off-balance sheet exposures promote a more diversified, margin generating asset-base compared to deposits or equity financing (Angbazo, 1997). However, increased off-balance sheet activities and escalation in bank failures have raised concern about the possibility of a positive relation between bank risk and off-balance sheet items. For example, US commercial banks exhibit a positive correlation between bank interest rate risk and off-balance sheet activities including letters of credit, options and net securities lent (Angbazo, 1997). This supports the moral hazard and adverse selection hypothesis that off-balance sheet activities increase bank risk (Wagster, 1996; Fraser, Madura and Weigand, 2002). We analyse 278 publicly-listed banks across Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the UK and the U.S. over 1996–2010, a period of extensive and rapid regulatory changes in the financial sectors. Our overall results can be summarised as follows: (i) off-balance sheet activities increase bank total, systematic and idiosyncratic risks but decrease interest rate risk in post-GFC period; (ii) However, this influence varies depending on other bank-specific characteristics (including charter value and asset quality) and the 2007/2008 GFC. For example, we observe that in presence of off-balance sheet activities, charter value decreases total and idiosyncratic risks over 2007/2010; (iii) loans are associated with higher market-based risks in both pre- and post (during)-GFC periods; (iv) the importance of bank capital in reducing bank risk is 2 Calmes and Theoret (2010) use the broad definition of off-balance sheet activities which loosely include all non-interest generating activities (income diversification is predominantly generated by these activities). Indeed, non-interest income has become an indispensable proportion of banks’ income today. For example, the total value of non-interest income had been larger than the interest income for US listed banks from 2003 to 2007. However, how beneficial this income diversification is remains unclear, in fact, there is a large body of literature related to the cost and benefit of bank diversification. 4 somewhat inconclusive; (v) disciplining role of bank charter value is effective in post (during)GFC period; (vi) charter value may substitute bank capital. The findings of this study may assist regulators to rigorously monitor banks, ensuring adequate internal controls over asset quality and risk management. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents data and methodology. Section 3 describes the empirical analysis while robustness checks are provided in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper with some policy implications. 2. Data and Methodology 2.1 Data The dataset consists of G-7 countries (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, UK and USA) over 15 years’ time span (1996-2010). Bank level information, including the balance sheet and income statement is extracted mainly from the Fitch Solutions database. The annual report of each of the banks is checked to ensure that bank subsidiaries are not also included as separate entities in our final data set to reduce the impact of double counting. We have used weekly market information including share prices and interest rate information from DataStream International. The original sample is filtered by excluding banks with less than three consecutive yearly observations, and banks for which data on the main variables are not available (such as market capitalization, tier 1 ratio). Thus, the final sample includes 278 publicly-listed domestic banks, giving an unbalanced panel of 3,149 bank-year observations. Table 1 provides the sample composition. [Insert Table 1 about here] 2.2 Alternate dependent variables The bank risk variables, broadly referred to as RISKijt in the following sections, include market-based risk indicators i.e. total, idiosyncratic, systematic and interest rate risks. Total risk is computed as the variance of the weekly bank stock returns in each year, i.e., (1) σ 2ri = 1/N ∑ tN=1 (R t − R ) 2 5 where σ ri2 = the total risk or variance of bank returns for bank i; Ri = bank i return per week; R = the average bank i return and; N = the number of observations. Following Konishi and Yasuda (2004), we use the following two-factor market model to compute systematic, interest rate and idiosyncratic risks 3. (2) R it = α i + β i, m R Mt + β i, I R It + ε it where R it = weekly stock return of bank i at date t ; R Mt = weekly return on the market. Based on the geographical exposure either the MSCI country index or the MSCI world index or the MSCI Europe index is used; ε it = residual term. The market beta, β m , is used as a proxy for systematic risk and is estimated using the MSCI market index. The natural log of the residual variance from the two factor market model is used as an estimate of idiosyncratic risk for each of the banks. The interest rate beta, βI , is estimated to capture interest rate exposure. We follow the work of Haq and Heaney (2012) and choose the long term interest rate in our model since longterm interest rates are considered to better explain bank returns 4. 2.3 Variables of interest Traditional off-balance sheet activities are measured by total off-balance sheet items against total liabilities. Off-balance sheet activities include managed securitized assets, guarantees, acceptances and documentary credits, and committed credit lines and other off-balance sheet activities. Market-related off-balance sheet activities are the sum of equity derivatives, interest rate derivatives, credit derivatives, foreign exchange derivatives and commodity derivatives scaled by total assets (Mayordomo, Rodriguez-Moreno and Peña, 2014). 3 Multi-factor models like the Fama and French three factor model are not used for risk estimation in this study as there is little support in the literature for the use of this model in analysis of bank returns (Viale, Kolari and Fraser, 2009). The risk estimates are calculated each year for each bank using the weekly return observations available during the year of interest. While there is some support for expanding the one factor model to include yield curve effects we include the interest rate level in our two factor model given the importance of interest rate sensitivity in analysis of bank risk. It should be noted that interest rate level will be correlated with yield curve, though ultimately variable choice is still fairly arbitrary in the asset pricing literature. 4 However, there is debate concerning whether a two factor market model or a one factor market model should be used. Due to multicollinearity between interest rates and market factors some authors orthogonalize changes in the interest rate factor (Flannery and James 1984). Giliberto (1985) argues that this approach can bias the t-statistics against one or other of the two factors. As a result, we follow Kane and Unal (1988) estimate the model without any attempt to remove common variation from one of the variables. 6 2.4 Bank-level and country-level control variables Charter value is the ratio of the sum of the market value of equity and the book value of liabilities to the book value of total assets following Keeley (1990). Bank capital is measured by Tier 1 ratio as mentioned in the Basel Accords. On one hand, capital ratio can discipline banks by way of the capital at risk effect, because by operating with their own capital, banks bear part of the risk for their activities (Tabak, Fazio and Cajueiro, 2012). One the other hand, higher capital levels may induce banks to increase probability of default (Gennotte and Pyle, 1991; Shrieves and Dahl, 1992; Berger, Herring and Szegö, 1995; Rime, 2001) since regulatory constraints on bank leverage lead to substitution from debt into more risky assets. Thus, the overall effect of bank capital is ambiguous. Further, as an indicator of asset quality (AQ) we define loans as the ratio of total loans to total assets (Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001), reflecting to what extent bank’s focus on traditional intermediation activity that is originate loans compared to hold other assets such as securities (Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga, 2012). The operational efficiency of banks is measured by cost to income ratio. Less efficient banks reflect higher expenditures. However, it can also be the case that banks that provide better quality services to their customers can incur higher expenditures to total assets (Martinez –Peria and Schmukler, 2001). Similar to Martinez –Peria and Schmukler (2001) we are unable to control for quality of the services provided by banks, thus, the effect of this variable is indeterminate. Operating leverage is measured by fixed assets to total assets. Mandelker and Rhee (1984) and Saunders, Strock and Travlos (1990) consider operating leverage in a similar way to financial leverage with increases in operating leverage resulting in increases in bank risk. Thus, the analysis considers that operating leverage will be positively related to alternate bank risk measures. With regard to revenue diversification prior literature (e.g.; Lepetit, Nys, Rous and Tarazi, 2008; Stiroh and Rumble, 2006) suggest that banks' expansion into non-traditional financial activities is not associated with diversification benefits, but rather with lower risk-adjusted return and higher insolvency risk. However, Baele, De Jonghe and Vennet (2007) provide evidence that 7 the market judges more diversified banks to have a higher return potential (measured by Tobin’s Q). 5 Williams (2012) finds evidence in the Australian context that combining interest with noninterest revenues does not generate any portfolio diversification benefit, supporting the argument that greater complexity can lead to an increase in agency costs that may exceed any diversification benefits (Schmid and Walter, 2009; Laeven and Levine, 2007). Revenue diversity is captured by non-interest income, calculated as: Revenue diversification index i,j,t= 1- (SH2NETi,j,t + SH2NONi,j,t) (3) where; SH2NET=share of net operating revenue from net interest sources and SH2NON = share of net operating revenue from non-interest sources. Finally, we incorporate bank size (natural logarithmn of total assets) to capture any effects of size differences among the sample banks. Large banks may be less risky, since they benefit more from portfolio diversification. However, regulatory environment can affect the relationship between bank size and bank risk. Deregulatory periods can encourage a positive relationship between bank size and bank total risk. In periods of greater regulation also, the imposition of “too-big-to-fail” policies, explicit and implicit safety net can increase the incentive of large banks to take on more risk (Galloway et al., 1997). Large banks with greater sensitivity to the general market movements may exhibit a positive relationship with bank systematic risk (Anderson and Fraser, 2000). Hence, we predict a positive association between systematic risk and size. The Economic Freedom Index (EFI) is used to measure regulatory restrictions, with higher EFI scores reflecting reduced levels of regulation. A negative relationship is predicted between bank risk and EFI. We follow Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga (2004) and incorporate real GDP growth (RGDP) as the macro-economic control variable. This will capture the impact of macro-economic shocks that adversely affect bank performance by increasing risk. Hence, we predict the relationship to be positive with risk. 5 Baele, De Jonghe and Vennet (2007) also argue that a bank that is more oriented towards non-traditional banking activities (lower loan to total asset ratio) has a higher systematic and total risk. 8 2.5 Descriptive statistics and correlation analysis Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for bank characteristics and macro-economic variables. The alternative measures, of bank risk, that is, total, systematic, idiosyncratic, and interest rate risks have a mean value of 0.002, 0.635, 0.001, -0.027, respectively. [Insert Table 2 about here] In general, traditional off-balance sheet activities range between 0.3% - 22.3% with an average of 4.90%. Market-related off-balance sheet activities range between 0 - 0.087 with an average of 0.002, which is consistent with Mayordomo, Rodriguez-Moreno and Peña, 2014. Keeley’s (1990) measure of charter value has a mean of 1.03. The maximum (1.11) and minimum (0.97) charter value is observed in the U.S. and Japan, respectively. Banks hold a Tier 1 ratio well above the minimum capital requirement of 4%. For example, the maximum Tier 1 ratio of 14.1% and the minimum of 6.60% are observed for Royal Bank of Scotland Group Plc in 2009 and 1998 respectively. Regarding size, the smallest bank in the study is Canadian Western Bank with total assets of USD 66.51 million in 1996, whereas the largest bank, Royal Bank of Scotland Group Plc has total assets of USD 4267.102 million in 2008. The maximum and minimum value for bank efficiency (i.e.; cost to income ratio) ranges between 52%-79%, and observed for U.S. banks. On average, bank total assets consist of 66% of bank loans. The macroeconomic variable real GDP growth rate reflects both crisis and normal periods. During the 2008-2010 period, GDP growth rate ranged between -6.23% to -0.021%. Pearson correlation coefficients are reported in Table 3. The correlation between charter value and tier 1 ratio and charter value and efficiency is 0.29 and -0.37 respectively and statistically significant. Other bank-specific variables are also significantly correlated with size including Tier 1 ratio (-0.36), off-balance sheet activities (0.21), loan to total assets (-0.24) and operating leverage (-0.21). To ensure that correlations will not lead to multi-collinearity, we check the variance inflation factors (VIF). All VIF values were less than 10, with the means lying between 2 and 4, suggesting that multi-collinearity is not a serious problem (Gujrati, 2003). 9 [Insert Table 3 about here] 2.6 Empirical method To examine the impact of off-balance sheet activities on bank risk, we estimate the following panel data model applying both individual bank and time fixed effects (Distinguin, Kouassi and Tarazi, 2013): α 0 + β1OBS i,j,t + β2 CVi,j,t + β3 Tier 1 i,j,t + β4 Loans i,j,t + β5 Fixed i,j,t + β6 RDI i,j,t + β7CIR i,j,t + β8 Size i,j,t + Risk i,j,t = γ1GDPGR j,t + γ 2 EFI j,t + η i + τ t + ε i,j,t (4) In the context of equation (5), we make the following predictions: β1 > 0. We predict that off-balance sheet activities have a positive impact on bank risk. Equation (5) explores the association between off-balance sheet activities and risk conditional on a bank’s market power and asset quality. α 0 + β1OBS i,j,t + β2 CVi,j,t + β3 Tier 1 i,j,t + β4 Loans i,j,t + β5 Fixed i,j,t + β6 RDI i,j,t + β7CIR i,j,t + β8 Size i,j,t + Risk i,j,t = γ1GDPGR j,t + γ 2 EFI j,t + δ1CVi,j,t × OBS i,j,t + δ2 Loans i,j,t × OBS i,j,t + η i + τ t + ε i,j,t (5) In addition, to examine how the association between bank capital and risk is conditional on the strength of a bank’s off-balance sheet activities, market power, asset quality, we estimate the following specification: α 0 + β1OBS i,j,t + β2 CVi,j,t + β3 Tier 1 i,j,t + β4 Loans i,j,t + β5 Fixed i,j,t + β6 RDI i,j,t + β7CIR i,j,t + β8 Size i,j,t + Risk i,j,t = γ1GDPGR j,t + γ 2 EFI j,t + δ1CVi,j,t × Tier1i,j,t + δ2OBS i,j,t × Tier1i,j,t + δ3 Loans i,j,t × Tier1i,j,t + η i + τ t + ε i,j,t (6) where: i for individual banks (i = 1, 2, , 16); j for country (j = 1, 2), t for time period (t = 1996, 1997, ….., 2010); ηi is the individual fixed effects, t t is the time fixed-effects, and εi,j,t is the remaining disturbance term. 3. Empirical results 3.1 Main results We test for the impact of off-balance sheet activities on both market-based risks. To do so, we divide our sample into two narrow periods including 1996-2006 (pre-GFC) and 20072010 (post (during)-GFC). First, we find that all our models satisfy the requirement of the bank 10 fixed-effects (Hausman test). The results are reported in Panel A (traditional off-balance sheet activities) and Panel B (derivative or market related off-balance sheet activities) of Table 4. [Insert Table 4 about here] Our findings document that off-balance sheet activities increase bank systematic and idiosyncratic risks in post (during)-GFC period which in turn, increases bank total risk in the same period (see columns 2, 4 & 6). Hence, the market recognises the importance and riskiness of off-balance sheet activities during 2007/2010 period. Similar evidence is also observed for interest rate risk (see columns 7) however, in pre-GFC period. This positive and statistically significant association between off-balance sheet activities and bank risk suggest that off-balance sheet activities, while generating fee income for banks, also creates additional bank risk. This could be a concern for bank regulators as the risk of off-balance sheet activities, if not managed properly, could squeeze liquidity and create sudden losses. However, both Basel Accord I and II proposals have also considered off-balance sheet activities to be risky and these are included in risk-weighted bank capital ratio calculations. This action seems warranted given the results reported in this study. We also perceive that in post (during)-GFC period, the coefficient on off-balance sheet activities is negative and statistically significant at the 5% level or better, particularly, for interest rate risks, (see column 8). These findings suggest that off-balance sheet activities help banks to reduce interest rate risk and thus, manage banks' maturity mismatch issue particularly, in the post (during)-GFC period. Further, we find support those off-balance sheet activities also decrease bank systematic risk in pre-GFC period (see column 3), indicating that market may have failed to identify the riskiness of the contingent liabilities. With regard to control variables, we observe that the disciplinary role of charter value is effective in post (during)-GFC period. For example, the coefficient on charter value for total and idiosyncratic risks (see columns 2 & 6) is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level. In contrast, we find that higher charter value tends to increase systematic and interest rate risks, 11 particularly, in pre-GFC period, suggesting that a surge in market value of equity and total liabilities has a positive impact on market-based risk measures (see columns 3, & 7). Thus, the disciplinary role of charter value was absent prior to 2007/2010 period. High bank capital is associated with lower total and idiosyncratic risks in both pre- and post (during)-GFC period (see columns 1, 2, 5 & 6). However, we do observe that bank capital tend to increase interest rate risk in the pre-GFC period (see column 7). Our findings show higher loans to assets ratios (asset quality) are associated with lower bank total, idiosyncratic risks during 2007/2010 period (see columns 2 & 6). Further, operating leverage exhibits a positive (statistically significant at 5% level or better) effect on total, systematic, idiosyncratic risks during 2007/2010 and interest rate risk over 1996-2006 (see column 7). The coefficient on bank size is negatively associated with total, systematic and idiosyncratic risks over the full sample period, suggesting that bank risk-taking may not be consistent with the “too-big –to-fail-policy”, where large banks have greater incentive to take on risky businesses as they enjoy a comprehensive safety net. With regard to macro-economic variables, real GDP growth rate is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level or better for total and idiosyncratic risks, capturing the impact of adverse macro-economic shocks that affect banks by increasing their risk exposure over 2007/2010 period. Similar evidence is observed for systematic risk over the full sample period. However, GDP growth rate decreased idiosyncratic risk in pre-GFC period. Further, economic freedom index (EFI) is negatively associated with all bank risk measures and is statistically significant at the 1% level (see columns 1, 3, 5 & 6). This result implies that greater levels of economic freedom, particularly, in terms of lower levels of regulation and government intervention, generate lower total, systematic and idiosyncratic risks. Hence, the result is consistent with our predictions. 12 3.2 Results for intermediating effects 3.2.1 Intermediating effects of off-balance sheet activities It has been argued that off-balance sheet activities increase volatility in bank’s revenue and therefore, increases bank risk (Mayordomo, Rodriguez-Moreno and Pena, 2014; Nijskens and Wagner, 2011; Calmès and Théoret, 2010). Further, contingent liabilities can help banks to earn rents temporarily if they have superior production technology that may not be available to other institutions, the so-called first-mover effect (Furlong and Kwan, 2006). Banks may have scope economies with other bank activities giving them a cost-advantage over non-bank institutions because banks have a comparative advantage in off-balance sheet activities like loan commitments (Haq and Heaney, 2012). Indeed, the combination of scope economies and potential efficiency enhancement can contribute to improve banks' charter value (Furlong and Kwan, 2006). Thus, even in presence of high off-balance sheet activities, bank charter value can decrease bank risk. Furthermore, it is evident that off-balance sheet activities increase the insolvency exposure of a bank that engages in such activities. However, an opposing view holds that loan commitments contracts may make a bank less risky than had it not engaged in them. The theoretical work by Boot and Thakor (1991) suggest that banks must convince borrowers that it will be around to provide the credit required in the near future. Thus, bank managers may have to maintain lower risk asset portfolio today than would otherwise be the case. By adopting lowerrisk portfolios, managers increase the probability that bank will be able to meet all long-term on and off balance sheet obligations. Empirical studies such as Avery and Berger (1991) confirm that bank’s making more loan commitments have lower on balance sheet portfolio risk characteristics than those with relatively low levels of commitments, that is safer banks have a greater tendency to make loan commitments. 13 Based on the above discussion we incorporate two interaction terms including charter × off-balance activities and asset quality × off-balance activities. Thus, we estimate eq. (5) and the results are reported in Table 5. [Insert Table 5 about here] The coefficient on charter × off-balance sheet activities is negative and statistically significant with bank total and idiosyncratic risk in post (during)-GFC period (see columns 2 & 6). These findings suggest the self-disciplinary role of charter value is evident for market-based measures of risk. Furthermore, with regard to total and idiosyncratic risks, the coefficient on asset quality × off-balance sheet activities is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level or better (see columns 1, 2, 5 & 6). This finding is observed for both pre and post (during)-GFC periods, indicating that in presence of off-balance sheet activities loans tend to increase bank risk. We find similar evidence for systematic risk although for post (during) - GFC period only (see column 4). 3.2.2 Intermediating effects of bank capital It is well-known that government guarantees or safety nets (such as deposit insurance, too-big-to-fail guarantees, and lender of last resort) can lead to a moral hazard problem. If the value of guarantees to the bank is less than they are charged for them, the safety net provides banks with a net subsidy (Allen and Rai, 1996), which is incorporated within the bank’s charter value. Thus, the moral hazard effect explains that, if bank charter value stems from government subsidies, this may discourage banks from holding capital. As these subsidies become more generous, bank capital is substituted by a government safety net and a negative association emerges between charter value and bank capital. The market rent effect, however, reflects a positive association between bank capital and charter value. To avoid any additional costs from providing a subsidy, governments impose restrictions on entry to banking. Entry restrictions allow banks to earn monopoly rents that may be dependent on the terms of the safety nets. Imperfectly competitive financial markets can also allow banks to earn monopoly rents and thus, higher charter value. Bank failure can force the 14 shareholders to surrender the bank’s charter value or expected profits from continued operations. Therefore, banks’ expected future profitability leads to higher charter values which, in turn, reflect greater capital buffer which may be significant for shareholders to retain control and reduce the probability of default. [Insert Table 6 about here] Based on the above discussion, we estimate eq. (6) and the results are reported in Table 6. The coefficient on charter × Tier 1 ratio is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level for systematic risk only (see columns 3 & 4) during pre- and post (during) - GFC period. This finding supports the moral hazard effect suggesting that in presence of bank capital, charter value fails to discipline banks, thus, charter value can substitute rather than complement bank capital in reducing bank’s risk taking exposures. In addition, off-balance sheet activities are fee generating activities and can improve bank’s profitability much faster than on-balance sheet fee producing activities. For instance, earning generated from off-balance sheet activities are included in income while total asset balances are not affected, thus, profitability ratios appear higher compared to income derived from on-balance sheet activities. In addition, off-balance sheet activities remain off-the bank’s balance sheet, hence, capital to asset ratio (with the exception of risk-adjusted capital ratio) is not adversely affected regardless of the volume of business conducted (Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), 2012). However, the volume and the risk of the off-balance sheet activities need to be considered by the regulators and examiners in the evaluation of capital adequacy. Regulatory concern arises with these activities since they subject a bank to certain risks. Many of the risks involved in these off-balance sheet activities are unquantifiable on an off-site monitoring basis (FDIC, 2012). Moreover, the risk-based capital requirements can be viewed as discouraging off-balance sheet activities growth thus, reducing total risk of the banking system. Thus, banks engage in offbalance sheet activities to reduce regulatory taxes, such as capital requirements. In contrast, 15 Benveniste and Berger (1987), Koppenhaver (1989) argue that capital constraints do not play a role in bank’s decision to engage in off-balance sheet activities. Further, Avery and Berger (1991), Jagtiani (1995) find that better performing and more credit worthy banks issue loan commitments and swaps (inconsistent with capital avoidance hypotheses) and that capital requirements have no consistent impact on the speed of transmission across off-balance sheet activities (Jagtiani, Saunders and Udell, 1995). Thus, we interact off-balance sheet activities with Tier 1 ratio (contingent × Tier 1) to investigate whether in presence of bank capital; off-balance sheet activities decrease /increase bank risk. The results are reported in Table 6. With regard to total, idiosyncratic, and interest rate, the coefficient on contingent × Tier 1 is statistically insignificant, suggesting that the importance of bank capital on off-balance sheet activities in reducing risk is inconclusive. However, with regard to systematic risk, the coefficient on contingent × Tier 1 is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level (see column 4), suggesting that market continues to recognise the riskiness of off-balance sheet activities, even when bank has capital buffer in place during 2007/2010 period. Perhaps, bank capital requirements do not serve the risk curtailment purpose as they do for on-balance sheet claims. Next, we analyse whether banks properly estimate and truthfully report the riskiness of their loans and ensure compliance and reduce moral hazard in banking. This is precisely the subject of the supervisory review mentioned in Basel II (Repullo and Suarez, 2004). Our findings show that the coefficient on asset quality × Tier 1 is positive and statistically significant (at the 5% level) with total and idiosyncratic risks in post (during)-GFC period (see columns 2 & 6). Thus, in presence of bank capital, bank loans increases market-based risks. This result further supports the argument that Basel II does not take into account the net interest income from performing loans, which provides a buffer in addition to capital losses against credit losses (Repullo and Suarez, 2004). 16 5. Robustness checks We conduct a number of robustness checks. First, we run regressions excluding the USA bank holding companies. Our findings demonstrate that with regard to systematic risk, the coefficient on off-balance sheet activities is statistically insignificant in both pre- and post (during) - GFC period. Second, we test the sensitivity of our results by considering alternate proxy of bank capital. Following Demirgüç-Kunt and Huizinga (2004), we consider leverage ratio (equity to total assets) as a book value measure of bank capital. Our mains results remain qualitatively the same. Third, we re-do this analysis without country-level/macroeconomic variables. The interpretations of the result remain the same as those discussed earlier in Section 3. Fourth, we divide the sample into high off-balance sheet activities and low off-balance sheet activities considering the mean of the off-balance sheet activities as the cut-off point. Our findings show that if off-balance sheet activities are initially at a relatively low level, then an increase in off-balance sheet activities can lead to an increase in total, systematic and idiosyncratic risks. This finding is observed in post (during)-GFC period. Similar evidence is also evident for systematic and idiosyncratic risks in pre-GFC period. Banks with relatively high level of off-balance sheet activities and in pre-GFC period we find evidence that these items appear to increase interest rate risk. Finally, to derive a better understanding of charter value as a determinant of bank risk, we divide our sample into two groups: high charter value (above the mean value 1.03) and low charter value (below the mean value 1.03). The coefficients on off-balance sheet activities are positive and statistically significant at the 1% level, suggesting that in post (during)-GFC period and with lower charter value, off balance sheet activities increase bank risk including, total, systematic and idiosyncratic risks. However, the opposite is true for interest rate risk. We also observe that in pre-GFC period and with high (low) charter value, off-balance sheet activities tend to decrease systematic risk. In addition, the disciplinary role of charter value is observed for 17 both high and low charter value banks in post (during)-GFC period across total and idiosyncratic risks. However, the coefficient on charter value is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level for total and systematic risks, indicating that disciplinary role of charter value is not in effect even for high charter value banks in pre-GFC period. 6. Conclusion The significant growth in off-balance sheet activities leads to difficulty to investigate bank risk. There has been increased amount of regulation focusing particularly on off-balance sheet activities. For example, Basel Accords increased the credit conversion factor for these activities from 50% (Basel I) to 100% (Basel II). Hence, regulators have repeatedly concentrated on strengthening bank capital, disclosure and supervision for banks in controlling excessive risktaking. Charter value has also gained the interest of the regulators in so far as it can work as a self-disciplinary tool in reducing the moral hazard problem that arises from implicit and explicit deposit insurance schemes. Against this backdrop, our paper investigates the impact of offbalance sheet activities and charter value on bank risk with particular focus on the recent financial crisis 2007/2008. To this end, evidence is sought as to how this relationship is conditional on the strength of a bank’s capital regulation and asset quality. Using a sample of all publicly listed domestic banks across G-7 countries over the 1996 to 2010 period, our results suggest that, on average, off-balance sheet activities increase bank risk (total, systematic, idiosyncratic and interest rate risks) in the post (during)-GFC period. The self-disciplinary role of charter value is evidenced in post (during)-GFC period, particularly for total and idiosyncratic risks. We show that in presence of charter value, off-balance sheet activities decrease total and idiosyncratic risks in post (during)-GFC period. Most notably, we find that charter value may substitute bank capital in reducing systematic risk. Finally, our findings support that the importance of bank capital on off-balance sheet activities in reducing risk is inconclusive. In general, the findings of this study have implications for regulators, equity-holders, bond holders and borrowers, all of whom have concern in understanding the risk and return 18 profile of financial institutions. Evaluating bank risk is equally important to regulators/supervisors, borrowers, equity and bond holders. Regulators (including implicit and explicit safety net providers) and supervisors, who are responsible to maintain financial stability, have a keen interest in bank risk (in particular total risk) due to the costs associated with bankruptcy, contagion, asymmetric information, managerial agency problems and possible disruption in the allocation of credit. Well-diversified equity-holders are particularly concerned with systematic risk while bond holders tend to be concerned with both systematic risk and idiosyncratic risk. Unfortunately, as a result of the GFC, there is a deeply embedded presumption that governments will use taxpayer dollars to bail out banks, creating a solid incentive for banks to take undue risks. Should this be allowed to continue, it will leave bank supervisors as the main restraint on excessive risk taking – not the banks themselves or their investors. Regulators and policymakers are setting out proposals aimed at counteracting the effects of this moral hazard on financial systems. The usefulness of the determinants of bank risk suggests that transparency mandated by regulators have been reflected in the market-based measure. Thus, it supports the belief that market risk is useful in evaluating large, complex and opaque financial institutions. 19 References Anderson, R. C., Fraser, D. R., 2000. Corporate control, bank risk taking, and the health of the banking industry. Journal of Banking and Finance, 24(8), 1383-1398. Baele, L., De Jonghe, O., Vennet, R. V., 2007. Does the stock market value bank diversification? Journal of Banking and Finance, 31(7), 1999-2023. Berger, A.N., 1991. Market discipline in banking. Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and Competition. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. Berger, A., Herring, R. J., Szegö, G. P., 1995. The role of capital in financial institutions. Journal of Banking and Finance, 19(3-4), 393-430. Boyd, J. H., De Nicoló, G., 2005. The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1329-1343. Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Huizinga, H., 2004. Market discipline and deposit insurance. Journal of Monetary Economics, 51(2), 375-399. Demsetz, R. S., Saidenberg, M., Strahan, P. E., 1996. Banks with something to lose: the disciplinary role of franchise value. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review, 2, 1-14. Distinguin, I., Kouassi, T., Tarazi, A., 2013. Interbank deposits and market discipline: Evidence from Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, 41 (2), 544-560. Fukuda, S. I., Kasuya, M., Akashi, K., 2009. Impaired bank health and default risk. Pacific Basin Finance Journal. 17 (2), 145-162. Galloway, T. M., Lee, W. B., Roden, D. M., 1997. Banks' changing incentives and opportunities for risk taking. Journal of Banking and Finance, 21(4), 509-527. González, F., 2005. Bank regulation and risk taking incentives: an international comparison of bank risk. Journal of Banking and Finance, 29(5), 1153-1184. Hellmann, T., Murdock, K., Stiglitz, J., 2000. Liberalization, moral hazard in banking, and prudential regulation: are capital requirements enough? American Economic Review, 90(1), 147-165. Herring, R. J., 2004. The subordinated debt alternative to Basel II. Journal of Financial Stability, 1, 137155. Keeley, M. C., 1990. Deposit insurance, risk and market power in banking American Economic Review, 80(5), 1183-1200. Konishi, M., Yasuda, Y., 2004. Factors affecting bank risk taking: evidence from Japan. Journal of Banking and Finance, 28(1), 215-232. Lepetit, L., Nys, E., Rous, P., Tarazi, A. 2008. Bank income structure and risk: an empirical analysis of European banks. Journal of Banking and Finance, 32(8), 1452-1467. Marcus, A. J., 1984. Deregulation and bank financial policy. Journal of Banking and Finance, 8(4), 557565. Martinez Peria, M. S., Schmukler, S. L., 2001. Do depositors punish banks for bad behaviour? Market discipline, deposit insurance and banking crises. The Journal of Finance, LVI, (3) 1029-1051. Merton, R. C., 1977. An analytic derivation of the cost of deposit insurance and loan guarantees. Journal of Banking and Finance, 1(1), 512-520. Rime, B., 2001. Capital requirements and bank behavior: Empirical evidence for Switzerland. Journal of Banking and Finance, 25(4), 789-805. Saunders, A., Strock, E., Travlos, N. G., 1990. Ownership structure, deregulation and bank risk taking. Journal of Finance, 45(2), 643-654. Shrieves, R. E., Dahl, D., 1992. The relationship between risk and capital in commercial banks. Journal of Banking and Finance 16(2), 439-457. Stiroh, K. J., Rumble, A., 2006. The dark side of diversification: The case of US financial holding companies, Journal of Banking and Finance 30(8), 2131-2161. Tabak, B. M., Fazio, D. M., Cajueiro, D. O., 2012. The relationship between banking market competition and risk-taking: Do size and capitalization matter? Journal of Banking and Finance, 36, 3366-3381. Viale, A. M., Kolari, J. W., Fraser, D. R., 2009. Common risk factors in bank stocks, Journal of Banking and Finance, 33(3), 464-472. 20 Table 1 Sample composition The sample consists of 278 publicly-listed domestic banks including commercial banks and bank holding companies across Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom (UK) and the United States of America (USA) over 1996-2010, with a total bank–year observations of 3,149. Group 7 countries Number of listed domestic banks Number of observations Canada 8 115 France 5 75 Germany 6 85 Italy 10 130 Japan 90 1,053 UK 5 67 USA 154 1,624 278 3,149 21 Table 2 Descriptive statistics This table shows descriptive statistics for risk measures and bank-specific characteristics. Results are for all publicly-listed domestic banks across Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, United Kingdom (UK) and the United States of America (USA) over 1996-2010. We winsorize all variables at the 1% level. + scaled by 100 Mean Standard deviation Minimum Maximum Dependent variables Total risk 0.002 0.002 0.049+ 0.006 Systematic risk 0.635 0.456 0.018 1.387 Interest rate risk -0.027 0.145 -0.270 0.202 Idiosyncratic risk 0.001 0.001 0.037+ 0.004 0.049 0.002 0.073 0.011 0.003 0 0.223 0.087 Charter value 1.026 0.047 0.970 1.115 Tier 1 ratio 10.151 2.404 6.550 14.100 Revenue diversification 0.321 0.111 0.143 0.479 Efficiency 0.660 0.084 0.521 0.795 Loans to total assets 0.657 0.081 0.516 0.769 Fixed assets to total assets 0.016 0.007 0.007 0.027 Size (natural logarithm of total assets in USD) 9.906 3.789 4.190 22.170 Real GDP growth rate 0.018 0.023 -0.063 0.055 Economic freedom index 74.407 5.604 57.360 81.200 Variable of interest Off-balance sheet activities- traditional Off-balance sheet activities- market-related Bank-level control variables Country-level control variables 22 Table 3 Correlation analysis The table shows the pair-wise correlation between off-balance sheet activities (traditional and market related) and other bank-level and macro-level control variables. Superscript significant at the 5% level. Charter value Bank capital Off-balance sheet -traditional Off-balance sheet -market Revenue diversification Efficiency Asset quality Operating leverage Size **indicates GDP growth rate Charter value 1 Bank capital 0.29** 1 Off-balance sheet activities-traditional -0.09** -0.02 1 Off-balance sheet activities-market related -0.01 0.03 0.23** 1 Revenue diversification 0.22** 0.18** 0.38** 0.20** 1 Efficiency -0.37** -0.17** 0.01 0.02 -0.12** Asset quality -0.01 -0.20** -0.16** -0.25** -0.18** 0 1 Operating leverage 0.06** 0.07** -0.23** -0.23** 0.01 0.23** 0.18** 1 Size -0.23** -0.36** 0.21** 0.24** -0.04 -0.08 -0.24** -0.21** 1 GDP growth rate 0.41** 0.19** -0.11** -0.03 0.12** -0.17** -0.06** 0.10** -0.21** 1 Economic freedom index 0.30** 0.48** -0.05** 0.02 0.15** -0.08** 0.11** 0.09** -0.40** 0.07** 23 1 statistically Table 4 Determinants of bank risk- narrow period analysis The tables represent the results of the bank fixed-effects with year fixed effects estimates of equation (4). The dependent variable RISK is either total risk or idiosyncratic risk or systematic risk or interest rate risk. Total risk is the standard deviation of the bank’s weekly stock returns over a year (eq. 1). Idiosyncratic risk is calculated as the variance of εit in eq.(2). Systematic risk is the coefficient of Rmt, i.e. βm in the two-factor market model as represented by eq.(2). Interest rate risk is the coefficient of RIt, i.e. βI in the twofactor market model as represented by eq.(2). Standard errors are reported in parentheses. Superscripts*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Traditional off-balance sheet activities Off-balance sheet Charter value Tier 1 ratio Asset quality Operating leverage Revenue div. Efficiency Size GDP growth rate Economic freedom Intercept Year fixed-effects Number of observations F-test Adjusted-R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk Interest rate risk 1996-2006 (1) -0.001 (0.001) 0.001 (0.002) -0.006** (0.002) -0.001 (0.001) 0.012 20072010 (2) 0.008*** (0.001) -0.010*** (0.003) -0.010** (0.005) -0.004** (0.002) 0.046** 19962006 (3) -1.286*** (0.486) 0.612* (0.369) -1.213 (0.855) 0.214 (0.226) -0.796*** 20072010 (4) 1.475*** (0.245) -0.817 (0.553) -0.761 (1.094) -0.582 (0.441) 0.279* 19962006 (5) 0.001 (0.001) 0.001 (0.001) -0.004** (0.002) -0.001 (0.001) 0.012* 20072010 (6) 0.004*** (0.001) -0.007*** (0.002) -0.006*** (0.002) -0.003*** (0.001) 0.031** 19962006 (7) 0.192* (0.110) 0.273** (0.137) 0.653** (0.329) -0.245*** (0.093) 3.491*** Interest rate risk 20072010 (8) -0.249** (0.121) 0.359 (0.303) -0.367 (0.446) 0.387* (0.209) -3.309 (0.011) 0.001 (0.001) 0.010 (0.015) -0.055** (0.027) 0.002 (0.005) -0.003*** (0.023) 0.003 (0.010) 0.002** (0.001) -0.239** (0.119) 0.022** (0.009) -0.010 (0.318) 0.310* (0.180) 0.114 (0.181) -0.584** (0.282) 0.325*** (0.105) -0.011* (0.151) 0.275 (0.181) 0.086 (0.203) -0.417** (0.185) 3.721* (2.226) 0.034* (0.007) 0.001 (0.004) 0.005 (0.015) -0.020** (0.010) -0.007*** (0.002) -0.015*** (0.015) 0.010 (0.019) 0.001 (0.001) -0.072** (0.031) 0.037*** (0.009) -0.021*** (1.252) -0.087 (0.072) 0.016 (0.071) 0.089** (0.045) -0.522 (0.421) 0.001 (2.591) -0.077 (0.112) -0.040 (0.110) 0.088** (0.044) 1.224 (1.594) -0.003 (0.001) 0.012*** (0.002) Yes 2,228 (0.012) 0.024*** (0.008) Yes 921 (0.006) 0.541 (0.674) Yes 2,228 (0.019) -0.714 (1.646) Yes 921 (0.005) 0.009*** (0.002) Yes 2,228 (0.007) 0.025*** (0.005) Yes 921 (0.002) 2.756 (3.994) Yes 2,228 (0.012) -0.437 (5.105) Yes 921 17.01*** 0.16 101*** 0.60 33.71*** 0.39 6.63*** 0.13 21.78*** 0.22 75.02*** 0.58 7.83*** 0.04 16.75*** 0.23 24 Panel B: Market related (derivatives) off-balance sheet activities Derivatives Charter value Tier 1 ratio Asset quality Operating lev. Revenue div. Efficiency Size GDP growth Economic free. Intercept Year fixed-effects Number of observations F-test Adjusted-R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk 19962006 (1) -0.007*** (0.003) -0.002 (0.001) -0.003 (0.002) -0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.001) 0.000 (0.001) -0.000* (0.000) -0.006*** (0.002) -0.013*** (0.001) 0.013*** (0.003) Yes 2,328 20072010 (2) -0.004*** (0.001) -0.022*** (0.004) -0.006 (0.005) -0.004** (0.002) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.004*** (0.001) 0.003*** (0.001) -0.001* (0.001) -0.043*** (0.003) -0.008 (0.006) 0.030*** (0.008) Yes 964 19962006 (3) -0.761 (1.178) 1.795*** (0.341) -0.429 (0.653) -0.213 (0.224) -0.250*** (0.058) 0.782*** (0.193) 0.106 (0.219) 0.437*** (0.048) 5.582*** (0.636) 1.291** (0.518) -0.527 (0.878) Yes 2,328 20072010 (4) -0.112*** (0.028) -1.959*** (0.495) -0.423 (0.971) -0.955** (0.422) 0.132* (0.074) 0.155 (0.185) 0.101 (0.184) -0.044 (0.141) -0.150 (0.560) -0.342 (1.097) 3.937** (1.542) Yes 964 19962006 (5) -0.003* (0.002) -0.002* (0.001) -0.003 (0.002) 0.000 (0.001) 0.000** (0.000) -0.000 (0.000) 0.000 (0.000) -0.000*** (0.000) -0.007*** (0.002) -0.010*** (0.001) 0.010*** (0.002) Yes 2,328 20072010 (6) -0.005*** (0.001) -0.015*** (0.003) -0.003 (0.003) -0.004*** (0.001) 0.001*** (0.000) -0.002** (0.001) 0.002** (0.001) -0.000 (0.000) -0.024*** (0.002) 0.001 (0.004) 0.021*** (0.005) Yes 964 1996-2006 (7) 0.580** (0.241) 0.239* (0.145) 0.219 (0.252) -0.283*** (0.084) 0.014 (0.021) -0.090 (0.067) -0.025 (0.071) -0.058*** (0.018) -1.435*** (0.270) 0.069 (0.168) -0.437 (0.331) Yes 2,328 20072010 (8) -0.006 (0.014) 0.417* (0.250) -0.313 (0.427) 0.795*** (0.209) -0.050 (0.040) -0.272*** (0.105) 0.052 (0.110) -0.011 (0.070) 2.663*** (0.263) -0.389 (0.535) -0.893 (0.688) Yes 964 9.22*** 0.077 15.33*** 0.393 12.22*** 0.200 5.69*** 0.046 16.89*** 0.101 25.36*** 0.394 14.12*** 0.026 21.12*** 0.149 25 Interest rate risk Interest rate risk Table 5 Moderating effects- narrow period analysis The tables represent the results of the bank fixed-effects with year fixed effects estimates of equation (5). The dependent variable RISK is either total risk or idiosyncratic risk or systematic risk or interest rate risk. Total risk is the standard deviation of the bank’s weekly stock returns over a year (eq. 1). Idiosyncratic risk is calculated as the variance of εit in eq.(2). Systematic risk is the coefficient of Rmt, i.e. βm in the two-factor market model as represented by eq.(2). Interest rate risk is the coefficient of RIt, i.e. βI in the twofactor market model as represented by eq.(2). Standard errors are reported in parentheses. Superscripts*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Traditional off-balance sheet activities Charter × Contingent Asset quality × Contingent Intercept Year fixed effects Number of observation F-test Adjusted R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk Interest rate risk 19962006 (1) -0.009 20072010 (2) -0.071*** 1996-2006 2007-2010 1996-2006 2007-2010 (3) -0.562 (4) -0.233 (5) 0.007 (6) -0.047** 19962006 (7) 0.110 Interest rate risk 20072010 (8) -0.127 (0.020) 0.033*** (0.027) 0.021** (0.610) 1.033 (0.218) 5.398** (0.014) 0.016*** (0.018) 0.019*** (1.520) -1.841* (2.340) -1.890 (0.010) 0.012*** (0.002) Yes 2,228 (0.009) 0.024*** (0.007) Yes 921 (3.937) 0.248 (0.637) Yes 2,228 (2.387) -0.219 (1.647) Yes 921 (0.006) 0.010*** (0.001) Yes 2,228 (0.007) 0.025*** (0.004) Yes 921 (1.087) -0.460* (0.265) Yes 2,228 (1.190) -0.473 (0.889) Yes 921 17.16*** 0.17 92.42*** 0.62 30.70*** 0.39 6.94*** 0.14 21.88*** 0.22 69.96*** 0.60 7.06*** 0.04 14.81*** 0.23 Panel B: Market related (derivatives) off-balance sheet activities Charter × derivatives Asset quality × derivatives Intercept Year fixed effects Number of observation F-test Adjusted R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk Interest rate risk 19962006 (1) -0.187 (0.118) 0.035 20072010 (2) 0.094*** (0.030) 0.042 19962006 (3) -11.398*** (2.091) -26.528 20072010 (4) 12.130*** (2.875) 9.797 19962006 (5) 0.061 (0.042) 0.016 20072010 (6) 0.084*** (0.025) 0.071 19962006 (7) 16.588** (8.847) -11.134 Interest rate risk 20072010 (8) 5.718 (6.393) -3.529 (0.122) 0.013*** (0.003) Yes 2328 (0.178) 0.031*** (0.008) Yes 964 (53.762) -1.364* (0.819) Yes 2328 (12.586) 4.059*** (1.563) Yes 964 (0.048) 0.010*** (0.002) Yes 2328 (0.075) 0.021*** (0.005) Yes 964 (12.375) -0.378 (0.339) Yes 2328 (14.224) -0.794 (0.691) Yes 964 0.077 0.395 0.217 0.047 0.100 0.402 0.026 0.149 26 Table 6 Moderating effects- narrow period analysis The tables represent the results of the bank fixed-effects with year fixed effects estimates of equation (6). The dependent variable RISK is either total risk or idiosyncratic risk or systematic risk or interest rate risk. Total risk is the standard deviation of the bank’s weekly stock returns over a year (eq. 1). Idiosyncratic risk is calculated as the variance of εit in eq.(2). Systematic risk is the coefficient of Rmt, i.e. βm in the two-factor market model as represented by eq.(2). Interest rate risk is the coefficient of RIt, i.e. βI in the twofactor market model as represented by eq.(2). Standard errors are reported in parentheses. Superscripts*, **, *** indicate statistical significance at 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. Panel A: Traditional off-balance sheet activities Contingent × Tier1 Charter × Tier1 Asset quality × Tier1 Intercept Year fixed effects Number of observations F-test Adjusted R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk Interest rate risk 19962006 (1) 0.016 20072010 (2) -0.006 1996-2006 2007-2010 1996-2006 2007-2010 (3) -0.243 (4) 0.626** (5) 0.019 (6) -0.023 19962006 (7) 0.408 Interest rate risk 20072010 (8) 0.232 (0.039) 0.001 (0.033) -0.048 (0.313) 0.092** (0.299) 0.264** (0.025) 0.011 (0.020) -0.036 (0.857) -0.275 (4.122) -1.049 (0.046) 0.013 (0.135) 0.055** (0.046) 0.062 (0.115) 0.235 (0.033) 0.002 (0.084) 0.057** (0.219) 0.810 (0.925) 2.140 (0.022) 0.013** (0.003) Yes (0.025) 0.022 (0.016) Yes (0.251) 3.292* (1.766) Yes (0.325) 1.064 (3.081) Yes (0.015) 0.011** (0.004) Yes (0.028) 0.023** (0.010) Yes (1.448) -0.855 (0.665) Yes (4.033) -0.254 (0.306) Yes 2,228 921 2,228 921 2,228 921 2,228 921 16.24*** 0.16 86.31*** 0.60 31.96*** 0.39 6.00*** 0.13 20.05*** 0.22 70.92*** 0.58 6.77*** 0.04 13.75*** 0.23 Panel B: Market related (derivatives) off-balance sheet activities Derivatives× Tier1 Charter × Tier1 Asset quality × Tier1 Intercept Year fixed effects Number of observations F-test Adjusted R2 Total risk Total risk Systematic risk Systematic risk Idiosyncratic risk Idiosyncratic risk Interest rate risk 19962006 (1) -0.121 20072010 (2) -0.000 19962006 (3) -12.404*** 20072010 (4) -2.300 19962006 (5) 0.060 20072010 (6) -0.013 19962006 (7) 1.726*** Interest rate risk 20072010 (8) 0.702 (0.134) -0.028 (0.042) 0.007 (0.011) -0.100 (0.127) 0.087* (1.338) 5.344 (13.400) 11.209* (1.524) 0.575 (18.153) 9.209 (0.069) -0.021 (0.030) -0.009 (0.008) -0.069 (0.087) 0.070** (0.467) -7.180* (4.203) 0.053 (2.384) 7.756 (9.012) 0.065 (0.019) 0.011* (0.006) Yes 2,328 (0.046) 0.027* (0.015) Yes 964 (6.400) 0.343 (1.871) Yes 2,328 (7.567) 4.682** (2.243) Yes 964 (0.014) 0.007* (0.004) Yes 2,328 (0.028) 0.019** (0.010) Yes 964 (2.029) -1.139* (0.601) Yes 2,328 (3.718) -0.162 (1.116) Yes 964 0.076 0.395 0.207 0.045 0.101 0.401 0.027 0.147 27