Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 Relationship between Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness: A Direct Test Jeong-Ho, Koo* and Tae-Young, Paik** Many research works have shown the downward stickiness of costs with decreased sales. The cost stickiness could result from managers’ decisions for their own interests, the agency problem. This study showed directly the association between the agency problem and the cost stickiness whereas the previous works did indirectly. It developed the estimation model for the normal SG&A amounts based on the firm- and industry-specific determinants. The abnormal (excess) SG&A amounts are taken as proxies for agency problem. It was found that the bigger this measure of the agency problem was, the stickier costs were. It was also shown that in the firms of major corporate groups presumed with less serious agency problem due to tight control systems, the association between agency costs and cost stickiness diminished. The association got weaker in the firms with bigger ownership shares of large shareholders and with hence stronger influence of large shareholders, too. I. Introduction The earlier works have shown that the cost stickiness, the inelastic cost change with the sales reduction is caused by the balancing of the resource adjusting costs and the idle resource carrying costs. Other later studies indirectly documented that the asymmetric cost behavior might result from the managers’ self-interest seeking, too. We show directly the relationship between the managers’ opportunistic behavior and the cost stickiness. Managers of firms as agents of their owners are supposed to make decisions maximizing their firm profits and values. Managers, however, might have incentives to expand their operations too much for their own interests, reputation, and power. It has been shown that these opportunistic behaviors got bigger with higher growth rates and higher surplus cash flow of firms (Jensen and Meckling 1976; Jensen 1986, 1988; Rechardson 2006). Chen et al (2008) showed that costs got stickier as the managers’ self-interests in empire-building or so were bigger. These results imply that the agency problem causes cost stickiness. The previous studies used as proxies for measures of agency problem, ownership share of managements and the ratio of SG&A expenses on sales. The ownership share of managements represents the degree of separation between owners and management and hence is used as proxy for agency problem. Excessive SG&A expenses might be caused by wasteful spending for management perquisites. SG&A expenses consist of major discretionary expenditures of R&D, advertising, promotion, training, and executive compensations. It is, however, not easy to judge the excessiveness of the SG&A expenses without a proper benchmark. *Assistant Professor. Jeong-Ho, Koo, Department of Business Administration, Kumoh National Institute of Technology, Korea. Email : jhk2001@kumoh.ac.kr ** Professor, Tae-Young, Paik, Department of Business Administration, Sungkunkwan University, Korea. Email : typaik@skku.edu. 1 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 We develop the benchmark to separate the normal amount and abnormal (excess) amount of SG&A expenses for each sample. We then use the abnormal SG&A amounts as a proxy for agency problem and show directly the association between this proxy and cost stickiness. The normal SG&A amount of a firm may depend on its firm-specific factors like sales, firm size, debt ratio, growth, and profitability. It is also affected by industry-specific factors such as industry size, entry barrier, and degree of competition. This paper first shows that the abnormal SG&A expenses are positively related to the cost stickiness measure of Homburg and Nasev(2008). It next shows that the abnormal SG&A expenses in the firms of the big 30 company groups in Korea are not positively related to these cost stickiness measures, implying that the cost stickiness of those firms presumably with well designed monitoring systems does not result from agency problem. It finally shows that the positive association between the abnormal SG&A and the cost stickiness is stronger in firms with small ownership shares of large shareholders than those of large shares. It implies that the cost stickiness of firms with stronger influence of large shareholders is caused less by agency problem. The main contribution of this paper is to derive as a proxy of agency problem, the measure of abnormal SG&A expenses, controlling their firmand industry-specific determinants, and to show its positive association with direct measures of cost stickiness. The remainder of this paper is organized into five sections. Section II outlines the prior research and our hypothesis. Section III describes our empirical design for analysis. Section IV reports our results and Section V concludes with comments on limitations. II. Prior Research and Hypothesis Recent research works point the agency problem as a cause of cost stickiness (Anderson et al. 2003; Chen et al 2007; Jung 2007; Koo 2011a, 2011b). They said that when firm sales go down, their managers do not actively cut their costs down for their own interests, not for their firms’ interests. The pioneering paper in cost stickiness, Anderson et al. (2003) stated without tests that managers may retain unutilized resources to avoid personal consequences of retrenchment, such as loss of status when a division is downsized or the anguish of dismissing familiar employees, contributing to sticky cost behavior. Chen et al. (2008) conjectured that managers’ empire-building incentives contribute to the asymmetrical behavior of SG&A costs. They showed that strong corporate governance mitigates asymmetric SG&A cost adjustment. Jung(2007) examined the effect of large shareholders ownership on the cost stickiness and found that the larger their ownership is, the weaker the cost stickiness is. Koo(2011b) found that firms reporting different levels of profits(losses) have different incentive for earnings management and their incentives influence cost behaviors. Firms reporting report small earnings and believed to have upward earnings management incentives show relatively weaker cost stickiness. On the other hand, costs reduction rates of firms reporting large profits were smaller when sales decline. It implies that managers with large incomes do not cut costs enough in order to smooth earning by reducing earning fluctuation with sales reduction. Finally, costs of firms with relatively large losses are very sticky, implying that managers in large loss 2 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 firms are taking big-baths instead of saving costs for future performance. This paper measures directly the agency problem with the abnormal SG&A expenses while previous research works did not use direct measures of agency problem. This work then shows the positive association between the direct measure of agency costs and recently developed direct measures of cost stickiness. The hypothesis to test is as follows: Hypothesis: The bigger the agency problem is, the stickier the SG&A expenses are. III. Research Design 3.1 Proxy for Cost Stickiness This paper uses the direct measures of cost stickiness in Weiss(2010) and Homburg and Nasev(2008). In Anderson et al. (2003) and its expansion papers, firm level cost stickiness could not be measured directly, limiting follow-up research. Weiss(2010) came up with a firm level measure of cost stickiness and it is defined as an estimated difference between the rate of cost decrease for recent quarters with decreasing sales and the corresponding rate of cost increase for recent quarters with increasing sales, STICKY : ……………….. (1) – where is the most recent of the last four quarters with a decrease in sales and is the most recent of the last four quarters with an increase in sales, ΔSALEit = SALEit − SALEi,t−1 and ΔCOSTit = COSTit − COSTi,t−1 . STICKY is defined as the difference in the cost function slope between the two most recent quarters from quarter t−3 through quarter t, such that sales decrease in one quarter and increase in the other. If costs are sticky, meaning that they increase more when activity rises than they decrease when activity falls by an equivalent amount, then the proposed measure has a negative value. A lower value of STICKY expresses more sticky cost behavior. That is, a negative (positive) value of STICKY indicates that managers are less (more) inclined to respond to sales drops by reducing costs than they are to increase costs when sales rise. We define our first measure of cost stickiness STICKY1 = - STICKY to avoid the confusion in the direction. Now bigger STICKY1 means stronger stickiness. Following Anderson and Lanen(2007), those samples with the opposite directions of changes in sales and costs are excluded. Homburg and Nasev(2008) measure cost stickiness as the SG&A ratio increase conditional on decreasing sales and increasing SG&A costs ratio on sales: STICKY 2 it = ΔCostRatioit · DSaleit · DCostRatioit ……………….. (2) where ΔCostRatioit = [ 𝑜𝑠 𝑎𝑙𝑒 ] [ 𝑜𝑠 𝑎𝑙𝑒 3 ] −1 ………………………… (3) Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 DSaleit = 1 DCostRatio it = 1 if Saleit < Saleit-1 , if ΔCostRatioit > 0 , 0 otherwise 0 otherwise When sales go down, stickier costs go down much less than in proportion, making STICKY 2 bigger. We use both STICKY 1 and 2 as proxies for cost stickiness at firm level. 3.2 Proxy for Agency Problem Prior works used the ratio of SG&A expenses on sales as a proxy for agency costs since SG&A expenses have a large portion of discretionary expenditures which might be over-spent due to agency costs (Singh and Davison III 2003). However, SG&A expenses depend not only on sales and other firm-specific characteristics such as firm size, growth rate, debt ratio, and profitability, but also on industryspecific ones such as industry size, degree of competition, and entry barrier (Choi 1994; Park and Paik 2006; Hong 2010; Bhagat and Welch 1995; Karuna 2007). Based on prior works on SG&A determinants, we derive a model for the normal level of SG&A expenses to compute the abnormal SG&A amounts as a proxy for agency costs. First, sales in current and previous periods are primary firm-specific determinants. Second, high debt ratio represents the financial pressure through high interest expenses for SG&A saving. Third, growing firms might spend more SG&A expenses to keep up with the growth rate. The growth rate of total assets is used. Fourth, profitable firms are willing to spend more SG&A expenses for future benefits. SG&A spending is expensed, not capitalized in conservative accounting. But we all know discretionary expenditures like R&D, advertisements, and training costs provide economic (not accounting) intangible assets for future. Return on assets is used. Fifth, firm size is included for potential omitted variables. The first industry-specific determinant to consider is market size. Firms with big markets might spend SG&A more to capture a big pie of the market. On the other hand, firms with big markets might spend less, believing they can achieve the target sales without lots of SG&A expenses. Market size is measured by taking log on the sum of all the firm sales in an industry. Second, higher competition may require high SG&A spending. The degree of existing competition in industries is measured by the number of firms in an industry (Bova and Pereira 2008). Firms with fewer than four competing firms are excluded in the sample. Third, high entry barrier means low potential competition in the future and leads to saved SG&A expenses. Degree of entry barrier is measured by the average tangible assets size of firms in an industry weighted with their sales (Karuma 2007). The abnormal SG&A as a proxy for agency cost (AC) is the residual of the following SG&A estimation model : log(COST) it = a + b1 log(SALES)it + b2 log(SALES)it-1 + b3 log(SIZE) it + b4 ROA it + b5 LEV it + b6 GROWTH it + b7 MKSIZE it + b8 EB + b10YD + AC it …………. (4) 4 it + b9 COMPTit Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 where COST it : SG&A of firm i, year t SALES it : Sales of firm i, year t SIZE it ROA it LEV it : Beginning balance of Total Assets of firm i, year t : Return of Assets of firm i, year t : Total Liabilities / Total Assets of firm i, year t GROWTH it : Growth rate of Total Assets of firm i, year t MKSIZE it : Market Size, log (sum of firm sales in the industry) of firm i, year t EB it : Entry Barrier, weighted average of Tangible Assets in the industry of firm i, year t COMPTit : Competition, the number of firms in the industry of firm i, year t YD : Year Dummy 3.3 Empirical Model and Sample The model for association between agency cost and cost stickiness is as follows: STICKY 1 (or 2)it = b0 + b1 AC it + b2 AST it + b3 PST it + b4 EST it + Ɛ it ---------(5) where STICKY 1(or 2) it : Cost Stickiness of firm i, year t AC it : Agency Costs of firm i, year t AST it : Asset Intensity, log(Total Assets / Sales) of firm i, year t PST it : Tangible Assets Intensity, log(Total Tangible Assets / Sales) of firm i, year t EST it : Employee Intensity, log(Number of employees / Sales) of firm i, year t The dependent variable is either STICKY 1 developed in Weiss(2010) or STICKY 2 in Homburg and Nasev(2008). The control variables are intensities of total assets, intangible assets, and employee against sales, which are found to be related to cost stickiness in prior works. The samples consist of publicly listed non-financial companies data from 2004 to 20071 satisfying the following requirements : 1) SG&A expenses are less than sales 2) Data are available in KIS VALUE II. Total 1,170 firm-year data are used in this paper 1 Year 2004 is the earliest year with quarterly financial data and year 2007 is the last year before the recent financial crisis. 5 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 IV. Results 4.1 Descriptive Statistics <Table 1> shows the descriptive statistics of main variables. The mean of AC is 0.025 and its median is 0.035. The mean and median of STICKY 1 are 0.265 and 0.304 respectively. The mean of STICKY 2 is 0.006. The large shareholders share is on average 35% and has median of 34%. <Table 2> reports the correlation coefficients of main variables. The agency costs proxy AC has positive correlation with STICKY 2. Multicollinearity between variable is not a problem having VIF(variance inflation factor) less than 10. <Table 1> Descriptive Statistics Variables Mean Std Deviation Median Min Max AC 0.025 0.474 0.035 -1.715 2.048 STICKY1 0.265 2.314 0.304 -8.829 13.392 STICKY2 0.006 0.046 0 0 1.048 log(SIZE) 26.243 1.385 26.002 23.118 31.411 LEV 0.447 0.199 0.457 0.02 1.407 GROWTH 0.098 0.393 0.054 -0.875 9.816 ROA 0.087 1.503 0.04 -4.626 49.495 35.306 18.455 33.87 0 100 AST 0.134 0.637 0.069 -2.285 5.405 PST -1.226 1.081 -1.108 -7.427 4.468 EST -20.071 0.919 -19.94 -25.759 -14.65 SALES 973,160,910 3,442,328,900 1,838,130,000 778,594 57,632,359,000 SG&A 104,810,911 459,971,323 219,884,000 344,461 9,239,745,000 Large Shareholders(%) <Table 2> Pearson Correlation Coefficients AC STICKY1 STICKY2 AST STICKY1 0.01 STICKY2 0.108*** -0.005 AST 0.003 -0.054* 0.342*** PST 0.031 -0.005 0.130*** 0.571*** EST 0.179*** 0.026 0.212*** 0.417*** 6 PST 0.414*** Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 4.2 Test Results 4.2.1 Main Results <Table 3> shows the results of SG&A estimation. As current and past sales, firm size, growth rate, and industry competition are bigger, the SG&A expenses get bigger as expected. As leverage and entry barrier are bigger, the SG&A expenses get smaller as expected. The profitability measured by ROA was an insignificant determinant. The market size showed negative influence on SG&A amounts. <Table 3> SG&A Estimation Results Coeff. t-value Intercept 6.371*** 13.69 Sales t 0.662*** 13.01 Sales t-1 0.102** 2.13 SIZE 0.259*** 8.89 LEV -0.274*** -3.44 GROWTH 0.096*** 2.95 ROA -0.018 -0.82 MKSize -0.218*** -13.59 EB -0.106*** -3.84 Compt 0.01*** 7.28 Adj. R2 0.757 **, *** Significant at the 5 percent and 1 percent levels, respectively. <Table 4> shows the results on the association between the agency problem and cost stickiness. AC has the positive relationship with STICKY 2, not with STICKY 1, partly supporting H1. 7 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 <Table 4> Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness : full sample STICKY 1(or 2)i,t = b0 + b1ACi,t + b2 ASTi,t + b3PSTi,t + b4ESTi,t + εi,t STICKY1 STICKY2 coeff. t-value coeff. t-value Intercept -2.743* -1.62 0.086*** 2.73 AC -0.099 -0.68 0.010*** 3.83 AST -0.330** -2.47 0.027*** 11.04 PST 0.05 0.63 -0.005*** -3.67 EST 0.145** 1.7 0.004*** 2.81 Adj. R2 0.036 0.141 N 1,170 1,170 *, **, *** Significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. 4.2.2 Additional Tests Since the Asian financial crisis in 1990’s, major corporate groups in Korea like Samsung and Hyundai Motors have improved their accounting transparency, internal control systems, governance structures, hence mitigating agency problems. Koo(2011a) showed that firms in major corporate groups have less severe cost stickiness. To see the interactive effect of corporate groups on the cost stickiness, we add a dummy variable, BSIZE for firm membership. BSIZE is 1 if the firm belongs to the top 30 corporate groups announced by the Korea Fair Trade Commission and 0 otherwise. <Table 5> shows that the positive association between the agency problem measure AC and cost stickiness measure STICKY 2 disappears in the member firms of major groups since the coefficients of AC and AC*BSIZE are the same (0.014) with the opposite signs. 8 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 <Table 5> Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness: major corporate groups STICKY 1(or 2)i,t = b0 + b1ACi,t + b2 AC*BSIZEi,t + b3 ASTi,t + b4PSTi,t + b5ESTi,t + εi,t STICKY1 STICKY2 Coeff t-value Coeff t-value Intercept 2.653 1.56 0.079** 2.52 AC -0.051 -0.3 0.014*** 4.46 AC*BSIZE -0.194 -0.58 -0.014** -2.26 AST -0.332** -2.49 0.027*** 11 PST 0.055 0.7 -0.005*** -3.38 EST 0.140* 1.64 0.004*** 2.57 Adj. R2 0.024 0.144 N 1,170 1,170 *, **, *** Significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. As the ownership share of large shareholders in a firm increases, they might exercise stronger influence on their management, reducing agency problem in the firm. To test this possibility, we separated the samples into the two groups of high large shareholders’ ownership shares and low ones. <Table 6> and <Table 7> report the regression results for the low and high share groups, respectively. The low share group has the bigger significant coefficient for AC against STICKY 2 than the high one, implying the controlling effect of large shareholders on agency problem. <Table 6> Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness: low share group of large shareholders STICKY1 STICKY2 Coeff Intercept t-value 0.852 0.36 Coeff 0.165 t-value *** 2.87 ** 2.03 AC -0.071 -0.32 0.011 AST -0.334* -1.76 0.035*** 7.55 PST 0.039 0.32 -0.009*** -3.18 0.41 *** 2.97 EST Adj. R N 0.048 2 0.009 0.061 0.145 548 548 *, **, *** Significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. 9 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 <Table 7> Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness: high share group of large shareholders STICKY1 STICKY2 Coeff t-value Coeff t-value Intercept 4.659* 1.91 0.014 0.53 AC -0.116 -0.59 0.008*** 3.83 AST -0.330* -1.74 0.020*** 9.93 PST 0.042 0.4 -0.002* -1.87 EST 0.243** 1.98 0.001 0.51 Adj. R2 0.024 0.187 N 622 622 *, **, *** Significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. We could not find any significant result on STICKY 1, the measure in Weiss(2010) above. Noticing firms reporting incomes close 0 have strong incentive for earnings management, we used a dummy variable EM for firms with ROA (net incomes over beginning total assets) between 0 and 0.01. To capture the strong effect of AC, we used for test the subsample group with high agency problem, positive AC (excessive SG&A). <Table 8> shows the test results on the association between the agency problem and cost stickiness in this subgroup with EM included. Interestingly, AC has the positive relationship with STICKY 1 in the firms with their incomes slightly greater than 0 but the negative relationship in other firms. <Table 8> Agency Problem and Cost Stickiness : excessive SG&A sample STICKY 1(or 2)i,t = b0 + b1ACi,t + b2 AC*EMi,t + b3 ASTi,t + b4PSTi,t + b5ESTi,t + εi,t STICKY1 STICKY2 Coeff t-value Coeff t-value Intercept -0.439 -0.18 0.093 1.71 AC -0.612** -2.03 0.025*** 3.64 AC*EM 1.731** 1.99 -0.016 -0.84 AST -0.324 -1.73 0.046*** 10.89 PST -0.068 -0.59 -0.009*** -3.45 EST -0.02 -0.16 0.005 1.98 2 Adj. R 0.09 0.205 N 620 620 *, **, *** Significant at the 10 percent, 5 percent, and 1 percent levels, respectively. - EM: 1 if firms with ROA (net income over beginning total assets) between 0 and 0.01 and 0 otherwise 10 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 V. Conclusions This study derived the benchmark to separate the normal amount and abnormal (excess) amount of SG&A expenses for each sample. Using the abnormal SG&A amounts as a proxy for agency problem, it showed directly the association between this proxy and cost stickiness. The normal SG&A amounts of a firm are found to depend on its firm-specific factors like sales, firm size, debt ratio, and growth. They were also determined by industry-specific factors such as industry size, entry barrier, and degree of competition. It was first shown that the abnormal SG&A expenses are positively related to the cost stickiness measure of Homburg and Nasev(2008), not to that of Weiss(2010). It was next shown that the abnormal SG&A expenses in the firms of large corporate groups are not positively related to the cost stickiness measure of Homburg and Nasev(2008) and Weiss(2010). This implies that the cost stickiness of these firms presumably with well designed monitoring systems does not result from agency problem. It was finally shown that the positive association between the abnormal SG&A and the cost stickiness is stronger in firms with small ownership shares of large shareholders than that of large shares. It implies that the cost stickiness of firms under high influence of large shareholders is caused less by agency problem. The main contribution of this paper is to derive as a proxy of agency problem, the measure of abnormal SG&A expenses, controlling their firm- and industry-specific determinants, and to show its positive association with direct measures of cost stickiness. There are several limitations in the paper. First, we could not find consistent results with the two direct measures of cost stickiness in previous works. These two measures do not seem to be correlated to each other. Second, the factors determining SG&A expenses should be further analyzed to develop a better estimation model. Third, the extended control variables for cost stickiness might be needed for future studies. References Anderson, M. C., R. D. Banker, and S. N. Janakiraman. 2003. Are Selling, General, and Administrative Costs 'Sticky'? Journal of Accounting Research 41(1), 4763. Anderson, S. and W. Lanen, 2007. Understanding Cost Management : What can we learn from the evidence on 'sticky costs'? Working Paper, Univ. of Melbourne. Bhagat. S and I. Welch. 1995. Corporate Research & Development Investment International Comparison. Journal of Accounting and Economics 19, 443-470. Bova. F and R. Pereira. 2008. The determinants and consequences of heterogeneous IFRS compliance levels following mandatory IFRS adoption : evidence from a developing country. Working Paper. Chen C. H, H. Lu, and T. Sougiannis. 2008. Managerial Empire Building, Corporate Governance, and the Asymmetrical Behavior of Selling, General, and Administrative Costs. Working paper. 11 Proceedings of 29th International Business Research Conference 24 - 25 November 2014, Novotel Hotel Sydney Central, Sydney, Australia, ISBN: 978-1-922069-64-1 Choi, J. 1994. The Effect of Advertising and Research and Development Expenditures on the Firm Value: An Empirical Analysis by Tobin's Q. Korean Accounting Review 19(1), 103-124 Homburg, C and J. Nasev. 2008. How Timely are Earnings when Costs are Sticky? : Implication for link between conditional conservatism and cost stickiness. Working Paper. Univ. of Cologne. Hong, C. 2010. The Effect of Industry-level Factors on SG&A Costs. Korean Accounting Review 35(4), 133-162 Jensen, M. 1986. Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. American Economic Review 76(2), 323-329. ------ 1988. "Takeovers: Their Causes and Consequences,”" Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, 21~48. Jensen, M., and W., Meckling. 1976. Theory of the Firms: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3(4), 305360. Jung, H. 2007. Determinants of Asymmetrical Behavior of Manufacturing Costs: Korean Evidence. Accounting Information Review 25(3), 1-28 Karuna, C. 2007. Industry Product Market Competition and Managerial Incentives. Journal of Accounting and Economics 43, 275-297. Koo, J. 2011a. The Effect of Corporate Governance on the Asymmetric Cost Behavior: focusing on mangers` ownership, foreign investor`s ownership and institutional investor`s ownership, Korean Journal of Management Accounting Research 11(1), 1-35 Koo, J. 2011b. The Effect of Earnings Management Incentives on the Asymmetric Cost Behavior: Focusing on loss avoiding, income smoothing and big-bath. Korean Accounting Review 36(3) 135-177. Park, J. and T. Paik. 2006. Trend and Determinants of Discretionary Expenditures. Korean Journal of Management Accounting Research 6(2), 33-57 Richardson, S. 2006. Over-investment of Free Cash Flow. Review of Accounting Studies. Vol 11(2-3), 159-189. Singh, M and W. Davison III. 2003. Agency Cost, Ownership Structures and Corporate Governance Mechanisms. Journal of Banking and Finance 27, 793816. Weiss, D. 2010. Cost Behavior and Analysts' Earnings Forecasts. The Accounting Review 85(4), 1441-1471. 12