Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 Exploring the Potentials of Optimum Currency Area and the Political Will of the Gulf Cooperation Council *Aljadani, A., *Mear, F. and *Raimi, L. Economic integration is a phenomenon that became highly pronounced in the second half of the twentieth century, as the attention of the global community shifted towards enhanced cultural, economic and political cooperation and the formation of regional and continental blocs. The prominent blocs include the North American free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the European Union (EU), the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS), the African Union (AU) and a host of others. The ripple effects of the realignment of economic interests with the formation of blocs propelled the Gulf States to establish the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC). The purpose of this paper is to explore the potential for an optimum currency area (OCA) and the readiness of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC). The authors adopt qualitative and quantitative research methods, sourcing the required information and data. The findings from the paper indicates that the GCC has fulfilled six out of eight prerequisite factors for an OCA, the only two remaining are policy integration and political factors, which greatly account for the delay in adopting a single currency union in the region. The implication of the paper is that the benefits of OCA outweigh its costs; a single currency union is an effective mechanism for unified central banking, robust monetary policy measures, stability of the exchange rate system and improved inflow of capital and labour among members; it is also a formidable political weapon for relating with the international community. JEL Codes: F, G, L, O Keywords: Optimum Currency Area, Gulf Cooperation Council, Political cooperation 1. Introduction Economic integration, regional cooperation and political integration are issues often discussed in economics, international relations and political science literature (AlSaud, 1997; Pinfari, 2009; Patrick, 2011; Wu, 2013). It is therefore a topical issue of discourse among scholars and policymakers in both theory and practice. With regards to the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) comprising of six Gulf States, there are several studies that analyzed the benefits and progress of the GCC bloc, but very few studies explored the potentials of an optimal currency area (OCA). Most empirical and theoretical works on OCA are from other parts of the world especially Europe, America and parts of Asia (see Ishiyama, 1975; Buiter, 2000; Mckinnon, 2004; De Grauwe and Mongelli, 2005; Dellas and Tavlas, 2009). This paper is therefore an attempt to fill the gap on GCC‘s economic integration and monetary cooperation in the Gulf region. Adoption of OCA could offer the region a strategic economic and political relevance among the developed nations, especially America, Britain and France (ABF), which could increase stability and peace in the Middle_________________________________________________________________ *Leicester Business School, Accounting and Finance Faculty of Business & Law, De Montfort University, The Gateway, LE3 0QQ, Leicester, United Kingdom, Email of lead author: aljad3ani@hotmail.com, T:00441162551551 F: 00441162577186 Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 East as it has done within the European Union. Opting for OCA would also allow for better understanding, information sharing, and policy harmonization on economic and security issues that increases social and national cohesion as well as increasing investment among the GCC member states. The research presented in this paper indicates a single currency and monetary policy among the GCC member states would enhance financial transactions across the region. Economic integration could be described as a phenomenon that became pronounced in the second half of the twentieth century, when the attention of the global community shifted towards enhanced cultural, economic and political blocs (Raimi and Mobolaji, 2008). The prominent continental blocs include the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the European Union (EU), the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS), the African Union (AU) and a host of others (Poldermans and Philippe, 2007; Raimi and Mobolaji, 2008). The ripple effects of the realignment of economic interests through the formation of blocs led to the call for the establishment of the Gulf Cooperation Council. This proactive call culminated in the formal establishment of the GCC in Abu Dhabi on 25 th May 1981 by six Gulf states, which are officially addressed as the Kingdom of Bahrain (Mamlakat al-Bahrayn), the State of Kuwait (Dawlat al-Kuwayt), the Sultanate of Oman (Saltanat Umān), the State of Qatar (Dawlat Qatar), the United Arab Emirates (Al-Imārāt al-‗Arabīyah al-Muttahidah) and the Kingdom of Saudi Arabia (Al-Mamlaka Al-Arabiyya Al-Saūdiyya). However, these six countries are popularly called Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar, Saudi Arabia and the United Arab Emirates (Al-Saud, 1997; Patrick, 2011). At the second meeting of the highest coordination organ of the GCC held in November 1981, the heads of the member states agreed and endorsed an ‗Economic Agreement (EA)‘ as a prelude to complete economic integration in the region (Laabas and Limam, 2002). From a historical viewpoint, Pinfari (2009:4) argues that two critical ideological issues precipitated the formation of the GCC as a weapon to avert threats and protect their mutual economic and political interests. The first issue was a geo-political concern regarding ―the regional ambitions of Iran and Iraq after they settled their dispute on the Shatt-el-Arab‖ and the second issue was fear of the spread of Iran‘s Islamic revolution to the region. To counter these political developments, six Gulf States drafted the GCC integration charter which was ratified by Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, Bahrain, Qatar, the United Arab Emirates and Oman. Similarly, Patrick (2011) notes that the GCC is a politically-motivated alliance of six states as a result of growing security threats in the region. On the strength of the foregoing, it could be argued that an economic integration may emerge naturally for mutually beneficial economic gains and may also emerge as a response to economic and political threats from other blocks or nations. This is not the normal argument; e.g. NATO has different membership to the EU. In the case of the GCC, the literature has established two undercurrents: the need for economic integration and the need for political self-preservation from powerful nations (Iran and Iraq) seen as threats in the region. The rationale for a genuine economic integration is encapsulated by Raimi and Mobolaji (2008:130-131) thus: Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 “The second half of the twentieth century witnesses a discernible shift in the economic and political equation of the world. Aptly speaking the century can be tagged as an age of integration. Countries are coming together all over the world in Europe, America, Asia and Africa with the idea of defending themselves economically and politically, against the incursions of other blocs into their areas, and to increase their influence in their own areas as well as outside it. For the last 50 years, countries in almost all parts of the globe have had one form of economic integration or the other. All nations in Latin and North America, Africa, Pacific, South East Asia and most European countries are members of different integrated organizations”. Furthermore, the history of the GCC as highlighted above indicates that the social, economic and political benefits of economic integration underpinned the aim and objective of the regional bloc. However, the social and economic interests weigh more than the political. Yet political, social and economic interests are inexorably linked. Economic integration has a sharp but reconcilable distinction from political integration. The following definitions from international relations literature provide clear explanation. According to Haas (1958), political integration connotes ―[the] process whereby political actors in several distinct national settings are persuaded to shift their loyalties, expectations, and political activities toward a new centre, whose institutions possess or demand jurisdiction over the pre-existing national states‖(Haas, 1958: 16). However, Haokip (2011) states that ―political integration is…the process of bringing together culturally and socially discrete groups into a single territorial unit and the establishment of a national identity, the problem of establishing national central authority over subordinate political units or regions which may or may not coincide with distinct cultural or social groups, the problem of linking government with the governed, the process in evolving a minimum value consensus necessary to maintain a social order‖ (p. 222). The debate has been at the centre of dicussions in most of the blocs that are developing internationally, for example the different views on Europe as to whether it is a political or economic union (Guigue A and Mear F, 2014 p33-34) From the two definitions, the aims and objectives of the GCC are now primarily economic; the political undercurrent only supported its formation several years back. The Economic Agreement Document (2001:1) states that the GCC emerged for the purpose of ―enhancing and strengthening economic ties among Member States, and harmonizing their economic, financial and monetary policies, their commercial and industrial legislation and customs laws.‖ The process of achieving the that aim entails: “Seeking to achieve advanced stages of economic integration that would lead to a Common Market and an Economic and Monetary Union among Member States according to a specific timetable, while enhancing market mechanisms and fostering the role of the private sector; and Desiring to enhance the economy of the GCC Member States in the light of recent global economic developments, which require further Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 integration among the Member States to strengthen their negotiating position and competitive capacity in international markets; and Responding to the aspirations and expectations of GCC citizens towards achieving Gulf citizenship, including equality of treatment in the exercise of their rights to movement, residence, work, investment, education, health and social services” (Economic Agreement, 2001:2) Another point supporting the fact that the GCC‘s bloc is an economic integration is that the member states already have well developed national identities and the loyalties of the citizens of these six countries are with their governments. Whereas, for political integration unification of all members into one entity is expected, the leaders of states pursuing a political integration must elicit the position of their citizen by referendum after which they could surrender their political structures and institutions for the formation of a new powerful nation (Haokip, 2011). This is not the rationale of the GCC as stated in the Economic Agreement quoted above. There is a spectrum as in Europe. The disagreements are concerning where the countries in Europe sit on the spectrum regarding political union. The objective of this paper is not to join the debates on the underlying political undercurrents of the GCC, but to examine the literature to explore the potentials of optimum currency area (OCA) as an economic integration template for strengthening the GCC. In accomplishing these tasks, the paper adopts qualitative and quantitative research methods, which relying on documentary sources as a research strategy. This approach entails sourcing numerical and numeric data from GCC documents, previous studies in journal articles and online sources. The analysis is done using content analysis and descriptive statistics. 2. Research questions The research questions that have arisen from the discourse above are: RQ1: What are the economic justifications for economic integration of the GCC? RQ2: What are the potentials for optimum currency area in the GCC? 3. Conceptual Issues There is need for clarity on the meaning of economic integration and its stages, as well as the benefits of economic integration in order to appreciate the potentials of block formation. Economic integration is broadly defined as the removal of all trade impediments between the participating nations, and establishment of cooperation and coordination between them (El-Agraa, 2001; AFRODAD, 2003; Patrick, 2011). Integration, whether economic, political or cultural is a sub-set of globalisation However, Mutasa (2003:2) defines economic integration as ―the unification of neighbouring states working within a framework to promote free movement of goods, services and factors of production and to co-ordinate and harmonize their policies. Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 This might involve convergence of trade, fiscal, debt management and monetary policies as a prelude to integration.‖ Similarly, Raimi and Mobolaji (2008) define economic integration as the coming together of countries for mutually beneficial purpose of defending the economic and political interests of their region from incursion by other regions/blocs thereby enhancing their region‘s influence relative to others. The working definition, applied in this paper, of economic integration is unification of economic imperatives by collaborating nations to allow for free entry of people, goods and services for mutually beneficial ends. The process of economic integration takes a very long time and requires caution; hence policymakers follow systematic stages in getting the intention of integration cemented. The AFRODAD Report (2003) identified five stages or taxonomies of economic integration. These are: free trade zone, custom union, common market, economic union and political union. The free trade zone is often the first and common stage of economic integration; it entails allowing unhindered trade and free movement of goods, services and factors among member states by removing trade barriers like border taxes and levies. The second stage is custom union, which allows free trade among members and maintains common external tariffs and other trade measures with non-member states outside the union. The third stage is a common market, where all member states allow ease of movement of capital and human resource as well as other factors' input, but each member country retains power over their monetary and fiscal policies. The fourth stage of economic integration is economic union, which demands more from member states. Essentially, economic union entails all the other stages in addition to common monetary policy, single currency, budgetary and fiscal policies as well as sociocultural policies that would boost the integration process. The peak of integration that most nations have avoided is political union, which demands from member states the unification of member nations‘ political institutions, governmental organs and apparatuses under a common central body, which provides direction to all member nations and is normally federal systems. From the viewpoint of the GCC charter economic integration is understood as meaning an economic relationship among member states built and nurtured on the principles of coordination, integration and interdependence (Al-Saud, 1997). For the avoidance of doubt, Article 4 of the Charter states the aims and objectives of the GCC as follows: 1. To effect coordination, integration and inter-connection between Member States in all fields in order to achieve unity between them. 2. To deepen and strengthen relations, links and areas of cooperation between their peoples in various fields. 3. To formulate similar regulations in various fields including the following: a. Economic and financial affairs. b. Commerce, customs and communications. c. Education and culture. 4. To stimulate scientific and technological progress in the fields of industry, mining, agriculture, water and animal resources. 5. To establish scientific research. Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 6. To establish joint ventures and encourage cooperation by the private sector for the good of their peoples (Cooperation Council for the Arab States of the Gulf, 2012). Al-Saud (1997:23) summarizes the aims and objectives of the GCC charter as ―the necessity of coordination between different administrative systems within the GCC countries and the promotion of cooperation between the member States in different fields to achieve a comprehensive economic unity through progressive steps that would unify regulations in economic, financial, custom commercial, cultural, legislative, information, and social fields.‖ Another review of the GCC charter by Patrick (2011) established that at the formation stage, the GCC was clearly declared as an alliance among the six Gulf nations on the basis of economic cooperation and collaboration, hence the highest decision-making body was named the ‗cooperative council‘ (or Majlis Al-Ta‘wuun). Also, the charter states that the basis of relationship is premised on three tenets, namely: (a) coordination (tashseeq), (b) integration (takamal) and (c) interdependence (tarabit). The three tenets of the charter are applicable only to ―economic and financial affairs; commerce, customs and communications; and education and culture‖ (p.2). The position of this paper therefore is that the GCC is primarily an economic union formed for multidimensional benefits of the member states but which may also include political and military cooperation without prejudice to the sovereignty and political autonomy of the members. From the foregoing conceptual discourse, one of the benefits of such economic integration in theory and practice is the creation of a collaborative mechanism for enhancing the potentials of member states and capacities for improving wellbeing of citizens, tackling poverty and indebtedness. Besides, it fosters accelerated development among member states based on mutual cooperation and support. It also allows for openness and wider trade relations among member states and their citizens. The openness often covers traveling visas, transportation and other immigration-related issues (GCC, 2012). Furthermore, economic integration allows for effective utilisation of surpluses and deficits among member nations. A labourabundant nation would explore factors of free movement for transfer of its excess labour to a labour-deficient nation, and the same principle applies to a capitalabundant situation (Raimi and Mobolaji, 2008). Integration allows for common regulations on economic, industrial and financial matters which would strengthen economic activities of all the member states. Economic integration accommodates political issues in the form of informal cooperation on matters of internal security, defence, peace-keeping and a common voice on global issues at the General Assembly of the United Nations, the UN Security Council and similar international summits. 4. Theoretical Framework Theory provides grounding that shapes the direction of academic enquiry and the basis for testing tentative propositions. The theory that provides foundation for this paper is the optimum currency area (OCA). It is appropriate to mention that Milton Friedman‘s work in the early 1950s articulated the significance of monetary integration, a view that predates the OCA (Dellas and Tavlas, 2009). However, the literature gives credit and accolades for developing the OCA theoretical construct to Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 the Nobel Prize winner in Economics, Robert A. Mundell (Coy, 1999). He proposed the idea in the 1960s for nations that coexist within the same geographical area to come together and enhance the economic potentials by adopting a single currency, rather than a proliferation of currencies. Other scholars argue that the credit for conceptualisation, development and articulation of OCA is to be shared by three Economists, namely: Mundell (1961), McKinnon (1963) and Kenen (1969) for their ground-breaking work at different times (Bayoumi and Eichengreen 1997; Dellas and Tavlas, 2009). With regards to the relevance of the theory to international economics, there are two conflicting viewpoints. Krugman (1993) asserts that the OCA is highly beneficial and should serve as the basis for international monetary economics. In opposition however, Coy (1999) and Buiter (2000) argue that OCA is one of the defective theories that emerged in the field of monetary economics after World War II; and that the OCA proponents placed too much emphasis on the supply side of economics which has had a devastating effect on the European Union as evidenced by the Greek debt crisis. The theory of OCA could simply be summarized as an academic debate over the superiority of a fixed exchange rate and a floating exchange rate within a region with many countries (Ishiyama, 1975). Mongelli (2008:2) defines an OCA ―as the optimal geographical area for a single currency, or for several currencies, whose exchange rates are irrevocably pegged. The single currency, or the pegged currencies, fluctuate jointly vis-à-vis other currencies.‖ Another definition of an OCA is a region or continental area which allows usage of a single currency for maximum economic efficiency and political leverage above other regions outside the OCA (Mundell, 1961; Coy, 1999). Quite similarly, Frankel and Rose (1996:14) define an OCA as ―a region for which it is optimal to have its own currency and its own monetary policy.‖ Laabas and Limam (2002) while in agreement with previous definitions add that OCA refers to an area or region that agrees to form a common monetary and currency union for mutual benefits with several implications for the governance and the economic structures of the member states. These implications include: Monetary integration which presupposes one single currency and a coordinating central bank with power over monetary policy measures on liquidity, inflation, foreign exchange reserves and interest rates; or Fixed exchange rates meaning convertibility of member states' currencies with non-members; and Financial market integration which entails openness and free inflow of capital transactions and centralized financial regulations. The various definitions above align with the view of the proponent Mundell (1961). According to Coy (1999), Mundell‘s OCA can be adopted only for regions or areas with similar economies which allow for embedment of a single monetary policy. There are two forms of currency area: (a) a currency area with several countries with their respective national currencies (Model A); and (b) a currency area with many countries with a single currency (Model B) (Mundell, 1961). He justified preference for the latter (that is, Model B) on the grounds that: ―In a currency area comprising different countries with national currencies the pace of employment in deficit countries is set by the willingness of surplus countries to inflate. But in a currency area comprising many regions and a single currency, the pace of inflation is set by Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 the willingness of central authorities to allow unemployment in deficit regions (Mundell, 1961:658). To summarize, a single currency area must have a single central bank (or all central banks in the region surrender to the monetary policy measures of the coordinating central bank within the currency area like the EU model). This arrangement allows for a single body looking at the whole currency area in decision-making, implementation and evaluation. As laudable as the OCA sounds in theory, there are costs and benefits associated with it during implementation. The benefits of OCA are essentially the benefits of economic integration discussed under the conceptual issues. On the cost of OCA, Laabas and Limam (2002) note that the main demerit is the loss of autonomy on monetary policy and regional currency. The first example is the European Union member state nations that adopted the Euro as a single currency and implemented the monetary policy measures of the European Central Bank; it became a cost because of the arrangements to ―create disincentives for individual governments to properly tackle fiscal and structural policies as well as to safeguard financial stability‖ in their respective nations (Cour-Thimann and Winkler (2013:2) whilst the Growth and Stability pact attempted to reduce this disincentive its failures resulted in the Treaty on Stability, Co-ordination and Governance to be enacted in 2013 which gave power to the European Commission to enforce fiscal rules on member states. The second classic example of loss of autonomy over currency and monetary policy is the case of Central Africa, where six nations Cameroon, Gabon, Congo, Equatorial Guinea, the Central African Republic and Chad under the Communaute Economique et Monetaire de l'Afrique Centrale (CEMAC) agreed to a single currency called Franc CFA ―with a fixed exchange rate of FCFA 656: 1 Euro‖ with effect from January 1, 2002 (AFRODAD, 2003:8). Furthermore on the disadvantages of OCA, Mckinnon (2004) contends: ―The major cost associated with monetary integration arises from the abandonment of an independent monetary policy. By fixing its exchange rate to other members of the monetary union, a country joining a union automatically gives up control over its own monetary policy. When its economy is subject to an external shock, it has no choice but to follow the common monetary policy of the monetary union. Countries with similar economic structures can respond to a common shock with a common monetary policy, and the costs of giving up an independent monetary policy are relatively small. In contrast, countries with heterogeneous economic structures require different policy responses to common shocks, and the costs of sharing a common monetary policy are relatively large. For example, Japan and Korea, both oil importers, can respond to a surge in oil prices with the same monetary policy. This, however, would not apply to Japan and Indonesia, where the latter is an oil exporter …p.694. In spite of the ideas contained in OCA, Mckinnon (2004) criticizes the theory on the ground that the lead proponent Mundell was inconsistent and self-contradictory in two of his works. For tackling economic shocks, he proposed a smaller and homogeneous currency area which allows for exchange rate flexibility in his 1961 treatise. However in a later work in 1973, he proposed a larger and heterogeneous Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 currency area which allows for upholding asset-holding for international risk-sharing. The adoption of OCA by the European Union was described as the bane of its economic crisis, which rather than fostering economic prosperity became an economic trap leaving Europe with squabbling nations (Krugman, 2012). Despite the criticisms launched against the two versions of OCA, the GCC accepted the conclusion that economic integration through the adoption monetary union is desirable because its benefits outweigh the few inconvenient costs (Mongelli, 2008). The GCC Document (2013) states: ―Introducing the GCC single currency and establishing the GCC Monetary Union… will increase the advantages of the economic integration and enhance the gains of the Customs Union and the GCC Common Market… the GCC single currency will have many impacts on the various economic sectors, particularly Intra-GCC Trade, tourism and investment… financial services and capital markets [thereby] increasing growth and accelerated developments…. the GGC single currency eliminates the risks related to the exchange rates of the GCC currencies, deepens the concept of the common market…contributes to the development and integration of the GCC capital markets, particularly the securities market, helps improve the stock market and considerably influences it in terms of volume, depth and liquidity‖ (Impacts of Introducing the GCC Single Currency, paragraph 1, 2013). 5. Prerequisite factors for applicability of OCA The viability of formation of a monetary union and the application of OCA, are based on critical conditions otherwise called prerequisites, criteria or characteristics in the literature on exchange rate regimes. These prerequisites are eight in all (Mongelli, 2008). Other studies like Jadresic (2002), Abed, Erbas and Guerami (2003), AlJasser and Al-Hamidy (2003), Maames (2003), Sturm and Siegfried (2005), Krueger and Kovarich (2006), Hebous (2006) and Hanna (2006) uphold these perquisites in their various works on OCA. The eight (8) prerequisites of OCA have been identified by Laabas and Limam (2002) and Mongelli, (2008) as: (i) openness,(ii) factor mobility, (iii) degree of commodity diversification, (iv) similarity of production structure, (v) price and wage flexibility, (vi) similarity of inflation rates, (vii) degree of policy integration and (viii) political factors. Detailed explanations of these eight factors are given below. a) Degree of Economic Openness: This factor explains the degree to which an economy is open to international trade. A large country has greater potential to survive international trade and exchange rate instability than a small country. It is therefore desirable for smaller countries to join a monetary union to enjoy openness and still be protected against trade fluctuations and shocks (Ishiyama, 1975; Laabas and Limam, 2002). b) Factor Mobility: This presupposes that a country which allows free movement of factors of production within and outside its economy will do better that a rigid counterpart. Factor mobility allows for self-adjustment between nations within a monetary union; a nation with labour abundance will offset this with another nation with labour deficiency and ditto for capital inflow and outflow (Raimi and Mobolaji, 2008). Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 c) Degree of Commodity Diversification: The more diversified the economies within a region, the more effective the result of entering a monetary union because they would be protected from external shocks. Consequently, the adjustment of exchange rates to correct the shocks would be unnecessary (Mongelli, 2008). In other words, diversified countries are those fitted for monetary and currency union (Laabas and Limam, 2002). d) Similarity of Production Structure: In OCA theory, it is observed that economies with homogeneous or similar production structure, when faced with external shocks from international trade are more likely to share the same experiences (that is, they are symmetric), which presupposes that these countries are not likely to adjust their exchange rate to mitigate the shocks. Economies with these characteristics are suitable for monetary union and a single currency (Laabas and Limam, 2002; Mongelli, 2008). e) Price and Wage Flexibility: Countries desiring OCA require flexible nominal prices and wages within the currency union and respective countries. These conditions enhance response to market shocks that could likely cause unemployment in one member nation and inflation in another and would therefore not require the exchange rate as an adjustment mechanism (Laabas and Limam, 2002; Mongelli, 2008). f) Similarity of Inflation Rates: Like symmetric production structures, countries with similar inflation trends or rates are more likely to utilise similar monetary and fiscal measures to correct their inflationary challenges. Besides, lower or similar inflation rates in these economies countries would fairly stabilize the terms of trade over time. Thus, it would be in their interests to embrace monetary union with a single currency and centralized economic policies (Fleming 1971; Laabas and Limam, 2002). g) Degree of Policy Integration: The willingness of members and positive attitudes toward unified fiscal policies and other commercial policies is a precondition for a currency union (Laabas and Limam, 2002). This condition allows for better risk-sharing among member states in a monetary union when shocks occur (Mongelli, 2008). h) Political Factors: In both political and economic literature on integration, the precondition for its adoption and effectiveness is the political will. For a monetary union adopting a single currency and economic policies, the willingness by political actors is crucial and important (Mintz, 1970; Laabas and Limam, 2002). The political factor cannot be downplayed because ―political will fosters compliance with joint commitments, sustains cooperation on various economic policies, and encourages more institutional linkages‖ (Mongelli, 2008:3). Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 6. Methods and Materials As mentioned at the outset, this research is exploratory. It explores the literature on economic integration with a view to unveiling the potential for OCA in the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) learning from the Crisis of the European Union. The required data was extracted from secondary data collected from the GCC headquarters. The data was analysed using content analysis and descriptive statistics were used to explain the potential for OCA following the approach of Laabas and Limam (2002). The present study with data covering 2003-2012 fills the gap by updating previous studies which utilised data from 1989-1998. There has been remarkable progression of the GCC towards a single currency since 1998. A new study is desirable. The preferred measurements of the eight (8) OCA prerequisites as used in the data analysis are: A. Degree of openness (DOP): This is measured by the ratio of trade to the Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which is calculated as: Openness = exports + imports of goods)/GDP}*100 (AlKholifey and Alreshan 2010). B. Degree of factor mobility (DFM): This is measured by capital inflows and the movement of labour across GCC member countries. However, we used only capital inflow within the GCC member countries. C. Degree of commodity diversification (DCD): This is measured as a ratio of oil sector to non-oil sector (production/exports) across the member states. D. Similarity of production structure (SPS): This is measured looking at average sector-by-sector contributions to GDP across the member states. E. Price and Wage Flexibility (PWF): This is measured using the average of prices and wages overtime in the member states. F. Similarity of inflation rates (SIR): This is measured as the average of inflation rates overtime in the member states. G. Degree of policy integration (DPI): This is qualitatively measured as the extent of commonality in fiscal, economic and social policies among the member states. H. Political factors (PFs): This is qualitatively measured as the attitudes of political actors to compliance with the economic policies of the GCC. 7. Outcomes/Findings and Discussion A. On the Degree of Openness, the ratio of trade to GDP indicates that GCC member states are open to one another as well as to the rest of the world as evidenced by the rising openness ratio in Table 1 below (AlKholifey and Alreshan 2010). Table 1: Degree of Openness in GCC (1998 - 2011)Million Dollar Saudi Kuwait Qatar Bahrain Arabia Average 1998 – 2011 81.46 89.15 89.67 150.65 Oman United Arab Emirates 85.41 128.83 UNCTAD (2011) B. On the Degree of Factor Mobility, the average capital inflows across the GCC member countries measured in terms of Total Trade Exchange in Table 2 confirm a high level of factor mobility, although the degrees of factor mobility Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 differ. Across the GCC member countries For Saudi Arabia the average capital inflow is $319,756.33 (highest), while Kuwait, Qatar,, Bahrain, Oman and UAE have $71,128.44m, $35,822.80m, $26.468.23m, $43,867.02m and $234,294.1m respectively. Table 2: Degree of factor mobility in GCC: Total Trade Exchange (2005 - 2010) Million Dollar Total Trade Exchange 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Average Index 2005 - 2010 Saudi Arabia Kuwait Qatar Bahrain Oman United Arab Emirates 240,034.7 280,731.3 323,330 428,595 287,842 358,005 58,515.2 65,204 89,983 56,614 85,326 35,822.8 50,491.9 67,822 95,131 72,861 98,087 19,632.3 24,165.1 26,910 35,971 23,129 29,002 27,516.3 32,482.8 40,678 60,644 45,505 56,376 153,403 183,336.6 224,394 316,906 247,680 280,045 319,756.33 71,128.44 35,822.80 26,468.23 43,867.02 234,294.1 GCC STATE BULL 2009-12012 C. Regarding the degree of commodity diversification, the findings as shown in Table 3 indicate that the oil sector dominates and the non-oil sector only provides marginal contribution. The countries are not diversified; they therefore suit a currency union for better economic diversification on the basis of the theory of comparative cost advantage. Table 3: Degree of commodity diversification in GCC (1998 - 2010) Ratio of Oil/NonOil=DCD Saudi Arabia Kuwait Qatar Bahrain Oman United Arab Emirates Average Index (1998-2010) 5.62 5.54 1.64 2.83 2.89 2.73 GCC STATE BULL 2002-12012 D. On the similarity of production structures, the findings as reflected in Table 4 indicate all the GCC member nations have similar production structures. The dominant sectors of their economies are agriculture, mining & quarrying (petroleum), electricity, construction, wholesale/retail/hotels/restaurants, transportation/communication, finance & insurance services and real estate services. They functionally have strong oil sectors, while other sectors are complementary. Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 Table 4: Similarity of Production Structure in GCC (1998 - 2010) Common Sectors=SPS 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. 8. 9. Agriculture & Fishing Mining & Quarrying (Petroleum) Manufacturing Electricity, Gas & Water Construction Wholesale & Retail, Hotels & Restaurants Transport, Commun. & Storage Finance & Insurance Services Real Estate Services Saudi Arabia Kuwait Qatar Bahrain Oman United Arab Emirates 9334.34 193.76 80.3708 62.3423 492.567 2771.86 168795.8 36680.96 26299.63 3237.182 14322.37 48182.31 27717.33 2541.5 4581.011 881.52 4494.638 475.4023 1781.932 179.3115 3075.205 357.9292 16213.25 2884.408 14308.23 1421.399 2887.885 560.0008 1305.297 13550.21 16704.04 3686.084 2994.17 1348.583 3379.035 19436.23 10492.81 4757.415 1875.842 871.7515 1937.125 11214.66 11580.27 7517.929 4716.662 2811.605 1254.814 9343.202 12792.83 4392.258 1350.223 1037.576 1507.647 11018.47 GCC STATE BULL 2002-2012 E. With regards to findings on the average price and wage flexibility, Table 5 indicates that the prices and wage rates across the GCC member states show similarity in terms of trends and rates. This is an indication that prices and wage rates in the region justify monetary union. Four nations (Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, Bahrain and Oman) have very close symmetry with regards to price and wage rates (110%, 119%, 108% and 112% respectively), while the two others (Qatar and UAE) have higher rates of 136% and 135% respectively. By-and-large, it could be concluded that there is a justification for monetary union for effective price and wage flexibility allowing mobility to the higher inflation areas. Table 5: Price and Wage Flexibility in GCC (2001 - 2011) General Consumer Price Index (Base year 2000 = 100) Average Index (20012011) Saudi Arabia Kuwait Qatar Bahrain Oman United Arab Emirates 110.65 119.35 136.82 108.52 112.99 135.29 Consumer Price Index in GCC States, 2012 F. Findings on the similarity of inflations rate as shown in Table 6 below, show that average inflation rates across GCC range 1.28% to 4.34%. On a countryby-country basis, Saudi Arabia has an average inflation rate of 2.32%, Kuwait 3.33%, Qatar 4.34% (highest in the region), Bahrain 1.28% (lowest in the region), Oman 2.56% and UAE 4.12%. Against the backdrop of the average inflation rate index, it could be concluded that the GCC nations do not have similarity in their inflations rates; rather there is divergence, given the UAE have decided not to pursue currency union, in the rest of the region however over the past 3 years the economies appear to be have converged with the Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 exception of Qatar and Bahrain. Given their relative economic this would not be problematic economically. Table 6: Similarity of inflation rates in GCC (1998 - 2012) Annual percentages of end of period consumer prices are year-on-year changes Trade in Inflation Rates Saudi Arabia Kuwait Qatar Bahrai n Oman -0.174 1.197 2.481 -0.838 0.47 -1.208 3.746 1.486 -0.997 -0.345 -1.503 0.428 1.679 -0.952 -1.02 -0.814 2.886 1.436 -0.837 -0.588 0.821 -0.254 0.244 0.589 -0.167 0.509 0.874 2.263 1.966 0.335 0.607 2.599 6.797 2.435 1.434 1.107 4.455 8.814 2.326 2.654 2.786 3.638 11.828 1.077 4.272 6.002 7.539 13.764 4.001 8.287 9.498 9.025 15.049 5.122 11.78 4.003 1.18 -4.865 1.554 0.923 5.774 4.496 0.402 0.99 4.192 3.64 4.905 1.923 0.178 3.292 3.738 3.199 1.856 2.58 2.881 Average Index 1998 – 2012 2.32 3.33 4.34 1.28 2.56 International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database, October 2013 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 United Arab Emirate s 2.048 1.72 2.079 2.86 3.02 4.095 5.633 7.787 10.247 11.719 6.597 1.217 0.876 0.769 1.072 4.12 G. The findings on the degree of policy integration as earlier discussed are a qualitative factor. Reviews of member states‘ acceptance of recommendations on fiscal, commercial, security and social policies are relatively positive and encouraging. The GCC official statement on level of policy integration reads: “The Ministerial Council perused the report of the Ministerial Committee concerned with the follow-up on the decisions pertaining to the joint process, and expressed satisfaction at the progress made with regard to implementing the decisions of the joint process, and looked forward to the implementation of the remaining decisions in this connection… The Supreme Council examined the progress report in the area of the Customs Union, the GCC Common Market, the Monetary Union, and the infrastructure integration projects in the GCC States, the most important among them being the electricity grid project, and the feasibility study for the GCC railways. The Supreme Council expressed satisfaction at the achievements made and issued directives pertaining to them” (Final Communiqué of the 30th Session, 2009: paragraph. 18-19). H. The findings on Political factors like degree of policy integration are largely a policy issue that cannot be measured quantitatively. The low political will of the GCC nations explains the reason for delay in the implementation of a single currency for years. Lack of political will largely explains the prolonged delay in starting the single currency project despite over 15 years discussion Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 on the issue. At one stage in 2006, Oman dropped the idea and the UAE followed in 2009, a decision linked to the relocation of the monetary council to Saudi Arabia. Kuwait still prefers pegging its currency to the U.S. dollar, in order to limit the impact of a repeat of crash of dollar from the experience of the financial crisis. By-and-large, there is mutual suspicion and fear of domination by some elements especially Saudi Arabia in the GCC (Lohade, 2013). ―Although economic integration in the Gulf has progressed, much still needs to be done to establish a legal framework and strengthen institutions that would be needed to manage a single currency across the countries that remain committed to the idea‖ (paragraph 8). 8. Conclusion/Recommendations The implication of this paper is that the benefits a single currency union is a viable option and there is an effective mechanism for a unified central bank, robust monetary policy measures, stability of the exchange rate system and improved inflow of capital and labour among the members. It is also a formidable political weapon for relating with the international community. Based on the present strengths and observed weaknesses in the implementation of a common currency, the following recommendations are necessary to forestall a repeat of the European Union crisis in the GCC monetary union. i. As an initial stage in economic integration there is a need for the implementation of a free trade area agreement for the free movement of goods and other factors, thereby promoting more intra-regional trade. ii. In order to better manage macro-economic fundamentals, the GCC countries need to create a central organization that could eventually be the basis to form a central bank like the European Central Bank, which would formulate and implement monetary policy measures for the region. Other supra-national institutions for coordination of fiscal policy measures are similarly necessary. iii. Several studies identified high structural convergence in production structure, low factor mobility and lack of price and wage flexibility in the GCC countries. For a beneficial monetary union, it is suggested that sound policies be formulated and implemented to promote structural diversification, more factor mobility and price wage flexibility as part of the GCC move towards greater integration. Finally and most importantly, genuine political will is a fundamental precondition for monetary union. This requires that the governments of the member nations surrender to the supra-national political institutions of the GCC including a central bank to coordinate their activities. iv. Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 REFERENCES AlKholifey, A., & Alreshan, A. (2010). GCC monetary union. IFC Bulletin No,32, 1751. African Forum and Network on Debt and Development (2003) Regional Integration and Debt in Central Africa. Research Report, AFRODA, Harare, Zimbabwe. Available: http://opendocs.ids.ac.uk/opendocs/bitstream/handle/123456789/1673/AFRODAD248340.pdf?sequence=1(Accessed: 1 March, 2014) Baldwin, R. and Wyplosz, C. (2004) The Economics of European Integration. New York: McGraw Hill. Bayoumi, T., Eichengreen, B. (1997) Ever closer to heaven? An optimum-currencyarea index for European countries. European Economic Review 41, 761–770. Buiter, W.H. (2000) Optimal currency areas: why does the exchange rate regime matter? With an application to UK membership in EMU. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 47 (3), 213–250. Cooperation Council for the Arab States of the Gulf (2012) The Charter: Article 4. Available: http://www.gcc-sg.org/eng/indexfc7a.html?action=Sec- Show&ID=1(Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Cour-Thimann, P. and Winkler, B. (2013) The ECB‘s non-standard monetary policy measures the role of institutional factors and financial structure. Working Paper Series, NO 1528 /April. http://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1528.pdf Available: 9Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Coy, P. (1999) Why Mundell Won the Nobel: For work that led to the Euro, not for his supply-side theory. Business Week Online October 25 Issue. Available: Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 http://www.businessweek.com/1999/99_43/b3652085.htm (Accessed: 27 February, 2014). De Grauwe, P., Mongelli, F.P., 2005. Endogeneities of Optimum Currency Areas: What Brings Countries Sharing a Single Currency Closer Together? European Central Bank Working Paper Series no. 468. Dellas, H. and Tavlas, G. S. (2009) An Optimum-Currency-Area Odyssey. Bank of Greece. Economic Research Department – Special Studies Division, Athens. Available: http://www.bankofgreece.gr/bogekdoseis/paper2009102.pdf (Accessed: 26 February, 2014). Economic Agreement Document (2001) The Economic Agreement Between the GCC States Adopted by the GCC Supreme Council (22nd Session; 31 December 2001) in the City of Muscat, Sultanate of Oman. The GCC Secretariat General, Riyal, KSA. Available: file:///C:/Documents%20and%20Settings/p11039237/My%20Documents/Downlo ads/1274258747%20(1).pdf. Frankel, J. A. and Rose, A. K. (1997). The Endogenity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria". The Economic Journal, Vol. 108 (449), pp. 1009–1025. GCC Document (2013) The Monetary Union and the Single Currency: Concept and Outset. Available:http://www.gcc-sg.org/eng/indexeeff.html?action=Sec-Show&ID=58 (Accessed: 2 March, 2014). Guigue A and Mear F (2014) A critical debate on the budgetary Framework of the United Kingdom, Europe‘s Golden Rule of Public Finances: Its impact on National Budget systems, Acts of the International Symposium 27-28th March 2014 under Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 the patronage of the French High Council of Public Finances, Gestion & Public Finances. Haas, E. B. (1958) The Uniting of Europe: Political, Social and Economic Forces, Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. Haokip, T. (2011) Theoretical Considerations of Political Integration and the Indian Experience. IJSAS, Vol. 4(1), pp.221-234. Available: https://www.academia.edu/1558681/Theoretical_Considerations_of_Political_Integration _and_the_Indian_Experience (Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Ishiyama, Y. (1975) The theory of optimum currency areas: a survey. IMF Staff Papers no. 22, 344–383. Kouparitsas, M. A. (2001) Is the United States an optimum currency area? An empirical analysis of regional business cycles. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper. 2001-21. Krugman, P. (2012) Revenge of the Optimum Currency Area. Presentation at NBER Macroeconomics Annual conference, The Opinion Pages, June 23 Edition. Available: http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2012/06/24/revenge-of-the-optimum- currency-area/?_php=true&_type=blogs&_r=0 (Accessed: 2 March, 2014). Laabas, B. and Limam, I. (2002) Are GCC Countries Ready for Currency Union? Research Paper, Arab Planning Institute, Kuwait. Available: http://www.mafhoum.com/press4/120E15.pdf (Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Lohade, N. (2013) Gulf Common Currency Chatter Returns Again. The Wall Street Journal (WSJ), December 3 Edition. Available:http://blogs.wsj.com/middleeast/2013/12/03/gulfcommon-currency-chatter-returns-again/ (Accessed: 2 March, 2014). Mckinnon, R. I. (2004) Optimum Currency Areas and Key Currencies: Mundell I versus Mundell II. JCMS Vol. 42(4), pp. 689–715. Available Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 https://notendur.hi.is/ajonsson/kennsla_2012/Mundel1versusMundel2.pdf (Accessed: 27 February, 2014). Mongelli, F. P. (2008) European Economic and Monetary Integration, and the Optimum Currency Area Theory. Economic Papers, European Commission, Brussels. Available: http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/publications/publication12081_en.pdf (Accessed: 2 March, 2014). Mundell, R. A. (1961) A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas. American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (4), pp. 657–665. Mutasa, C. (2003) Regional Integration and Debt in Africa: A Comparative Report of Africa‘s Regional Groupings. AFRODAD Research Series Patrick, N. (2011) The GCC: Gulf State Integration or Leadership Cooperation? Research Paper, Kuwait Programme on Development, Governance and Globalisation in the Gulf States. Kuwait Programme on Development, Governance and Globalisation in the Gulf States, No. 19. Available:http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/55660/1/__lse.ac.uk_storage_LIBRARY_Secondary_lib file_shared_repository_Content_Kuwait%20Programme_Partrick%202011%20paper.pdf (Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Pinfari, M. (2009) Nothing but failure? The Arab League and the Gulf Cooperation Council as Mediators in Middle Eastern Conflicts. Working Paper no. 45, Regional and Global Axes of Conflict, London School of Economics and Political Science. Available: http://www.lse.ac.uk/internationalDevelopment/research/crisisStates/download/wp/wpSer ies2/WP452.pdf (Accessed: 29 February, 2014). Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 Poldermans, R. and Philippe, Jean-Marc (2007) Study On The Integration Of The Financial Sector In The Ecowas Region ‗Supporting The Dialogue & Moving Forward‘. Final Report of Business Climate (BIZCLIM), Project No. 2007-140425. Availabel:http://acpbusinessclimate.org/pseef/documents/final/ecowas_finance_e n.pdf (Accessed: 6 February, 2014). Raimi, L. and Mobolaji, H. I. (2008) Imperative of economic integration among Muslim countries: Lessons from European globalisation", Humanomics, Vol. 24(2), pp. 130 – 144. Ricci, L. A. (2008) A Model of an Optimum Currency Area. Economics: the OpenAccess, Open-Assessment E-Journal Vol. 2 (8), pp. 1–31. Scitovsky, T. (1984) Lerner's Contribution to Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 22 (4), pp.1547–1571. Sturm, M. and Siegfried, N. (2005) Regional Monetary Integration In The Member States Of The Gulf Cooperation Council. Occasional Paper Series, No. 31, European Central Bank. Available: https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/pdf/scpops/ecbocp31.pdf (Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Takagi, S. (2012) Establishing Monetary Union in the Gulf Cooperation Council: What Lessons for Regional Cooperation? ADBI Working Paper 390. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute. Available: http://www.adbi.org/working- paper/2012/10/19/5268.monetary.union.gulf.cooperation.council/ (Accessed: 1 March, 2014). Weiner, M. (1965) Political Integration and Political Development. Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 358, pp. 52-64. Wu, X. (2013) How the Newly-built State transformed the old society? ——The Mechanical Political Integration Policy and its Impacts in Mainland China, 1949-1958. Journal of Proceedings of 4th European Business Research Conference 9 - 10 April 2015, Imperial College, London, UK, ISBN: 978-1-922069-72-6 Cambridge Studies, Vol. 8(1), pp.73-84. Available: http://journal.acs- cam.org.uk/data/archive/2013/201301-article5.pdf (Accessed: 1 March, 2014)