Merchants, mariners and the European wholesale trade in Chinese export wares, c.1720-c.1760 Meike Fellinger (University of Warwick) This paper discusses the informal networks and commercial activities of British mariners in the service of different European East India Companies in the first half of the 18th century. At that time, only few merchants and mariners enjoyed direct access to the profitable trade in Canton. Those who did, however, developed sophisticated trade schemes that allowed them to profit enormously from their private trade allowances, insider knowledge and patronage networks within Company hierarchies. An aspect that has hitherto been ignored is the way in which China traders were also deeply involved in the profitable intra-European trade in Chinese consumer wares. I will argue in this paper that through the scrutiny of private correspondence and account books of merchant seamen we can learn a great deal about the missing link between the arrival of goods from the East in the different Company headquarters and the eventual re-distribution to all parts of Europe. [opening remarks] In my paper today I hope to discuss an important aspect of my PhD research, which explores the private trade activities and informal networks of British captains and supercargoes engaged in the long-distance trade to China in the period between c.1720 to 1760. I shall argue that merchant seamen acted as essential linchpins in a profitable re-export and commission trade by means of which large parts of Europe became integrated into a single market for fine manufactures goods from Asia. This paper grows out of a chapter that I am writing at the moment about the transnational and, at first sight, bewildering links between British mariners (in Company service) and a group of powerful wholesale dealers on the continent – especially in places like Amsterdam, Rotterdam, Hamburg, and Cadiz. Although there are a number of studies by now that discuss the private trade ventures of merchant seamen in the China seas as well as in the Indian Ocean (Erikson/Bearman, Bowen, Tomlinson and a few others), there is very little work done on these men’s trading careers in Europe – especially with regard to the question what they did between voyages! 1 As you might guess, I hope to contribute with my PhD research to closing this gap in the literature by writing about the maritime elite in Europe; which includes an analysis of the nitty-gritty of their business activities and contacts in Europe. The evidence presented today throws light on a number of important issues that have so far escaped the attention of Company historians and scholars of the European luxury trades alike. 1 One exception is a book by Conrad Gill from the early 1960’s. See idem, Merchants and Mariners 1 Firstly, wholesalers exercised direct influence on what was to be supplied from China by placing large-scale orders with supercargoes and captains of East Indiamen who managed to get an appointment for one of the ‘plum voyages’ to Canton. Thus, private trade (which is usually very much marginalised in the Company literature) – became the loophole through which individual merchants could experiment with changing consumer demands. Agreements between members of the maritime elite and one or more merchant houses usually grew out of an already close business relationship between both parties, and has to be seen in the context of the frequent exchange of favours and commitments between them. In this particular constellation, mariners played the role of the mediator or commission agent (who charged a service fee or claimed a share in the sale of the goods). This kind of business partnership will be explored in some depth in this paper by using material from one of my case studies on a Scottish network of Company servants and city-merchants active in Gothenburg, Amsterdam & London. Secondly, the Companies’ maritime elite was far more than carriers of private trade goods that were then sold of at the Companies’ public auctions on their behalf. I maintain that they were substantial merchants in their own right, who developed a highly sophisticated trade in both bulk and fine luxury goods across Europe – including Britain. It is already well-known that private traders catered for niche markets; that is, they brought in goods in which the Company never traded such as wallpaper, lacquerware, porcelain for the top end of the market, fans and heavily embroidered silks. But it is also true that they diversified their interests from early on and always kept a foot in the lucrative but risky trade in cheaper Company goods (such as Bohea & Singlo tea and cheap but fashionable cotton texiles). For instance, one of the findings of my research so far is that captains and supercargoes consistently bought up large parcels of tea and textiles at various Company auctions for their own account. This points, of course, to their double-role as mariners and as merchants, a fact that has escaped even those scholars who have worked specifically on their entrepreneurial activities (Huw Bowen). Their connection to merchant houses on the continent was again vital, since the latter would be used to store and sell the goods on behalf of the more mobile maritime elite. A supercargo turned wholesaler could thus profit from retailing (of speciality goods), but also from re-export of semi-luxuries and more importantly from the smuggling of bulkier goods (such as tea and porcelain) across national boundaries in Europe. Unfortunately, I will not have time to go into any detail here about their illicit activities, even though these were substantial and fill the pages of another chapter of this project. 2 Thirdly, another important pillar of the European trade in Chinese consumer goods for captains and supercargoes alike was that of ‘speculation’, an activity that typically involved the hoarding of particular goods (such as cheap green teas) in order to control supplies and thus retail prices in specific markets (called today: buy-and-hold). Some members of the maritime elite did also engage in short-term speculation, in buying up certain goods in convenient moments when the market was glutted in one place and undersupplied in another (swing trading). This aspect, too, has not yet been discussed in the secondary literature – which makes me very much the slave of my primary sources to piece together information from many different cases in order to get a coherent picture. A key component of speculation is, of course, the trade in information. What becomes clear through the letters between merchants is that the maritime elite often enjoyed first-hand knowledge of what was otherwise kept long secret by the different Companies. This privileged access to commercial information was beneficial for their business and good for their position in mercantile networks, e.g. in London or Amsterdam. Facts like the number of ships that were expected back from the Far East, their envisaged time of arrival and the kind of cargo they had loaded, were ‘hot topics’ among the merchant communities involved in that trade, since such ‘intelligence’ always caused excitement for some and anxiety to others. Writing from Hamburg in July 1759, Charles Metcalfe, a Scot and retired captain who seemed to suffer from his landsman existence, informed his principal Charles Irvine (himself a supercargo) that ‘The Arrival of your Ships [that belonged to the SEIC fleet] has cast a great Damp on the Spirits of our Speculative Chaps’. From Metcalfe, we learn that following the news, most merchants in Hamburg tried to dispose off their old teas immediately, which in turn caused the prices to drop ‘from mouth to mouth’. He advises Irvine about the reasons for this herd behaviour amongst Hamburg tea dealers: as he knows that there is still ‘a good many old Teas in Town & tho they are mostly in fast Hands [that is in the hand of brokers], yet it must be from an Apprehension of the new Teas maybe of a superior Quality’. This might be why his neighbours ‘seem determined to clear their warehouses’ despite seeing their profits melting away. Metcalfe, who had been previously informed by his friend of the actual qualities that would come in via Gothenburgh, wisely waited a little longer before disposing his fine teas – still being able to report a handsome profit for Irvine’s account. This sort of gambling, and the crucial gathering of rumours and facts, was part of a merchants’ business. And I should not forget to mention – the reason for some dramatic cases of bancruptcy! But in general, the maritime elite (and with them their close associates) profited from having reliable 3 information and often superior knowledge about the qualities of goods to be had, and the exact timing of Company auctions. This became and continued to be a distinct advantage for the European leg of their trade. The ways in which such information was pooled and shared within a more intimate circle of merchants thus helps to illuminate the crucial position that the maritime elite held within different merchant communities. Informal networks and ‘insider knowledge’ Intelligence, as a crucial component of speculative trading was a the central concerns in letters that were send back and forth between city merchants and the Companies’ maritime elite. Crucially, details on Company and private cargoes (of different nations) were often send back to Europe whilst supercargoes and ships’ officers still dwelled in Canton and then again when they reached a port where they took on provisions on the return-leg of their voyage. Since voyages by sea bore considerable risks, regular reports on the state of the ship, its passengers and weather conditions were communicated as soon possibilities arose. The Companies directors knew about the chatty character of their seafaring crowd and wisely kept in touch with powerful merchants on the continent who were able to pool information from employees of different East India Companies. George Clifford & Sons, Thomas Wilkinson and Pye & Cruikshank in Amsterdam – were all at times correspondents of the Court of Directors in London and at the same time important players in the wholesale trade. Charles and James Gough, merchant bankers in Cadiz readily reported back to Gothenburgh about incoming and outgoing ships and their investments. The role of Company agents still lacks more research – but seems to have been a tool used by all chartered Companies. Clifford, who sends every now and then a cask of dried fish to the EIC headquarter most have gained some kind of renumeration Intelligence was extremely important when a ship lost its passage (for instance, due to the Monsoon winds) and had to stay in India for a season. In addition, warfare, piracy, shipwreck and other hazards of the sea added considerably to the chance of loosing one’s ships and entire cargo – a possibility that had tangible effects on supplies in Europe. In fact, markets in the eighteenth century sufferent considerably from supply variations – a condition that probably helped generate a pan-European arena of trade, rich opportunities for speculation as well as a need for individual merchants to find ways for reducing the uncertainties of the market through commercial strategies and efficient networking. What concrete strategies of risk reduction were applied by private traders will be discussed after this excursion into the role of information networks between city merchants and mariners. What is clear, however, is 4 that access to ‘insider knowledge’ was vital for merchants dealing in Chinese consumer goods. In fact, every little piece of information that was to be had through private correspondence, but also via newspaper announcements, rumours and meetings at the local coffeehouses was judged, discussed and widely shared through transnational trading networks, a fact that makes it difficult to see the neatly isolated markets that mercantilist ideals suggest to have existed. In reality, wholesale prices in the Amsterdam market were usually affected by information about the cargoes that were thought to arrive in Lorient, Copenhagen and London in the same season. This is equally true for other entrepôts on the continent and the British Isles. This interconnectedness of markets is partly to be explained by the ‘unbounded behaviour’ of early modern merchants – the countless ways in which merchants and mariners operated across national boundaries and beneath the mercantilist system. The uncertainties of the market The intra-European trade in tea and drugs from China can be usefully compared with the nature of the cowry market of that period (a product that came almost exclusively from the Maldives and was used as currency in some societies on the west coast of Africa). The dynamics behind this trade has been well described by economists Jan Hogendorn and Marion Johnson in their interdisciplinary study entitled The Shell Money of the Slave Trade. Similar to the case of tea and other products such as rhubarb and raw silk, the authors noted the great supply variations in the cowrie trade. Yearly shifts in supplies from the East Indies often forced merchants to travel overland to several European company auctions in order to buy up stocks in secret to fulfill their orders. Thomas Wilkinson, a Scottish merchant who was based in Amsterdam acted as one of the principal agents of the Royal African Company in the 1720’s when a sudden shortage of cowries put him into distress. In 1723, his principals in London asked him to purchase at least 70 tonnes of cowries for shipment to the Guinea Coast where they would be exchanged for slaves for the New World plantation economies. But as it turned out, there were very little cowries brought back by the Dutch and English East India Companies that year. The authors describe in detail how Wilkinson ended up buying chest by chest from suppliers across Europe and having to travel to different auctions to get hold of larger lots – always followed by competitors who sought to assemble a similar parcell of cowries for the Dutch West India Company, the Portuguese and French trading ventures. Wilkinson, desperate to assemble the quantity needed wrote back to London about his plans to look on the private market where I ‘shall go on picking up quietly what [I] can find’.2 2 Thomas Wilkieson to ??? quoted by Jan Hogendorn and Marion Johnson, p.95. 5 Similar scenarios happened in the re-export trade of tea and other goods which had to be imported from China - a branch of business with which Thomas Wilkieson was very familiar. He sold large parcels of tea on commission basis for Captain Thomas Hall (former Ostend trader and later one of the leading contractors of English East India Company ships), the brothers Alexander and Abraham Hume (ship-owners in London) as well as some Scottish supercargoes who operated under Swedish flag. His suppliers and clients were mostly German, Dutch, French, Flemish and British and his portfolio was typically varied with interests in the East Indies, Atlantic and European coastal trade in addition to his role as a banker. To make this point clear, it would be deeply misleading to think that British Company servants and city-merchants bought tea, porcelain and textiles only for domestic consumers. Quite the opposite is true. As we have seen, China traders made extensive use of commercial agents abroad who sold goods on their behalf and provided often precise information about local market conditions. In turn, the maritime elite acted as agents as well – buying on order – for ciy-merchants with particular markets in mind. In sum, the two groups described here became ever more entangled in the course of the eigheenth century and clearly relied upon each others’ information networks and different trading expertises. As far as I can tell from the analysis of Company sales records and private correspondence, the trade in Chinese consumer goods was in the first half of the eighteenth century in the hand of a relatively small group of big players to which mariners and city-merchants both belonged. I would even argue that this mutual dependency of both groups in terms of capital, intelligence and the making of markets for new commodities or qualities is crucial for understanding the nature of private trade in this period. Wholesellers always kept an eye on the remaining stock of particular goods in town and reported on every little shift in taste and responded accordingly in chosing the right way of selling. Mariners provided timely information about the cargoes and even marked particular lots/ or chests of Company and private trade goods well in adance of the public auctions. Their privilege buying right allowed them to ‘cherry pick’ for their own account and a number of intimate trading partners who had their premises scattered across Europe. Through this little introduction to some of the key topics discussed in my chapter I have tried to demonstrate that supercargoes and captains were active in all branches of the wholesale trade, a fact that should led us to rethink their better role as mariners and Company servants. In the minutes remaining I would like to discuss some of the mechanisms that were in place through which wholesalers could exercise an influence on what was brought in via the private trade. I will be looking at large-scale commissions as an instrument for reducing risks, in 6 creating an advantage over competitors and in shaping fashions for certain goods. I will be focusing on silk textiles. Until here… In my paper today, I will focus on the relationship between the Companies’ own maritime elite and a group of city-merchants (who are sometimes described as wholesalers, sometimes as financiers, since they fulfilled both functions) by using material from one of my case studies. The exchange between these two groups has to be imagined as an ongoing ‘dialogue’ of experts that does not lack frictions or misunderstandings. Clearly, China traders felt that they were the arbiters in matters of taste. At the same time, also wholesalers claimed expertise with regard to the quality, packaging and pricing of goods for specific markets. These written conversations that were upheld by the exchange of letters (sometimes on a weekly basis) provide clues to the points I have mentioned in the introduction. Consider one case, Charles Irvine, a Scotsmen and Jacobite, who learnt his trade in Rouen as apprentice of a Scottish wine merchant (Arbuthnot&Co) with links to the English East India Company. He went to the Far East in his early twenties when working as a petty officer for the Ostend Company – which was then a newly established East India Company who sailed under the protection of the Habsburg dynasty from the Austrian Netherlands. This interloper had attracted the capital, expertise and workforce from both English and Dutch East India Company circles, and was hugely successful in the short time of its existence. After the definite dissolution of the Company after the Treaty of Vienna in 1731, its successor was swiftly put in place, this time under the Swedish flag. Operating from Gothenburg, the Swedish East India Company was founded in the same year in which Ostend stopped to send ships for good by Colin Campbell, Hendrik König and Nicholas Sahlgren – (a Scot, a Swede and a German) and had a noticeable group of British and most conspicuously Scottish merchant seamen working for them. (Unclear sentence) Irvine was made supercargo and later chief-supercargo (Q: what’s the difference?) of at least six voyages. His close friend and business associate Colin Campbell was (as I mentioned) one of the directors of the Company until his death in 1757. These partnerships between merchants and mariners took the form of large-scale commissions by means of which capital for the purchase was provided beforehand by the city-merchant. In turn, Company servants promised that they would use their privileged buying right at Company auctions in order to secure the commissioned lot at previously arranged terms. These kind of transactions were one of the mechanisms used by merchants and mariners to 7 complement eachothers expertise and privileges. The commission trade usually grew out of long-lasting business relationship between merchants and mariners and has thus to be seen in the context of a range of other committments and favours regularly exchanged by both parties. Wholesalers provided insider knowledge on potential markets, price elasticity and local taste – an expertise that very few merchant seamen had because of their great mobility. These market insights were transmitted in written form, often with material artefacts such as fabric samples attached to them. lists with the goods needed for specific markets that they new well – i.e the detailed the assortment of silk fabrics with regard to their physical properties such as colour, quality and patterns and provided patterns on paper to ease the communication with Chinese merchants and painters. Hitherto ignored by Company historians and historians of early modern European trade alike, this I argue that city merchants on the continent sought to influence the market and thus the supply of specific goods and qualities from China by entering in business (and personal) relationships with the highly mobile class of ships’ officers and supercargoes of East Indiamen. This partnership had distinct advantages for all parties. Both groups could rely on (sometimes overlapping) but vital information networks and brought to this marriage a distinct set of experiences, trading expertise and practical were extremely well-positioned to become substantial traders in their own right in Europe – profiting from a curious mix of personal experience, superior intelligence and substantial private trade privileges granted by the Company in order to secure their ‘loyalty’. By analysing the European trading activities of Company supercargoes and captains we gain a more nuanced picture of the relationship between Company and private trade, the mechnisms of re-distribution intended to answer what actually happened with the goods (belonging to the Companies’ or their servants) that were sold publicly at Company auctions after the fleets returned to the Company headquarters after roughly two years of voyage. The actual trading season in Canton the only Chinese ports where Europeans were allowed to establish their factories was limited to five months of the year by the changing monsoon winds. The European ships arrived negotiated with a small group of privileged Chinese merchants (known as hong-merchants) with whom they placed their orders of all the goods and qualities that the Company had a particular interest. Furthermore, they contracted for goods that 8 Merchants and mariners who plied the Eastern seas in the service of various European East India Companies conducted extensive private trade using Company ressources and infrastructure to accumulate goods that could later be sold at considerable profit in different markets in Asia and Europe. Their commercial activities were known and largely tolerated by their employers – knowing that only relative freedom of trade would prevent these fortuneseekers from any steps that would harm the Company’s performance. 9