lteea &cUa#t~ i Warm ;Via/ Seminar Conducted b y WATER RESOURCES RESEARCH .INSTITUTE Oregon State Universit y 786 8 Fall Quarter 1979 GOVERNING BOAR D PETER C . KLINGEMAN, Directo r FRED J . BURGESS, Dean, School of Engineerin g CARL H . STOLTENBERG, Dean, School of Forestry JOHN R . DAVIS, Director, Agricultural Experiment Statio n KEITH W . MUCKLESTON ROBERT BESCHTA LARRY BOERSMA MARSHALL ENGLIS H KENNETH CUMMIN S R . CHARLES VARS, JR . On June 6, 1978, President Carter announced a broad set o f water policy initiatives to bring about "reforms" in four key areas : federal-state cooperation, water planning processes, water conservation, and increased environmental sensitivity . Task forces are working on specific implementation efforts . A year later, in June o f 1979, the western governors met and passed several resolutions opposing some aspects of the federal policies announced thus far . The governors criticized Carter's plans for cost-sharing by the states in all future water developments . The federal proposal ask s that states pick up 5% of the cost of non-revenue producing projects . Opposition was also expressed to the Administration's proposed cuts i n the federal snow survey program --- to be phased out by 1983 . Viewe d with suspicion is the attempt "to impose federal controls over wate r conservation practices" inasmuch as this is deemed "a prerogative o f the states" . The question of federal water rights is an area in whic h many uncertainties need to be resolved . Still undecided is the futur e of such national organizations as the Water Resources Council . To examine some of the factors involved, a seminar serie s was held during Fall Quarter at Oregon State University . The weekl y presentations were open to faculty, students of all ages, and th e general public . Peter C . Klingema n Directo r Corvallis, Orego n January 198 0 f= unds for this publication were provided by the Office o f Water Research and Technology, U .S . Department of the Interior, unde r the provisions of the Water Research and Development Act of 1973 . %e 90tateeate' The Water Resources Research' In•St i'tu-te,, located-' o n the Oregon State University Campus, serves the State• of Oregon . The Institute fosters, encourages- and faci'l'i•ta-tes• water resource s research and education involving all aspects of the quality an d quantity of water available for- beneficial use .. The Institu=t e administers and coordinates statewide and regional' programs of multidisciplinary research in water and related land resources . The Institute provides a necessary communications and coordination link between the agencies of local, state and federa l government, as well as the private sector, and the broad researc h community at universities in the state on matters of water-relate d research . The Institute also administers and coordinates th e interdisciplinary graduate education in water resources of Orego n State University . This seminar series is one of the activities regularl y undertaken by the Institute to bring toge har the- research community, the practicing water resource specialists, students of al l ages and interests, and the general public, in order to- focu s attention upon current issues facing' our state . efed FEDERAL/STATE WATER POLICY ISSUE S Thomas E . Klin e Oregon Water ' Resources Departmen t Salem, Oregon 1 WATER AND PUBLIC CONTRO L James Huffma n Northwestern School of La w Lewis and Clark College Portland, Oregon . :. . ., ; . . .; 3 , A, ; POLICIES AND AQUATIC ECOSYSTEMS Lou Fred d Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlif e Portland, Oregon 15 WATER RESOURCES AND LAND USE PLANi'IN G Anne Squie r Land Conservation and Development Commissio n Salem, Oregon 21 ENERGY AND WATER POLICY IN THE COLUMBIA RLVE R Zane R . Harpe r Bonneville Power Administratio n Portland, Oregon 31 Presented October 11, 1979 by THOMAS E . KLINE, Oregon Water Resources Department , Salem, Oregon . 9edelai/ Stag ?Oatet Pedec~y Tweed the While spectrum subject of federal and state water policies encompasses a of concerns on the use, development and management of water , there appears to be some inherent commonality between the various issues . Water policy issues tend to be controversial, perhaps reflecting the divers e interests of society that are directly or indirectly affected by water decisions . Secondly, water policy issues generally tend to involve political solutions . Finally, perspectives on the issues tend to change with time . Thus, the trus t of the water policies of the past may be viewed by some with skepticism today . Historically, federal water policies have tended to be project oriented, reflecting national interest in navigation, flood control and reclamation . As that interest expanded over the years, encompassing hydroelectri c development, recreation, municipal water supplies and water quality, polic y objectives have become less clear . Against this background, President Carter introduced a range of wate r policy initiatives in 1977 . The proposals addressed seven major areas : wate r resource planning and evaluation criteria and procedures, cost sharing, institutions and institutional arrangements, conservation, water resource research , federal reserved rights, and water quality . Perhaps not unexpectedly, th e initiatives prompted immediate and sharp criticism from many sectors and i n particular, from the western states . While, with the appointment of numerous task forces to more full y develop the proposals the process became more obtuse, several consistent theme s appear to be emerging . In particular, the level of federal participation i n water development appears to be decreasing . This is reflected in proposal s aimed at increasing user changes and requirements for state and local participation in federal water projects, and, potentially, for investigations and dat a acquisition . Emphasis on conservation and non-structural measures appears t o further support a program of reduced federal funding for water development , 1 at least in the immediate future . Collectively these measures and the othe r proposals, if implemented, will alter the traditional federal role in wate r resources . It is perhaps important to note that proposed policy initiate s thus far do not appear to be tied to national energy concerns . The apparent uncertainty over the future federal role in wate r resources has carried over to states . In some recent instances litigatio n has been employed to more clearly define the respective roles . On the positiv e side, this period may provide opportunities and possibly an incentive fo r development and implementation of local and state initiatives in water resources . In Oregon, policies affecting water are formulated by a number o f agencies, boards and commissions . Their respective responsibilities cove r almost all aspects of water and its present and future use within the state . Within Oregon, water is a seasonally and annually variable resourc e with a disparate distribution across the state . In most areas only a smal l percentage of the annual surface runoff is available during the summer months , usually associated with peak demands . The two-thirds of the state constitutin g eastern Oregon receives only one-sixth of the total state runoff . The challenge facing Oregon is clearly to develop policies an d management programs that reflect the extent and availability of the resourc e in the context of increasing demands for virtually all uses . Emerging issue s involve coordination between land use, water quality and water quantity planning , increasing demands for community, municipal and agricultural supplies, renewe d interest in hydroelectric power development, instream flows and means o f achieving desirable objectives, the efficiency of current water use, the rol e of the state in water resource development and an entire spectrum of concern s on ground water resources . Perhaps on the basis of a false sense of abundance , little emphasis has been placed on water resources in recent years within th e state . Factors already in place will likely force a dramatic change in tha t outlook in the future . (This is a summary of the remarks presented . ) 2 Presented October 18, 1979 by JAMES HUFFMAN, Director Natural Resources La w Institute, The Lewis and Clark Law School, Portland, Oregon . Warm awl Pat.& eaata~ Private water rights in the western United States are cause for a goo d fight . Tales of water related disputes between farmer and ranche r are as much a part of the lore of western history as is the six-gun . Hollywoo d has probably exaggerated the six-gun legend, but not the history of fighting word s and conflict that were the public side of the development of the law of privat e rights in water . Liberties may have been taken with the facts of particula r disputes, but the importance of water to western development could not have bee n overstated . In 1900, even as recently as 1960, the water lawyer was an expert i n private law . Actions in water courts were disputes between private parties . They were traditional property law cases, distinct only in the nature of th e property at issue and the branch of property law to which th.e lawyers and judge s must refer . The classic cases of western water law ; cases like Irwin v . Phillips , Coffin v . Left Hand Ditch Co ., and Tattersfield v . Putnam ; were all dispute s between private parties over title to water . The state's role in these case s was as interpreter and enforcer of existing private rights . The state was no t an independently interested party . Water would be allocated between the disputants according to the law of private rights in water . This resolutio n would conform to and encourage reliance upon private expectations founded in th e relevant water law . PUBLIC POLICY CONSIDERATION S This does not mean that the water law was devoid of any conten t relevant to public policy . The commitment to a system of private rights i n water was itself an affirmation of a public policy favoring the market allocation of water resources . Several specific attributes of private water right s reflected identifiable public policy . It has long been the rule that th e waste of water is not a beneficial use, a rule which seeks to maximize th e amount of water available for productive use . However, the application of th e rule is based upon a reasonablenessstandardin which reasonableness is define d in terms consistent with a market approach to water allocation . Water user s 3 " . . . cannot be expected to install methods now that might reduce to a minimu m the amount of water necessary, at a cost that would absorb the profits ." Th e rule of beneficial use itself has obvious policy objectives . Public policy reflected in particular aspects of private water right s appears directed either at the correction of market failure or at the alteratio n of efficient, but for some reason undersirable, market allocations . An exampl e of the latter is the rule favoring domestic over all other water uses . I f applied as a true preference, this rule allocates water in a time of scarcit y on the basis of the nature of the use rather than the priority date of th e right . If reflects a preference for survival of the water poor over th e economic or aesthetic welfare of others . Transfer Right s Water rights attributes which appear to have the purpose of correcting for market failures include those affecting transfer and loss of rights . Restraints on transferability reflect the inability of all affected right s holders to be represented, as they must be, in a transaction leading to a chang e in the nature of use, place of use, or point of diversion of a particular wate r right . The institutionalization of a transfer approval process presumabl y lowers transaction costs and allows most affected rights holders to be represented . The transferability restraint, in other words, is an attempt to facilitate market exchange by reducing prohibitive transaction costs . Transfe r limitations may also reflect a public policy favoring a particular water use , or may be the inheritances of a riparian rights system in which water and lan d were appurtenant by definition . A discussion of the policy content of the rules of water right s ownership could go on, but for present purposes it will be sufficient to recognize that, whatever the wisdom and logic of these policy contributions to th e law of private rights in water, the system of water allocation within eac h western state was predominantly a market system . The state layed down som e policy relevant ground rules, was a commitment to private decision making i n water allocation . The big political issues of water allocation in the first five or si x decades of the twentieth century were not over water allocation in an economi c sense, they were over how the water management authority was to be exercised i n a federal system . To be sure these were disputes over the best uses of water , but to some degree the water use issue served as a vehicle to pursue the wate r management authority issues, perhaps in anticipation of impending scarcities wit h which government at some level sould be expected to deal . States argued wit h the federal government over the extent of federal constitutional powers in wate r regulation . States argued with each other over the control of water withi n their geographic boundaries . States argued internally over control of thei r own waters . Through it all, however, the private water rights owner was no t seriously challenged . The commitment to market allocation of water appeare d secure . 4 Intervention in Market Plac e In 1927, the United States Supreme Court upheld, in Euclid v . Amble r the authority of a state to zone land in the interests of promoting th e Realty, public health and welfare . In 1973, the Supreme Court of Wisconsin upheld th e application of a wetlands regulation law which effectively deprived the owne r of affected lands of the economic value of his private property . The now pervasive system of land use planning and zoning is dependent upon the rational e of the Ambler Realty decision, if not the extreme consequences of the Wisconsi n ruling . It is a rationale based upon the belief or assumption that privat e decision making in land allocation will lead to a less than socially optima l utilization of land . It further assumes that these market failures will not b e corrected through improvement of the private rights system itself . The conclusion, evidenced by the growing network of land use regulations at both th e state and federal level, is that the public interest will be achieved throug h direct intervention in the market place to the extent that clearly define d vested rights in land are changed without any form of compensation to th e affected party . The water rights compartment of America property law has no t experienced anything analogous to "the quiet revolution in land use control" . Whatever the states may do to influence initial water rights definition, an d whatever they may do to jockey for position in the federal system, the state s have seldom if ever seen fit to alter in any meaningful way existing, veste d rights in water . The remainder of this paper examines the issues of the stat e role in water allocation in the context of two very different approaches b y Montana and Colorado to the specific problem of water allocation to instrea m flows . This rather narrow focus will help to illuminate the much broader issu e of the appropriate regulatory role for the state . In the process, it may als o be possible to better understand the stark contrast between agressive stat e regulation of private rights in land and an apparent reticence to affec t private rights in water . PUBLIC INTEREST IN WATER ALLOCATIO N Historically, water rights in the West have been limited to traditional "economic" uses like mining, agriculture and industry . In 1913 th e Eighth Circuit Court of Appeals of the United States rejected a private clai m under Colorado law based upon a resort's interest in preserving the natura l beauty of a waterfall . "It may be," wrote the court, "that if the attentio n of the lawmakers had been directed to such natural objects of great beaut y they would have sought to preserve them, but we think the dominant idea wa s utility, liberally and not narrowly regarded, and we are constrained to follo w it ." Not until 1973, a full six decades later, was the attention of th e Colorado lawmakers directed to the preservation of water values not include d in this "liberally regarded" notion of utility . In that year the Colorad o legislature broadened its definition of beneficial use to include minimum flo w preservation on natural streams and lakes . But even then, the state did no t seek to impose minimum flows upon private water rights owners the way land us e laws had imposed limitations on private land holders . The 1973 Colorado la w merely authorized the state to establish minimum flows by competing in th e market place on an equal basis with all others desiring water for beneficia l uses . 5 Before examining the Colorado situation in greater depth, a brie f consideration of public interests in water allocation will be instructive . Minimum stream flow maintenance is just one example, and a very good one fo r the purposes of this paper, of a potential water use which is unlikely to b e realized in a system of exclusive market allocation . Even absent rulings suc h as that in the Federal Circuit Court decision mentioned above, the allocatio n of water to non-consumptive, instream uses such as recreation, fish habita t protection, and aesthetic enjoyment is not likely to occur on any significan t scale in a market system of private transactions . The reasons are those whic h provide the classic justifications for government intervention in the marke t place . Aesthetics and Recreatio n The benefits of aesthetic and recreational use of natural water courses are generally realized in relatively small amounts by numerous an d diverse members of society . The transaction costs, including organizationa l costs, will more often than not prevent those interests from competing in th e market place . In addition, the nature of most aesthetic and recreational use s in such that benefits take the form of public goods . Even if private interest s could raise the necessary capital to purchase a water right for an aesthetic o r recreational purpose, they would have difficulty controlling the consumptio n of benefits and therefore difficulty in realizing a return on their investment . As with other types of public goods, free riders would realize significan t external benefits, with a resulting under-investment in aesthetic and recreational water uses . The physical characteristics of the water resource are the principl e cause of market failure in water allocation . Water in natural watercourses ha s the character of a common pool resource . It cannot be fenced in the way tha t land is . It is difficult to define exclusive rights in water . The earl y Anglo-American legal response to the ownership or right of use of water wa s the common property system of riparian rights . It is a system which suffer s from the allocational deficiencies of all common property systems . The costs o f enforcing individual rights in a common property system are increasingly prohibitive as the number of correlative rights holders becomes large . Th e result is the allocation of significant resources to enforcement and an accompanying under-investment in the development or preservation of the resourc e commonly held . Appropriation Syste m The Western response to these shortcomings of the riparian right s system was the existing system of appropriative rights which creates exclusiv e rights not by subdivision of the resource, but by a system of temporal priority . The system has been reasonably successful in creating for rights holders a meaningful level of certainty with respect to water quantity . However, th e appropriation system is not free from market failure . The inability of numerou s and disparate consumers of small, yet real, benefits to compete in the marke t because of high transaction costs may be justification for government intervention . Secondly, the exclusivity which appropriative rights owners have wit h respect to water quantity does not exist with respect to water quality . Significant external costs in the form of pollution result from private use o f 6 water . With respect to water quality, it would stretch reality to contend tha t even a primitive common property system exists . Thus, the factors which justify public intervention in a riparian system of water rights, a 'he equally if not mor e persuasive with respect to pollutive uses of water under western appropriatio n 1 aw . The case of minimum stream flow maintenance calls for some form o f public intervention for the reasons suggested above . The benefits of minimu m stream flows are of at least four types : 1) aesthetic, 2) recreational, 3 ) water quality control, and 4) wildlife habitat maintenance . Many aesthetic an d recreational uses, such as hiking, sightseeing, rafting and fishing, are of th e nature of numerous and disparate interests which, because of transaction costs , are unable to compete effectively in the market . Water quality control is a straightforward externalities proble m which requires some form of public intervention to assure that costs ar e internalized and that polluters do not over-invest in polluting activities o r under-invest in pollution control . As a practical matter the level of strea m flow is directly related to the impact of existing pollutants on stream quality . Finally, wildlife habitat maintenance presents peculiarly complex problem s calling for public intervention due not only to the factors discussed above , but also to the fact that the wildlife resource itself has the characteristic s of a common pool resource . Accepting that some minimum level of stream flow is to be preferre d to dry streambeds from a social welfare point of view, and accepting tha t market failures associated with the existing private water rights syste m necessitate some form of public intervention if optimal minimum flow level s are to be preserved, the following two sections examine the approaches adopte d by the states of Colorado and Montana : The final section seeks to draw som e conclusions based upon a comparison of these two state systems . COLORADO : A CASE OF RESTRAINED PUBLIC CONTRO L Colorado is appropriately the namesake of that strain of wester n water law which is exclusively an appropriation system . It is a doctrine whic h respects the initiative of the person who actually invests time and resources i n the development of a resource . The doctrine - is a living version of the Lockia n conception that property rights should be granted to those who have put thei r labor into increasing the value of physical ,resources . It is not surprising , therefore, that a laissexfaire approach to water allocation has dominated an d continues to dominate in Colorado . In 1963, the Colorado legislature authorized the Colorado Rive r Conservation District to appropriate, for the use of the public, water of an y natural stream sufficient to maintain the fish habitat . When the Distric t sought to implement its new power, its action was challenged as being i n violation of the long standing requirement that water could not be appropriate d without a diversion . In Colorado River Conservation District v . Rocky Mountai n Power Company, the Colorado Supreme Court found "no support in the law of thi s state for the proposition that a minimum flow of water may be 'appropriated ' in a natural stream for piscatorial purposes without diversion of any portio n of the water 'appropriated' from the natural course of the stream ." Thus the first attempt at minimum flow protection in Colorado was aborted . In 1969 the Colorado legislature adopted the Water Rights an d Administration Act of 1969 which was designed to facilitate the adjudicatio n of existing rights, an outcome which would in turn facilitate the working s of the market as a water allocation mechanism . A 1973 amendment to the 196 9 Act sought to succeed where the 1968 instreamflow legislation had failed . Thi s 1973 act amended the definition of appropriation to eliminate the statutor y requirement of a diversion which had been the basis of the Rocky Mountain Powe r The legislation also expanded the definition of beneficia l Company ruling . use to include minimum stream flows "to preserve the natural environment to a reasonable degree" . Supreme Court Act s Again the Colorado Supreme Court was called upon to consider th e legitimacy of the law, this time on the basis of a claim that the Stat e Constitution required diversion and that the law could deprive Colorado citizen s of their Constitutional rights to appropriate water . The Court upheld th e constitutionality of the 1973 minimum flow law in the 1979 decision in Colorad o River Conservation District v . The Colorado Water Conservation Board . An effor t begun in 1963 thus culminated sixteen years later in a final determinatio n that the State and Colorado could act to preserve minimum stream flows . During those sixteen years the controversy was not limited to th e courts . In 1977 both houses of the Colorado Legislature approved legislatio n which would have prevented the State as owner of a minimum flow right fro m opposing the transfer of change of use of a senior right . The legislation, whic h was vetoed by the Governor, would have deprived the state of the only rea l strength its minimum flow rights would give it . Because the State appropriate s minimum flow rights with very junior priority dates, it has not protectio n during low flow periods . The rule which prevents water rights transfers i f they would harm existing rights, is the principal handle a junior rights holde r has on influencing future water allocations . The 1973 Act was subjected t o further attempts at amendment in 1979 and the effort will surely not b e abandoned in the next legislative session . Beneficial Use Defined If one steps back from the politics and litigation of what is a n emotional issue to many in Colorado, there is an inclination to wonder why al l the uproar . The State of Colorado has not been empowered to use its police powe r to make sure water is left in the State's streams and lakes . It has not eve n been suggested that the State develop a serious water management plan whic h might then be implemented, as is a land use plan, through government restriction s and limitations on vested private rights . The only thing the State has done i s to expand the definition of beneficial use to include minimum flow preservatio n and to authorize the Colorado Water Conservation Board to appropriate wate r for minimum flows on the same basis as any private party would acquire a ne w water right and to compete in the market for the purchase of existing rights . The law guarantees that the State will have no competitive advantag e by prohibiting the use of its traditional eminent domain power as a means o f 8 acquiring instream flow rights . Thus, the State is not seeking to exercise som e form of police power regulation which might justify alteration of vested privat e rights as it has in land use regulation . The State does not even seek to forc e its view of optimal water use on the market by requiring unwilling sellers to sell . It is clearly a market system in which the State has only whatever influence it s taxpayers are willing to give it . Yet many in Colorado have fought the minimum flow program on ever y front . Given their own vested interests, it should be no surprise . Historically , the beneficial use standard has restricted entry into the water rights market . People seeking to use water for "non-beneficial" purposes have simply bee n barred from the acquisition of water rights, whatever price they might be willin g to pay . The relaxation of this entry restriction is not an insignifican t occurrence to those who have benefitted from reduced competition in the past . Secondly, it is also significant that the State is authorized to act for thos e who would be precluded from the water rights market because of the burden o f _ high transaction costs . Whether the market approach to minimum flow water-allocation i s working in the sense of improved economic efficiency or in the sense o f achieving a more desirable distribution of benefits, and whether the fears o f those threatened either by improved efficiency or wealth redistribution ar e warranted, are questions which only more experience can answer . To date the State of Colorado has acquired nearly-1000 minimum flo w rights on lakes and streams . Almost all of those are upstream or hig h mountain . rights in water -fn which no one else had any interest . However, th e State's ability as a junior appropriator to object to water rights transfer s or changes tn . use which are detrimental to the State's instream rights wil l certainly' be of significance to future water allocation in Colorado . This wil l be particularly true if the State becomes serious about purchasing downstrea m rights Which will be impacted by upstream transfers and use changes . MONTANA : A CASE OF EXPANSIVE PUBLIC CONTRO L Montana is a Colorado Doctrine state in the lingo of western wate r law, which suggests, accurately, that Montana's water law looks a good deal lik e the water law of Colorado . It is an exclusively appropriation system whic h allows for the private acquisition of water for beneficial uses which includ e "agricultural, domestic, fish and wildlife, industrial, irrigation, mining , municipal power, and recreational uses" . In 1973, the Montana Legislature adopted the Water Use Act which wa s designed to implement a Constitutional provision requiring the State to administer , control and regulate water rights and to establish a centralized records system . Prior to 1973, the private water rights system in Montana suffered from a common (among other states) inadequacy of information on existing rights . Th e market exchange of rights was seriously hampered by this lack of ownershi p records, and it caused individual rights holders to be uncertain about th e extent of their particular rights . 9 In addition to i'ts purpose of clarifying existing private wate r rights, the 1973 Water Use Act created a channel for expansive public contro l of future water allocation in the State of Montana . Under the Act, state an d federal agencies, as well as political subdivisions of the State, may apply t o the Board of Natural Resources and Conservation to reserve water for existin g or future beneficial uses, or to maintain a minimum flow or quality of water . Applicants for water reservations must show, among other things, that th e reservation is in the public interest . State Allocates Wate r The effect of this reservation system is similar to that of th e various withdrawals from the United States public domain which led to th e creation of the National Park and National Forest systems . The water resourc e is publicly owned and has been made available to people who would appropriat e it for approved uses . The State subsequently decides that it will withdraw , through water reservations, a portion of the water which will no longer b e available for private acquisition . The system in no way affects existin g vested rights, nor does it eliminate the legal opportunity for future privat e acquisition of water . It does, however, reduce the amount of water availabl e for future private appropriation and it puts the state in a new role a s allocator of some of the state's water . The waters are no longer up'for grab s in a competitive market place . They are now up for grabs in the politica l arenas of local, state and federal government . . This Montana system for reserving water for future uses is particularly interesting in light of a strong historical bias in western water la w against the holding of water for future use . Private speculation in wate r was and continues to be discouraged by rules penalizing the non-use of a wate r right . The water right is acquired by putting the water to a beneficial use , and the right will be lost if the water is unused . In a system of poor records , abandonment and prescription are mechanisms for identifying truly abandone d or forgotten water rights . However, they are also mechanisms which demand present developmen t of water rights to protect the right, and thus a probable over-investment i n current as opposed to future water utilization . This bias for resourc e development now and against speculation in possible future values, a bia s reflected elsewhere in the law of the developing west, is lost upon a syste m which allows for the reservation of water for future use . Moratorium Passe d The Montana reservation system does not pre-empt the right of privat e parties to appropriate water in accordance with a permit procedure also established by the 1973 Water Use Act . In the face of dramatically increasin g pressure for water on the Yellowstone River, a demand related primarily t o energy development in Southeastern Montana, the Legislature passed a thre e year moratorium on the approval of pending or future permit applications . During the moratorium, which was later extended, the Board of Natural Resource s and Conservation accepted applications for water reservations on the Yellowston e River . TO Over thirty reservation applications were filed pursuant to a procedure established by the Department of Natural Resources and Conservation . O f these applications, two were for significant instream flow reservations . Th e other applications were for agricultural and municipal uses . The Montana Fis h and Game Commission sought a reservation of 8 .2 million acre feet per year a t the eastern edge of the state for fish habitat protection . The Montana Department of Health and Environmental Sciences applied for an annual flow at the same location of 6 .6 million acre feet for water quality maintenance . The Board of Natural Resources conducted protracted hearings whic h were followed by lengthy deliberation prior to the issuance of a feral order i n . 1979 . The procedures employed by the Board and the factors which influenced its final decision are fascinating subjects, but their discussion is not centra l to the objective of this paper . that is central is the recognition that th e State of Montana, through a Board of citizens appointed by the Governor, ha s prospectively allocated most of the waters of one of its three large rive r basins . The legal significance of these reservations in' relation to existin g and future appropriated rights is not entirely clear, nor is the authority o f the Board with respect to future adjustments of the initial reservation order . But these substantial uncertainties aside, the Yellowstone River has been parceled out and the State is already making plans to launch similar reservatio n proceedings on the Missouri and Clark Fork River basins . Early planning by th e Department of Natural Resources and Conservation anticipates a more coordinate d and less contentious approach on the part of state agencies than was the cas e on the Yellowstone . The Colorado Doctrine still prevails in Montana . It does not appea r that the reservation system in any way alters existing water rights or tha t right to appropriate new water rights . However, the reservation system doe s remove from the workings of this private rights allocation system the larges t portion of the water in perhaps the most economically important river in th e State . The water removed from the private market will be allocated by the Boar d of Natural Resources and Conservation as they make and amend reservations an d by the local, state and federal agencies who are the beneficiaries of th e reservations granted . PUBLIC CONTROL AND PRIVATE RIGHTS : WHICH PATH IS BETTER ? As was pointed out at the beginning of this paper, public contro l of water allocation is minimal in relation to the extensive public regulatio n of land use . Not even in Montana has it been seriously suggested that th e state might, for example, require irrigators to forego half of their wate r right in the interest of protecting the fish habitat or water quality in th e way that the down zoning of a parcel of land will sometimes reduce its valu e by 50 percent . Perhaps this reticence or perceived inability to regulat e private water rights is a product of a history of scarcity and its relate d disputes . Or the states may feel estopped ; in a way, because of the beneficia l use conditions imposed upon the initial acquisition of a water right . Bu t notwithstanding the fact that private rights in water have rarely been th e subject of significant state regulation, the contrast between the Montana an d Colorado approaches to instream flow maintenance is dramatic . There are n o doubt • lessons to be learned, but they will not be easily understood . 11 The Montana approach is dramatic and its impact is immediate . A n instream flow reservation of nearly 6 million acre feet per year makes most i f not all of Colorado's minimum flow rights appear insignificant at best . Bu t comparison of the systems must begin with a recognition of where both state s were when they began to think about minimum flow preservation and other use s not provided through the traditional private market transactions . Montana has a relative abundance of water, Colorado, particularly o n the east slope, has been water short for half a century . In a sense it wa s easy for Montana to decide to reserve water for future use, because suc h reservations would not deprive existing uses . The Board's decision on th e reservation applications was also made easy by the relative abundance of water . To be sure the Board agonized over their decision, but the issue they faced wa s how to satisfy everybody, not who do you satisfy and who must go without . Th e latter question will only be asked when scarcity demands it . In Colorad o scarcity requires that some will have less water than they want and others ma y have to go without . Under those conditions the reliance on a market allocatio n mechanism is not surprising . The situation in these two states contradicts a commonly held vie w that increased scarcity will necessitate increased government regulation an d intervention . Perhaps Colorado has yet to reach that condition of scarcity which triggers expanded government control . Only time will tell for sure, bu t for the moment it appears that government regulation has not been perceived a s the only available route for the allocation of a scarce resource . It is probably also premature to assess the relative adequacy of th e market and public control approaches, and in any event it is beyond the scop e of this paper to attempt such an empirical study . Many in Colorado are very pleased with the progress of the state's minimum flow program . They ar e optimistic that the state will plan an increasingly important role in wate r allocation as the state requires more downstream and senior water rights . Others in the state are less optimistic, but seem to see littl e prospect for a more aggressive state posture . The director of a state sponsore d water study says that the state has only three ways of influencing the allocatio n of water : it can negotiate agreements with federal agencies developing wate r projects in the state, it can acquire minimum flow rights under the 1973 law , or it can purchase rights in the market . The difference between the optimist s and pessimists in Colorado comes down to their perceptions about the state' s ability to effectively influence water allocation through participation in a market allocation system . Because of numerous legal uncertainties with respect to the Montan a reservation system, it is difficult to predict its long range impact on Montan a water use . It is clear, however, that the reservation system represents a strong commitment to expansive public control over future water allocation i n the state . The Board's experience on the Yellowstone suggests that despit e widespread satisfaction with the results, there is a serious need to examin e and improve the process by which such public allocation decisions are made . The complexities of diverse interests and voluminous technical evidence deman d sophisticated decision making processes if public water control is to avoid th e perceived misallocations which call the public control into existence in th e first place . 12 It will be fruitful to continue to study the contrasting approache s to allocating water to minimum flows in Colorado and Montana . For the present , however, it is of no small significance to recognize that the normal, ofte n reflexive, appeal to expanded public control of scarce resource allocation i s not the only available course of action . The Colorado experience with publi c participation in the market rather than public regulation of the market bear s watching closely in the coming years . 13 Presented November 1, 1979 by LOU FREDD, Oregon Department of Fish and Wildlife , Portland, Oregon . Pallcied acrd rf9aaeec Scc44tem 4 been asked by Director Donaldson to discuss with you toda y ' have "Policies and Aquatic Ecosystems" -- a subject which I hope i s sufficiently broad to cover the substance of my remarks . What I propose to d o is outline for you the principal policy and administrative tools the Departmen t of Fish and Wildlife uses to ensure adequate supplies of water for the fish an d wildlife resources of this state . The abundance of fish and wildlife is fundamentally determined b y habitat quality . For fish and other aquatic life, habitat is water . Withou t water in sufficient quantity and quality, commercially and recreationall y desirable species of fish fail, to be replaced with species of little or n o utility . All of us enjoy the native fish of Oregon, as consumers ; for income if we happen to be commercial fishermen or involved in related industry ; fo r recreation if we happen to be sportsmen ; or we may enjoy them simply for th e sake of their existence and what their presence tells us about the health o f our environment . At the same time, we enjoy the comfort and convenience growing out of the utilization of the state's wa-ter resources for economic an d social development in its many forms -- hydroelectric generation, flood control , irrigation, dependable and clean home water supply, and so forth . The wate r consumptive demands for this development has, and will continue, to jeopardiz e aquatic life -- most especially our once magnificent runs of anadromous fish , salmon and steelhead in particular . These demands can take unanticipated form . For example, if I ma y use a figure of speech innocently, a proposal has just recently surfaced t o divert 200 cfs from the Willamette River near Eugene to develop Amazon Ditc h for urban-centered recreation . By present day standards, this is a larg e diversion . Although details are sketchy, I believe plans are to run the wate r through the Ditch to Fern Ridge Reservoir and thence down the Long Tom Rive r back to the Willamette . The diversion could cause considerable loss of down stream migrant salmon and steelhead from the main Willamette if unscreened . 15 There may be other undesirable effects on fish and wildlife resource s of the main Willamette, including perhaps loss of spawning areas and deterioration of water quality -- all side effects which are difficult to predict an d quantify . The project, if it becomes reality will require careful coordinatio n among our Department, the State Water Resources Department, the local sponsor , and perhaps quite a few other agencies, if it is to have little or no detrimental effect on a long pursued objective of the Department of Fish and Wildlif e -- to restore salmon and steelhead runs of the Willamette River and its tributaries to potential abundance . PISTOL RIVER PROPOSA L More in an anticipated vein is a current proposal by private developer s to appropriate up to 1100 cfs of the flow of Pistol River, a small coastal strea m in the southern coast near Gold Beach, to create a low-head hydroelectric plant . Given the energy crisis, we expect to see many low-head hydro proposals . The proposed diversion would greatly reduce seasonal flows of the main stem Pisto l River at a point critical to the upstream passage of its runs of chinook salmon , steelhead, and cutthroat trout . Also, screening of the diversion would b e essential to protect downstream migrant juvenile fish from turbine injury . The Department of Fish and Wildlife has intervened in both Stat e Water Policy Review Board and Federal Energy Regulatory Commission proceeding s to ensure adequate safeguards for migratory fish are built into the projec t and its operating criteria . The cost of such safeguards in terms of powe r production opportunity forfeited to minimum flow requirements, screening device s and fish ladders, certainly makes the economic feasibility of this projec t questionable at this time . In the above examples, the Department of Fish and Wildlife has ha d to react through the administrative processes of other agencies to ensure safe guards for resources affected by proposed developments of water resources vita l to fish and wildlife . On the other hand, we also use those administrativ e processes in a prospective way ; that is, to establish long-term policies whic h resolve existing conflicts, or which minimize possible future conflicts ove r water allocation . As an example, we expend considerable biological and lega l expertise to develop satisfactory minimum flow schedules for the Columbia River . That is an interstate effort involving the fishery management agencies o f Oregon, Washington, Idaho, the federal government, and the treaty Indian tribes . One result of this effort has been to establish a means for maintaining a minimum flow of 110,000 cfs during the month of May in the main Columbi a at McNary Dam for the purpose of facilitating the downstream migration o f juvenile salmon and steelhead through the lower reservoirs and dams . This i s accomplished through agreement on use of water stored in reservoirs on th e Snake and upper Columbia rivers, and exchange of power produced at federal an d private turbines . To maintain 85,000 cfs flow at the mouth of the Snake i n May, water is drafted from Idaho Power projects on the Snake River . Power production lost to Idaho Power is repaid by the federal govern ment through generation at Dworshak Dam, operated by the Corps of Engineers o n the Clearwater system . The balance of required flow is developed by release o f storage from Coulee Dam, operated by the Bureau of Reclamation . Use of storag e 16 for fish mitigation on the Columbia River and its tributaries involves in almos t every instance complicated power exchanges with international implications , since overall storage policy in the Columbia is regulated under treaty betwee n the United States and Canada . Closer to home, protection of aquatic resources in allocation o f in-state waters is determined mostly through interaction of the Department o f Fish and Wildlife with the state Water Resources Department, and with federa l agencies implementing congressionally authorized water development projects . To a much lesser extent, protection is achieved through direct agreement between the Department of Fish and Wildlife and other water users . Such agreements, although binding on the affected parties, are not an integral part o f state water resources policy . Water appropriations in Oregon are administered by the state Wate r Resources Department . The nature and extent of new appropriations is determined , by statutory policy, water resources policy of the Water Policy Review Board , and administrative actions of the Water Resources Department within these polic y guidelines . The Department of Fish and Wildlife believes that statutory policie s of the State of Oregon provides the Water Resources Department with ampl e authority to provide a reasonable level of protection for fish and wildlif e habitat from new consumptive appropriations . That statutory authority must b e implemented, however, through water resources program statements developed b y the Water Policy Review Board . Statutory policy clearly identifies fish , wildlife, and recreation as beneficial uses to be considered, without prioritization, against other beneficial uses in the development of Board policies . Statutory policy is also clear that the Board must give due regar d to protection of fish and wildlife resources in the planning of multi-purpos e impoundments and drainage projects . Further, the Board is directed by statut e to "foster and encourage" minimum perennial streamflows sufficient to suppor t aquatic life and to minimize pollution, subject to existing rights . A principa l objective of the Department of Fish and Wildlife is to support the Board in it s effort to improve and extend its policies for protection of minimum perennia l streamflows within the state . In meeting that objective, the Department of Fish and Wildlif e provides the Board with information on streamflow requirements for maintainin g satisfactory populations of fish . These recommendations stem mostly from a state-wide survey conducted by the Wildlife Commission approximately ten year s ago . Since that time, the Board has used those recommendations in its newe r basin programs . The job of incorporating those recommendations into program s with state-wide coverage is far from complete, however . For example, th e Rogue and John Day Basins support some of the most important anadromous fis h runs in the state, but programs for these basins predate our minimum flo w recommendations, and we regard them as seriously deficient with respect t o minimum flow protection for small tributaries which provide some of the mos t important spawning and rearing areas . It is estimated by some that present Board policies provide 20,000,00 0 acre-feet of water for fish habitat . In our opinion, considerably more allocation of water for this purpose will be required to provide adequate, state wide coverage . 17 APPROPRIATION S As I stated previously, new appropriations are administered withi n statutory and Board policies, by the Director of the Water Resources Departmen t and his staff . The Board rarely, if ever, reviews proposed appropriations unless there is question of conflict with Board policy . The Department of Fis h and Wildlife and the Water Resources Department have an interagency agreemen t which provides environmental review of new appropriations prior to approval . This review provides an opportunity to identify fish and wildlife resource s affected by and new appropriations and to develop solutions of potential conflicts or policy issues for Board considerations . The interagency agreemen t which defines staff procedures for the review is relatively new, and it is to o soon to assess its effectiveness in reconciling conflicts between new consumptiv e uses and instream resource values . I believe, however, it has been extremel y helpful already in coordinating management aims of the two agencies . Let us turn now to some discussion of the Department of Fish an d Wildlife's role with respect to federal water development projects . Thes e projects have considerabl y, modified flow characteristics of several importan t Oregon rivers, such as the Willamette and Rogue . Newer projects, such as Los t Creek and Applegate dams in the Rogue Basin, have leaned heavily on fisher y enhancement for favorable benefit : cost ratios . Consequently, considerabl e storage in these reservoirs is dedicated to downstream flow enhancement . The Department of Fish and Wildlife has participated actively i n th e design of these projects for fishery enhancement functions . Authorized flo w schedules will serve to improve water quality and quantities of flow for upstrea m and downstream anadromous fish migration, spawning and rearing as well as sup port of resident fish populations . This habitat irilpkro . ement is limited to th e main-stem and to be most effective should be complemented by state wate r resources policies protecti•ng'streamflows in important tributary systems . Unfortunately, in the Rogue Basin and, toiallesser extent, th e Willamette Basin, this coordination of state and fed ral programs has not ye t been ach5-eved . We are hopeful that new programs for' the Rogue- and Applegat e Basins will be adopted by the Board this biennium . The . amounts of water required for fishery enhancement purpose s associated with water development projects is large . In average years, abou t 125,000 acre-feet of storage will be utilized from'Lost Creek to,mair'utain a congressionally-authorized flow schedule for that purpose . The Department o f Fish and Wildlife is currently evaluating . the effects of that flow regime o n fish life of the Rogue River . A similar study is planned for Applegate projec t when it is completed . The purpose of the evaluation is to determine ho w storage authorized for fishery enhancement can be best utilized . Optimum utilization may require adjustments in initially planne d flow regimes -- adjustments which may be difficult to secure without congressional action, and the cooperation of the state and federal agencies and othe r affected interests . This points out some of the risks and uncertainties face d in designing water development projects with fish mitigation function, sinc e existing habitat must often be sacrificed before habitat improvements can b e verified . 18 I would like to note-in passing that water development projects wit h dedicated fishery enhancement fUnct'ions provide the DepartmertLof Fish and Wild life with the rare opportunity to legally appropriate instrean flows -- but onl y to the extent those flows are developed out of dedicated storage also legall y appropriated by the Department . In this brief overview, I have neglected to point out many mino r considerations, and perhaps some important ones as well . I hope however I hav e left you with better understanding of the objectives and activities of th e Department of Fish and Wildlife in the development of state. and federal water- policies affecting aquatic ecosystems . Presented November 15, 1979 by ANNE SQUIER, member of Oregon ' s Land Conservatio n and Development Commission, Salem, Oregon . ?Pam Rammed aid Zama Zlde Pe'aaaea g ABSTRAC T Oregon's land use planning program, in the ideal, encompasses join t planning by all interested parties for the use of land, water, and air withi n a city or county . Whether the program will endure or fall will be largel y determined by our success or failure in coordination of state and local planning . There are close ties between the land use program and traditiona l water planning , A number of problems can be identified as plans are submitted fo r acknowledgement : 1, Cities need better information on future water availability i n order to do basic growth planning . 2. Counties and some cities need increased understanding of th e extent of their dependence on in-stream flows, and their responsibility t o participate in state policy formation to protect those interests . 3. Many cities are extremely concerned about protection of water shed areas outside their jurisdiction and will be bringing to the fore a conflict between city/public welfare concerns and those of county, private an d agency programs . 4. Overriding need for agency participation by the Water Resource s Department (as by all agencies) in plan development and review . In a positive vein, plan strengths include floodplain zoning , reservoir site protection and increasing awareness of water policy questions . Too, the state Water Resources Department has established a program for recognizing the land use plans and goals in their permit issuance program, utilizing the "Public interest" referral statute . 21 1 Future issues discussed include flood control planning, the 20 8 program with relation to population projections and minimum flows, minimu m flows into estuaries, reservoir site selection, non-federal cost sharing an d basin updates . As a result of interaction with the land use planning process , and increasing scarcity of the resource, updated basin plans will focus mor e on quantification of allocations and on reservations than on the present broa d brush definition of beneficial uses . OREGON'S LAND USE PLANNING PROGRA M The 1955 water law changes which established a framework for toda y ' s basin plans were an important step forward in land use planning in this state . In essence, basin planning established a process for setting out the appropriate and feasible land uses in a county area, since water availability leads an d controls land uses . This for many counties was as close to land use plannin g as they had seen to that point . The process included considerable technica l and inventory input, some public debate, and a final policy decision by th e water resources board . Our present land use program is not very different in basic structure : the intent is to make a decision as to appropriate use of land area, rather tha n a water source ; the public input and debate ; and decision making . What make s Oregon's program an innovation and a grand experiment is that it attempts t o utilize all information about the area being planned-not just informatio n related to water use, not just information for transportation, not just loca l economic or social needs--and to accomodate and recognize the plans and program s of all affected jurisdictions and agencies . Oregon's land use planning program seeks as an ideal to produce a coordinated comprehensive plan which, for d given segment of land, lays ou t uses agreed to by all interested and affected parties . The potential benefit s from such a plan are apparent . No longer would one state agency be plannin g and making decisions for an area based on an assumption of high growth, whil e another agency having some additional information (perhaps regarding wate r availability, or air quality problems) is making decisions for the same piec e of land based on an entirely different projected growth . Finally, neither o f these agencies would be planning without foreknowledge of the affecte d community's vision of and plans for the future . So much for ideals . What does the law say today ? ORS CH . 197 mandates the preparation of coordinated, comprehensiv e land-use plans, to be in conformance with statewide planning standards, th e goals adopted by LCDC . 1. "Land" includes water, both surface and subsurface, and the air . 2. "Comprehensive" means all-inclusive both in terms of the geographic area covered and the functional and natural activities and system s occuring in the area covered by the plan . 3. "Coordinated" means (again, from the statute) that the needs o f all levels of government, semi-public and private agencies, and the citizen s 22 of Oregon have been considered and accomodated as much as possible , Coordination is the key to the whole process . In Senate Bill 10 0 the legislature made a clear choice as to what type of land use plannin g system Oreg.pn would have : Cities and counties should remain as the agencies to manag e the local aspects of land conservation and development with in their jurisdictions ; and to promote coordinated administration of land uses it is necessary to have planning goal s to be applied by state agencies, cities, counties, an d special districts throughout the state, Both the statute and Goal 2 require that agencies make their interest s and responsibilities known in the coordinated planning process, as well as t o supply information and technical resources available within the agency so as t o improve the factual base for the plan . Thus, the final plan adopted at th e local level will reflect not only the questions, concerns, and standards in th e statewide planning goals but incorporate and 'accommodate the needs and plans o f all levels of government as muchaspossible . There will be conflicts . Coordination does not mean that state agencies have a veto power over a pla n policy proposed at the local level, nor that local government has veto powe r over a proposal from a state agency . It does mean that wherever there is a conflict, the final decision must be based on the facts of the situation an d the'rationale for the decisions must be available . Planning Goal s This then is a brief description of-coordinated comprehensiv e planning . What are goals? They are statewide planning standards to which all _ plans and implementing regulations must conform . After extensive hearings i n 1973-1975 LCDC adopted a total of 19 goals (see Appendix . A) . What do-the Goals have to do with water resource planning ? Although only Goal 6 (Air, water, and land resources quality) an d Goal 16 (estuarine resources) have an obvious tie to water, coordinated water / land planning is critical to the majority of goal topics . Examples : . Goal 3 : Defines agricultural lands as being certain Soil Conservatio n Service (SCS) class lands and other lands suitable for farm use taking int o consideration many factors, including "existing and future availability o f water for farm irrigation purposes" . Goal 4 : Defines forest-lands not just as those with potential fo r commercial use but "other forested lands needed for watershed protection" : and defines forest uses far which these lands must be retained to include_ watershed protection . ' Goal 5 : Mandates that the location, quality, and quantity of wate r areas, wetlands, watersheds, and groundwater resources be inventoried . Thes e resources are to be managed so as to preserve their original character unles s the plan process identifies conflicting uses for them, In that case, con sequences of the conflicting uses shall be identified and programs develope d -23 to protect the natural resources for future generations . The guidelines fo r Goal 5 make clear that potential reservoir sites are to be protected agains t irreversible loss to that purpose . Goal 6 : Is directed to maintaining water quality and directs tha t discharges not be planned which in the long range will exceed the "carryin g capacity" of the stream . The obvious underlying requirement for this is tha t we know in the long range what the base flow, or minimum flow, of a stream i s to be . Goal 7 : Directs that developments not be planned or located i n known areas of natural disaster or hazard without appropriate safeguards . Plans must be based on an inventory of known hazard areas, including strea m flooding, and high water table . Goal 11 : Requires that there be long range plans for delivery o f public services - such as water - consonant with the planned growth for th e area . This includes, as a first step, a realistic inventory and evaluatio n of present and future sources of supply . Goal 16 : Includes an implementation requirement which asks tha t the Water Policy Review Board, assisted by Federal and State agencies , consider establishing minimum fresh water flow rates and standards such tha t uses of our estuaries, including navigation, fish and wildlife characteristic s (which would include wetland productivity) and recreation, will be maintained . Goal 17 : Speaks to planning for coastal shorelands so as to reduc e adverse effects on water quality, such as sedimentation, and to reduce hydro logic hazard to shoreland developments . This goal emphasizes maintenance o f riparian vegetation, and the importance of retaining shore areas which ar e appropriate for water dependent uses such as docks, marinas, or fisher y activities . Goal 18 : Beaches and dunes, includes an implementation requiremen t on local, state , - and federal plans, to protect groundwater from drawdown whic h would lead to loss of stabilizing vegetation, loss of water quality, or intrusion of salt water into water supplies . From this list, which is by no means exhaustive, it is clear that planning fo r water is intimately tied to planning for terra firma . CURRENT PROBLEM S As comprehensive plans are completed and adopted they are submitte d to LCDC for acknowledgement review - that is, for measurement against the goals . All agencies are notified as is the public, and there is a 45 day review perio d for comments or objections . This is an important review, for once the plan i s acknowledged, state agencies and all others are not to take actions inconsistent with the plan . At this point about 55 of 277 plans have been acknowledged . A number of water related problem areas are obvious in review o f these plans : 24 1. Municipal water' s .upg .ily . Most plans have some- discussion a t 1!east in the. inventory section regarding sufficiency and qualdty and location of water, whether ground or surface . In planning for public facilities, citie s project an expanded water system but often lack any discussion or factual bas e regarding the sufficiency of future' supplies for expansion, This c.a.n . trr•i r into question the community's growth assumptions and goals . One example would be the plan• for the city of StanfteYd, which identifies its dependence on groundwater, identifies decline of city well levels an d recognizes the possibility of becoming a critical groundwater area . Policies. express the city's willingness to participate in a regional system but th e feasibility of such a system is not known . Stanfield has nonetheless planne d for considerable industrial, commercial, and residential growth without assessing the impact of that growth on declining groundwater supplies, or providin g policies which limit or control and contain ' growth until a regional wate r system or some other solution is identified . The city is awaiting detailed information from a current groundwate r study now being conducted by the Department of Water Resources . LCDC has aske d that the plan have policies committing the city to any changes necessitated b y the groundwater information when it is available . Such changes might b e extensive, even to modification of their growth plans . Second, Stanfield need s planning policies to keep growth compact until that study and necessary pla n changes are complete so that the city is not precommttted to a growth patter n which cannot be efficiently served . A second example is from the city of Sheridan, which identifie s severe water shortages during low water seasons, and projects development o f considerably expanded supplies from several sources, including an earl y municipal reservation . No data is given regarding the adequacy of thes e sources . In sum, our cities need better information on the actual avail ability of water from various sources in order to plan with reality . 2. County plans may include information on the importance of in stream flows, but generally do not include policies relating to in-stream flo v protection - seemingly leaving this area to "state water resource planning" . Yet these same plans and some city plans depend heavily on continued in-strea m flows for their economic planning, recreational resource, water pollutio n control, etc . A community which depends on fishery income or income from wate r oriented recreation will gain by explicit recognition of that fact and b y drawing concerns about the essential in-stream or in-lake water supply an d quality directly into its planning discussions and documents . Such a communty can then influence management of its basic economic resource by state o r federal agency plans and policies . Local interests in water'quality standards , or minimum flows, or various storage potentials must be a part of state agenc y planning, but cannot be if they have not been articulated . There is a critical need to increase understanding bf the extent of a community's dependence on in-stream flows and that community's responsibility t o participate in establishment of state policies'to protect those flows . :25 3. A third area where conflicts are increasingly apparent is i n relation to watershed protection . Many small cities have watersheds outsid e of their urban planning area and are concerned to protect those watershed s from influences which would degrade water quality or quantity . Gilliam County recognized that the city of Condon takes its water from five wells outside th e city and has included in its plan a policy to restrict land use in the vicinit y of those wells to protect the water supply . The city of Cannon Beach has a plan policy which purports to influence actions on the land around the city owned watershed . This policy is non-binding since it has not been jointl y adopted by the county, but our department has pointed out the county's responsibility to deal with the city ' s valid concerns as the county draws up it s plan for that area . We can see that as county plans are completed there will be increasing focus on conflicts between cities concerned for their water quality an d county plans for watershed areas . These conflicts are sure to involve stat e agencies, in particular the Department of Forestry . 4. Finally, as we review plans we become ever more acutely awar e of the importance of state agency participation in plan development and review . Our staff can in no way provide the technical expertise, background and dat a to identify actual gaps in plan inventory information or to evaluate technica l questions presented by the communities . Likewise, it is apparent that far mor e help is needed at the local level in sorting through the technical data in basi n plans and other documents in order to arrive at realistic and acceptable policies . This need will continue beyond acknowledgement of all plans, since new data wil l be generated, needs change, and state policies change . On the positive side, plans are generally dealing well with flood plain policies ; county plans are identifying potential reservoir sites ; an d inventory documents are showing greatly increased awareness and concern fo r water resources in general . Also on the positive side, the Water Resources Department ha s instituted a good method for assuring that issuance of water rights or permit s will not be done in contravention of the goals or acknowledged plans . Thre e steps have been taken . The permit application identifies the need for a n applicant to be sure his proposed use meets the plan . The weekly listing o f applications to the Water Resources Department will be given wider circulation , including all county planners . Finally, if the Director of the Water Resource s Department receives any allegations of goal or plan violations, he will refe r the application to the Water Policy Review Board for a decision under ORS 537 .170 . (This statute provides that when the Director has cause to believe an applicatio n may not be in the public interest he may refer the application to the Board . ) There will probably not be many such applications, but it is importan t to have this mechanism in place since land use plans are more detailed than th e basin plans under which beneficial uses are now defined, and because the plan s may identify further considerations which need to be part of the water allocation decision but which have not been incorporated into basin plans, many o f which are sorely outdated . 26 FUTURE ISSUE S What water-land planning problems face Oregon in the coming month s and years? 1. Flood control project planning must in the future bette r recognize present zoning and damage control ordinances for the flood-threatene d areas and figure benefits from protection only of allowed uses - not fo r projected "highest and best use" in terms of full development to urban densities . 2. The "208" program will become less a catchword and more a par t of the concern of every agency . In particular there must be attention t o evaluation of in-stream flows for water quality, then coordinated policy actio n on the part of the Water Policy Review Board (WPRB) and the Department o f Environmental Quality (DEQ) to tie the quality/quantity issues together . focus . estuaries . 3 . Maintenance of in-stream flows for all purposes will be a majo r 4. Eventually there will be attention to minimum flows int o 5. There will be a significant number of small/medium storag e projects proposed and carried through across the state . As these are planned , we must reorient our thinking to recognize that the identification of need an d options for technically satisfactory sites are water resource issues, but tha t the choice between alternative sites is one which encompasses the entire lan d use planning process and should be intimately tied to it, from the citize n involvement program through final choice made at the county and state level s considering all planning goals . Water resource planning can no longer mak e those choices independently . 6. The non-federal cost sharing initiative may be a boost t o greater state involvement in project planning and a broader approach to th e local involvement in such planning . That is, it may be another spur to tyin g water planning to the overall coordinated land use planning because only wit h that tie can a strong case for state funding and support be made . 7. Finally and most important - basin updates : * are desparately neede d * will provide new basic data-as on ground water, which wil l be incorporated into land use plan in the update proces s * will utilize population projections available from th e comprehensive plans and uniform 208 population disaggregation s (now underway) . All jurisdictions and agencies will be usin g these projections . * will need to recognize agricultural lands identified in th e county plans as irrigable lands, since it makes no sense to coun t as irrigable those lands already committed to development . Th e recent south coast update appears to continue to rely on overal l 27 assessment of physically irrigable lands without regard for actua l land use, with the result that calculations of need for water ar e thrown into questio n * will increasingly need to focus on ground water managemen t as communities wrestle with increased demands and accelerate d conflicts . The critical areas designation, coming after the proble m is acute, is not an adequate tool for Planning : we need allocatio n of ground water every bit as much as of surface water . * Last, but not least, new policies on "beneficial use" wil l have to be more than lists of uses . They can be better refined , utilizing land use plans as a guide for beneficial uses and goin g on to questions of quantification and reservation in the light o f diminishing supplies . 28 APPENDIXA LCDC Goal s 1. Citizen Involvemen t 2. Land Use Plannin g 3. Agricultural Land s 4. Forest Land s 5. Open Spaces, Scenic and Historic Areas, and Natural Resource s 6. Air, Water, and Land Resources Qualit y 7. Areas Subject to Natural Disasters and Hazard s 8. Recreational Need s 9. Economy of the Stat e 10. Housin g 11. Public Facilities and Service s 12. Transportatio n 13. Energy Conservatio n 14. Urbanizatio n 15. Willamette River Greenwa y 16. Estuarine Resource s 17. Coastal Shoreland s 18. Beaches and Dune s 19. Ocean Resources 29 Presented November 29, 1979 by LANE R . HARPER, Bonneville Pawer Administration , Portland, Oregon . Ete aad Z~/arrn Place/ ix eehemgea Revel p lanning for development of the Columbia River probably starte d with Lewis and Clark . They recorded the numerous Columbi a River falls, rapids, and other hazards to navigation on their detailed map s 175 years ago . The Columbia River was, at that time and for many years there after, the major natural resource of the region and served as the main stree t of the Pacific Northwest . President Theodore Roosevelt set forth the principles of rive r basin planning and development early in this century . In messages, to Congres s he stated the case for developing each river as a unit, thus giving us th e principle of unified development, the concept of multiple purpose planning , and the use of upstream storage to capture the flood waters and control an d regulate the release of water for optimum benefits . Many of his quotation s on these principles have become classics . He said : "Every stream should be used to its utmost . No stream can be s o used unless such use is planned in advance . When such plans ar e made, we shall find that, instead of interfering, one use ca n often be made to assist another . Every river system, from-it s headwaters in the forest to its mouth on the coast, is a singl e unit and should be treated as such . " In transmitting the report of th e Inland Waterways Commissio n February 26, 190 8 With respect to the arid and semi-arid West, he saw the opportunity to make good water out of bad water by putting the floods to work . I n urging Con g ress to launch the reclamation program, he said : "The forests alone cannot, however, fully regulate and conserv e the waters of the arid region . Great storage works are neces sary to equalize the flow of streams and to save the flood waters . " Message, December 3, 190 1 31 These quotations come from much longer messages setting fort h the three basic principles of (1) unified river development, (2) multipl e purpose development, and (3) optimum development by means of upstream storag e reservoirs . These are the principles which another Roosevelt, Franklin Delano , put to work in 1933 in the Tennessee Valley and throughout the West, includin g the Columbia River Basin . Major John S . Butler was one of the first people who calle d attention to the need for upstream storage on the Columbia River . He wa s Seattle District Engineer of the U .S . Army Corps of Engineers in 1932 an d wrote much of the Army's first 308 Report on developing the Columbia Rive r which was published at that time . For example, he recommended buildin g Hungry Horse Dam, which Congress authorized for construction by the Water an d Power Resources Service (previously the Bureau of Reclamation) of the U . S . Department of the Interior, in 1944 and is today one of our most valuabl e storage projects in the Pacific Northwest . The value of the Hungry Horse Da m in relation to the hydroelectric generation system in the Columbia River Basi n is discussed in more detail later in this paper . An outstanding expert on the value of upstream storage in th e region was Ben Torpin who was Project Engineer, Corps of Engineers, on th e Bonneville Dam Project from 1933 to 1936 . He later became Chief of Engineering , North Pacific Division, from 1942 until his retirement in 1950 . In 1945 h e prepared a 95-page report in which he said : "Storage is the key to complete development of the Columbi a River . . . without storage only about 20 percent of a hydro electric power site's potential firm capability can be realize d . . . 80 percent of the potential power depends on storage . . . "When properly planned, conflict seldom arises between the use o f storage for power and the use of storage for these various purposes ; rather, they complement and benefit each other . " He repeatedly pointed out that upstream storage opened the doo r for optimum, balanced, multiple purpose development . Through his work th e Corps found that the same upstream storage project could reduce floods ; provid e a full reservoir for summer recreation ; increase minimum flow for power, navigation, and fish ; and increase water availability for irrigation . He summarize d this point by saying : "The fundamental basis for the application of the multiple us e principle is storage_ . " In part as a result of Ben Torpin's studies, the Corps o f Engineers in 1944 asked the International Joint Commission to study the Libb y Dam opportunity . The Libby Dam reference of 1944 resulted in 15 years o f studies and 5 years of negotiations which led to the Columbia River Treaty o f 1964 between the United States and Canada . Since 1964, the Treaty led to th e completion of three storage dams in Canada and our Libby Dam which togethe r gave us about half of the 47 .7 million acre-feet of upstream storage now avail able in the Columbia watershed . Libby Dam, incidentally, solved the local floo d control problem of the Bonners Ferry, Idaho, area, and also helped to solve th e flood problem along the Columbia River's main channel . 32 The Treaty with Canada underlines an important fact . Th e Columbia is an international river . About 43 percent of the summer peak flo w comes from Canada . Under the Treaty, Canada can, if it chooses, divert th e Kootenay River into Columbia Lake in the early 1980's . The Treaty has termination dates applying to certain rights spread over the next 75 years . Thi s means that Canada can make some changes that would affect the flow of wate r in the United States . Through the years hydroelectric development for commercial operation has taken place throughout the Pacific Northwest . However, there is no t enough hydroelectric energy to go around . In fact, only about 80 percent o f the region's needs are met from hydroelectric generation ; the rest is met by thermal-electric generation . The privately owned utilities have 88 plants , publicly owned utilities have 39, and Federal agencies have built 30 plants , for a total of 157 plants with a total of about 28 .3 million kilowatts . Ther e is a total of 31 thermal-electric generating plants in the region, 18 privatel y owned and 13 publicly owned utilities, for a total of about 7 .3 million kilo watts . See Table 1 . Information on the amount of generating capacity is als o shown by states in Table 2 . COORDINATION WITH OTHER S Bonneville Power Administration (BPA) sells electricity from th e 30 Federal hydroelectric plants built and operated by the Corps of Engineer s Service (previously the Bureau of Reclamation) in the Pacific Northwest . These are all on the Columbia River or its major tributaries . Bonneville make s the benefits from water power available to the public ; and, in that sense, BP A is a bridge between the people and their river . In making this accomplishment , Bonneville has been heavily involved in coordination with others . This involve s arrangements for transmission line rights-of-way across Indian reservations, th e Columbia River Treaty with Canada, and the Pacific Northwest-Pacific Southwes t Interties which involve the entire West Coast . While BPA primarily transmits and markets electric power , Bonneville is also well aware of the many other water uses such as navigation , flood control, irrigation, pollution control, fish and wildlife, wild an d scenic rivers, wilderness and primitive areas, and recreation . The Bonnevill e customers each year pay in millions of dollars that go into some of these othe r purposes . BPA contributes to the fisheries research and study program, t o environmental research, and in time will provide major payments to subsidiz e irrigation . The use of water for virtually all of these purposes has priorit y ahead of power generation, and some of these priorities reduce the powe r production . The Columbia River has a number of characteristics which affec t its ability to produce electric power and serve other uses . First, the rive r is steep, dropping 2 feet per mile compared to the slow moving Mississipp i which drops only 6 inches per mile . Second, the river flows in a channel o f solid rock suitable for dam foundations . Third, the river is virtually fre e of silt, assuring long reservoir life of hundreds of years . Fourth, th e Columbia discharges 73 percent of its natural flow in the six summer month s and only 27 percent in the six winter months, when electric energy is mos t 33 c~. x4 r~ H 0 0 ' (0 Lv (t-) N Q~ C rl tr-1 oo tY -t i M N (9 r- 0 0 CI) rI ~ ~-n c- 01 to Cf3 , C') n Co 0-1 W C'J l r--f c", CV '.0 C`^ LI "i !'n Ln H co Y N \0 O-= C] OZ LC D L CI, Mc t-N H H 0 Pi 0 oH o c 0 UPt 7a t4 s-, o C7 H H P; O 0 H 0 1-D 0 r I C) ;d J •r i ') !i: E{ M St ra ~a 4t H C 34 H a3 4= c ci ui a) AS +3 o El ,c , E- 4 * TABLE 2 PACIFIC NORTHWEST STATE S EXISTINGGENERATING CAPACITY January 31, 198 0 State Hydro I Thermal Total WASHINGTON 1 Federal Public Private OREGON 1 13,420,830 6,301,741 893,860 0 1,341,400 1,280,900 13,420,83 0 7,643,141 2,174,76 0 3,189,700 111,615 861,823 0 51,200 1,750,000 3,189,700 162,81 5 2,611,82 3 611,250 10 :350 1,566,445 0 4,740 56,825 611,25 0 15,09 0 1,623,270 705,000 0 607,670 0 0 756,944 705,000 0 1,364,61 4 28,280,284 5,242,009 33,522,29 3 17,926,780 6,423,706 3,929,798 0 1,397,340 3,844,669 17,926,78 0 7,821,04 6 7,774,467 / Federal Public Private IDAHO Federal Public Private MONTANA Federal Public Private TOTAL Federal Public Private 1/ . On border - each state has half of the total generation . 2,/ Only on the west slope of the Continental Divide except Colstrip i s counted . BPA - Branch of Power Resource s February 14, 198 0 35 needed . It is this last ratio of 73 to 27 that the engineers are changing b y means of upstream storage . Finally, as a fifth characteristic, the Columbi a historically had peak flows as high as 1,240,000 cubic feet per second measure d at The Dalles in June 1894 . That great flood reached the second floor of many buildings i n downtown Portland, Oregon . At the other extreme, the Columbia had a low flo w in January 1937 of only 35,000 cubic feet per second . The ratio of the highes t to the lowest flow is 35 to 1 . It has been one of the goals of upstream storag e to reduce that ratio from 35 to 1 to the present 5 to 1 . Storage projects hav e cut the maximum flood down to about 600,000 cfs and have brought up the low flo w to more than 100,000 cfs . For comparison purposes, the St . Lawrence River is one of th e steadiest flowing rivers in the world . The peak flow has never been mor e than double the minimum flow . The steady flow results from the upstrea m storage provided naturally by the five Great Lakes . The Columbia will neve r reach a 2 to 1 ratio, but there is still plenty of opportunity for mor e upstream storage to improve the existing ratio . In examining the existing development of the Columbia River an d its major tributaries, Table 3 gives the nameplate ratings of the hydroelectri c power storage projects . The operating utilities and agencies are adding additional units to some of the existing projects . Plans for expanding some o f the other projects are underway . When all of the projects, existing an d planned, are completed, the system will release very little water withou t generating electricity from it . HUNGRY HORSE DAM Figure 1 is a profile chart which shows the relationship of th e existing projects to one another by their elevations in feet above sea level . The vacant spaces between some existing dams are potential damsites . Ther e one can see how Hungry Horse Dam is a key project in the system . Figure 2 i s an illustration of the value of Hungry Horse Project, through the developmen t of the downstream hydroelectric benefits from it . The average runoff of the Columbia River is 180 million acre-fee t at the mouth . Table 4 shows that the amount of usable storage developed i n the Columbia Basin is about 47 .7 million acre-feet . This stores about 2 6 percent of the runoff . Storing more of the runoff can provide a little additional energy for meeting base loads . It would give more flexibility in operating the storage more efficiently . However, non-power uses of the water , such as for fish, flood control, and recreation, may utilize the extra storag e in more effectively meeting their requirements . The Pacific Northwest River Basins Commission recently issued th e final draft of its three-volume report called "Water--Today and Tomorrow . " This report addresses the need for more upstream storage especially in respons e to the pressure from the fishery people for higher minimum flow, and pressur e by the irrigators for more water for irrigation . The report lists more tha n 26 million acre-feet of potential storage reservoir sites available upstrea m 36 38 0000, 0,00 01400 p .. 40 .04 •'ar Y . M0 •000 • 1 0 ▪ u _ 0000 0• .ee S 0• 0 I a 0000 .J{0d at 00 I M 00•011,W0 /100N N0000 . 0 04 0 000 0 O000 ' N 0 0 • I! +I0 00 '06 0. N 01006. C . 10 0 6•OZ 01 100 000601 101000 0 I a 1 0 .0 a l I e ! • .00 V • 0 NN 0 N •N .N . • O• iW s 0111 1 0•W W 0 .0 1 00.0 0 0100 0 • • UeIW0 O O!06. C 1• J •,Z C a . ' 0r O• 00 Z •'! Z • T 9 0 • .•1 f• Z •' W ~' tr 1Y » •: el • W • ' 06 1 1 1 N Z 0N 6 U : 0 CO r IA rC Z . 1 1 1 , 6 •N T0 r • " CC w 110 040 1!1 . 1 1 1 1 1 01101 1 . 1 1 1 a0 4 4 1 a u• 0• a .N040n 1010 .0 . . .NN' 66 . .6 W {J 00 0 N0 . o .. 0 WL' Z 00 T. N C r00 r 00 r 000 E i oe2 l Z O w& ▪ 0 0 N 00 q 00 R 04 •! • 0 Z q WO 00 M r C V U J t 0 e 0 r 0 0 r . 0 0 o 111 1 1 10001 A10 .1 • 0 0 .0 0000 • M 1 11111 1 0 0 .0 I 11 . 1 1 1111 1• a I 1 11, , 1014 1 1111 1 1 1 W 111 ,a 1 1 1 0 0 0 0D 100 0 0101 0 0 0• . 0 e 0 0 0 . 11 N a P I 1161 .. .1 I 1 1 1 1 11 11-00 001001 00100 .0000 •• 0060 O 01000 rNO 0000 a 01041 N e0•00 M •O 00100 00040 0000 •O • 0M • • • 00 • N••C • r f 00 U 0• • • 00 • • 0000 •••• •• • •• Lt . e 00 0e 000 a 0 ON 0e00 wI NNee 00 • L r .C N 0000 0000 0 n •0 N 0 Z • 20 N N a .o 1111 1 1 1 1 1 00 .0 0 0 0 0011 CC 1 1 11 1 0111 1 '1 Mar °. CS C Z • C r C 0 . 0 • .2 • WC J W 1000w P .b w I P M P e N ON = • Z • a 60 0 0 0 Z Z rW .0 w 0 0 00,00 o r 10 0000 0 000 00 0 .00 ® 0 0 0 i 0•'0 A ee•e 1000 AN 00 0•00 .•0 00 0 . . NN.I .00 0000 10000 0 000 0•00 6 000O •owe .0 0 N 00 . 0 0 C N0100 .00-00 C. w N N N 1000 0 0W M 0 01,00 00004 0100 .7 N cZ r ft Z IW 00000 M 00,0 0 0 0 0 0 00000 .0C5000 A0 00 01000 0 q 0 00 .00 00000 M 000 •0 . . . . a 000 e t 00 e 0001. 0 0000 0 Oc J 0 Me . . 00 . N N .►N ►e•.A 00100 'O .A• P wq0 0 ..00 0 .00 N N N .Nor . Nw . q 0 'U r J 0 0 0 0 W L ! 00 0000 00000 U . U . . A 2' .6) 'J ((~~ W W W' W 0 D WW7 yyII W W 61,~1 •. w O') O C t O L 0 L 0 0 00 A00 0 0 0 0 0 W0 0 N 0 p W1 J 060 •.4 0 {O W W -ow JU W 00 6.0 « y• O ..u 4w V 4LL 4CW 2 0 Z 0 0 e 1J 00 0 00 .70 2 0 2 i 0 SW M Wr C a W 0 00000 00000 0 0 000660 V = 0 0W0W 0 0 e .W R Y 0. 0 04 040 0 s ♦ U r0 W0 0 .-0 Z0 000 000 002'Y . _ 0 0 0 .0i. e Y W r W Z Z 00000 00 0004, 0 Y 0000U 0 .40 0 JSPO O W { R0 gates 000 { W LL01. . . ,,l!N I .►. W OM 1 00000 0 J J 0 0460 0 CW 0 0 61 u U e e Y 0 0L O. 0 N N L! 000100 Z 2 0 000 L CH T Z e :Ill J J JU _Y! W r i 0 e w ... .. Z 00 Z 000 ppL t f 2 Z 0 00 W 0` 0 20 04.0=4 0 .6 a ZXZZ0 Z Y Y0 0S 2 g .T 0002 'I V IU 0000 0 0 4 0 20 00000 _00000 00000 00000 000 U 0000 ▪▪ O .•U1.+001000 00 t 0t 0t 2ZZZ C 00000 N T MM i 100 Sv : t t T t t . U a•J 00000 00000 IA 0 r100000 ii i 0 .0 0 000 0 002 0 Lb f1-e0 M4 Z s 10000 . 00000 4.1 2 2 W 1'1'1'1 00 0O W 2r' z 0 000ZW4{ rc ▪ 0=01 0 0J s f• 0 416 W 0O W W 0 0 0 0 04 000 C. C 2 M. L K 00000 00 0 00 0 0 000 00 U 00l l l 1' S00000 9 3 0Owry 0 1 00000 00l l 05.55 . 1.7. U U U U U 000 . 0 • T T t t t 00000 00000 0 0 0 0 0 00000 O ••Z0 U 1}w W 2J21 w'toO 2 p• =00000 4000Ua t•a L J 0Z 0 . 0U N0 W0 q0 00 00 a OO 0 .0 . 00 0.4 0 04 . 00 Y` O 00 C- 0-6 00 ~l`NJ W OO N I. It0 0 ,. OL . t Z0 Sc .0 0• 00 00.•r00 00 2 2 0r 0440 .. 0 0O 0 r= . 00000 0Oe• 0 00 0.00C 0 S 0 t 2 N 0 0 t 2 2 0 0 0 00 0 00000 0 c1 00 tC20J 0Yd00 mo+s0 y _woo-•. 00000 1/ t 0 _ .. t rr J Y t G 0 y .COe• G U U L 2 0 iS . . ti0D 0 a 0O 0 U 0 0 0 0W'00 0 0 N 00 . .1 NOa r • OZ W4 ON-Pe .►► N a r c I . N . b V 0 . N TI1 AI C. N. 00 .6•. ■+ N .n N O0 .0m 00 n MW PN0 •N 0 A NN0•O n0 .05 f r • • • ace • • • • • • • • • • N•O N• O •00 ► A N N .WNW!' OS . n0 NP0O n.6IN ►O n NN! 0! PN OM O. ..! 51. . ►! N N 0a 0n I Z■ N N n NHN N. N. J wears . O O M N O Oa 0 . 0000W Z CL N . N N 0 101 W O N M. M WNM W M N ,0 N N t P arroyo NAOW I r C O N C M O O N . N N . 5 n 2 N N n N N •. WNW S N Z 00010 •..O I O c 1♦ . • 0 N N &C OWN An 20PS OO ..NO e.N N C 000 N NNOO W000 N . 0,505 N. . O .NNN NM ONW WI •05N I .• WN N .o .t . N . M000 .'Ma C Z. 1 r• N N 0W NNO n! naJ N Z w 0 1 5 .1 P n M N N.!JW• M N N n . N M M A0 P . . r, C CQ y • • e .n•A •N MWOMM n N M c e N! N► N ► NP 10e P N Me Im N•• Cl 0000 M OW n N 0000N 0 n N e P n A NN. 0 .n O . IN► 0 .O Nt e .N JCNr.ReMO NNPA OeNM0 . P I WO O ma N J` • WaN "WO . OWNS, seeI O . N ` rWU A .NN WM .156 . N INN J. OW .Ca f 6., B O W aa NW . W WV► 0461 ■ r 650114 .,t NW . . ... W W W W W O O O . N M. e.ONO e 0! NA . .... . -e .Met 't . e►. octet NO P I c n . N.O .I . OM►Nn N .. M heat fleas seat . .. . . . . . ... .. .. . 1111145 W W W W W W W W W W W W In n • • .. ... WI.) W W W n O N . e . O O . . O I N N O t C A ! IA J M N.N W M. P . A O O . P *SAN MN . n N .. N ... n A PN .NSS . ... . N Mt af 0 O O . O . M 00 00 W0,00 AI.e AA . s O.OO .I. !. see PO CP t ' : : :t e c 0 :NW . . 0 MNe . . . . A P M O N 0 .11 0 e N 0 . . O0 I ac--c P . WM I . . I .5 A O NI N n N!■ MOW. I I .C I n N n A t n e s N 0 . n_ n 0• P c c N .5 .0045 e N . N A I n N . N . N WA N I O P e . N I n NW MO 0. I I B.NN . . aA In. N . N t. I I 00. •2 C Ni .- a S Oi.eB Nr Z t W101 ml:r C .tom Car e r. r a O ea s r S O Cw .L alr.' E AO N ZrNW W Z.••N .Cr..ZC WJ t. rC C ■ ver a wa W r► Z0 WZ WCZ J0 e. .U W aJ Os er a 2W 2O OW W■ 0W •r N L' -I lbOG W u a C .. a 2WON w War 2 aa aN C .I .A A. a Z a 00001 Oa 0 UW 000 Oa 2W J W2 S e 0N00 5 0 5 6. NN N. 0 . 1 Z aV N . A .N N N M . 0N NI. 1 rap, n 1 th •. .r ►r 1• W •• W 0. W OW ••► 6 •a. •TN W ►w x. W00 .C 6 C Z• [Z ► N P n AN au JJ Jr W.rr WW W Y rZ rZOa a ZO CUri B50 . 0 n . N C O C 0► .. . . 0a ►► <C C Z < Z Z. Staab. 0006. .J0 0w 0 S 0r 00000 N . 010100 ON CP 0W • A NI MW A. 00. .6 C .No 5Mt ► r► ► 2 Z < U U as ► sa ► ►r r► 2'a O< F `W W 5 a a5 a5 a5 ',WOW 2 0202020 01100 WWWW 1a5 Z5. a5 a5 5a ZUOarf WZ0 UZ0 2U0 05001) A► t 0 05 .01 5 0 P O A tN 65 . u N N N N NA O P► .. I O■ WZ Y a .. .ea a35 4 a W N AYZ . aYW 0Y 0& J J In W U 4a W M W O0 1 nAN nn A N A. . I see 0 1 000w AI M WW W .N aerate • cO AN N . N AI Nn ► r ► Z' a a If V V V J lr V V rV WJ a JU W2 O .< aZr CJYY WW N. tV.O.N •2 CZ ~ OU p.. ,,0 . ' ..t. I .S .I 551 . O . . S N N O OI e N Scot .n I N . N N tA 00t5 . N . .. . N . . . 10000 00 .0 ► O c t O C . t I O t- S t . N . O A 0 . nA . t n NM nI . Nnn 0 elat e Of N 0 NPI J• e Jt W ANNWW N P . C A► J J J J ►► ► < aW rr VV JJ ►► ss 6Y 00 ZW rW rr a * JW J WJ W.W L Y W W . W W raW W a W Ua U aA r rU 0 rZUa'r . rZ rZ Y Y Sr Z YW Ua Ur Z Z Z aU OaZ0ao Z a . :00000 . 0 0 0 0 0 00 05055 W a W U a W W r U U W W W W W P O P W O t t N A P St N M N I .O .I A5 N P . N . Nna I. N S I arc It N. 0A nI t. t0 'AO N N. N N a SW Z rW a W YW W Z 2a S WSZNrZ w r r .■ J N WI W a N Nf W . w J J Y(,,) a u 6r O r0 UZ W W W' O aN Z Z t W awNV. N.r W 5Z' JZ V W Y Y Y Y 0 . 0Z0Y0 14.y Y Y Y < W NNN WWW 0 J Z Z ZN.W 12 65 2 0 0 W z ZWNWSNZa 0 .1 . 1 0 . . .. . • N •C 2 Z 2000 2 2 20 O 0Z 00Z O Wr Z Z5=5== ZC SC SS C Z <as 10 U ty 0 2 u C 42 N u u Z 2 2 2 Z 2 • 2 Z 22322 2 2 .r a 0: 00 00 00 00 00 a r a 0S0 0 0 :00020 C 00000 O o00 oVOZ= . .r r r 0 Z z _ S Z 5 2 1 0 Z Z 2 2 2 f N aNt. wear . . 4 11 0 65 0 Z "aura Lbw . ' 1 r e a c t Z00000 0 0da a adad Z Z Z . C o5 6cTa3 s 00000 -------- 0O C 000 .50 0 0 3 2 2 nne Su tW rO u ZWWWW 1110 U U ZZ Z ZTZ 2 O O O r G WW Z W W W WW a da r .ra rC WW TT t.r Zf We . Zw Z O a2 o 2 C G a . .o o a .00 W oCOOO . u 12 u O C V J. 4W 6O. eC r U W < 0 £0500 u 6W Z Z 5022 Z 01.5304530 O c t e tZ==55 0 0 0 0 6 N 6 .. r0 = U~ q b Y t S J L' OS GW Jr C SU C 6 . •.JUN yW W a aS N ..Z t Z YW jW fa2 z ra O0 Y . 0a OY 0 D r .C a .aa 0 r 5 W WJw a M ..C V aC r S o 5 = .!Z W W 2 w' C C z 50000 JS0Z6 S .414 s11JU 2 Wr wW 6C W K N 2 C C . N V yW •• OV r0 R 2 Y NO' a. z ZrVO W N .. =OS wC x J i U 0 a 2 z a O W WT y ► 01.550 W=0 , C Z J10C ►[Tn► Z S r 6. from The Dalles . The report a:ls,o identifies, another 20 million acre-feet o f si orag e , s>i ,tes' i n restricted areas' which-are now • i n wild and scenic, recreation* , or proposed areas . These two lists total about 47 million acrefeet .of potemti .al storage . which compares to the 47 .7 million acre-feet mentioned earlier i n existing storage projects including those in Canada . Malcolm Karr, as Director of Planning of the River Basin s Commission in a recent speech sa-i .d,: . "Among the recognized means to increase water availability o n a timely basis, only that of• additional" story Aeve-lopment ha s the potential to support_ major increases in the level--of wate r use ." May, a a,„ 1'979rt The Corps of Engineers in its 1948 and 1958 review of the 30 8 Reports on the-Columbia called attention to the need for storage . not only fo r re'gion!aT flood' control but also for- local flood' control'oar parti cuTar tri'bu taries . Since 1958, the Treaty projects have completed bring'tng under contro l the* fTo©.ds on'" the main stem- of tWe Columbia . There remai n , the flood risks o n the tributaries -- risks which now prevent or discourage other development an d use . The need for flood control today is on the tributaries : the Methow , Simi l kameen ., Okanogan, Clark Fork-, . FTathea-d, J }lii Day, and many others . In each case, the local improvement from upstream, sltor-age wil l incide.nt~ a~ y. provide both at site and' downstream power be !fi.its., and variou s other benefits which differ from one stream to another . There has been some misunderstanding,about the degree .or completeness of the development of the Columbia River . Development on the. main stem is nearly, finished, bud, on many tributaries we, hi ve not- yet started .. Th e Tennessee Valley Authority completed the dams on the main stem of tfe Tennessee River by about 1950 and then shifted gears- to what . became . known as . TAD, Tributary Area-Development . Electric power-may-or m a not . be an importan t purpose at the projects needed on the key tributaries , More likely, the main interest will be , on flood control, wate r for irrigation, and other purposes with particular emphasis on all forms o f water-oriented recreation and on water quality . Regardless of the purpos e of the tributary projects, the key to development is storage . I- shoul d especially mention one . lesson from TVA expe.rience . . In . the. TVA area, th e . peopl e living in the individual tributary basins organized themselves as an advocac y association which then steered the planning for their subregion or area, pu t forward the program of development, and then provided the political support . The result is to move away from regional centralization to decentralizatio n to: the local area . In summary, I submit that while the main stem of the Columbia i s almost fully developed, there is still storage space on the tributaries, whic h is useful for many purposes . Therefore, the developmental' future of th e Columbia River is on , its tributaries . - 41!