This article was downloaded by: [University of Warwick] On: 06 January 2012, At: 05:26 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Journal of the History of Economic Thought Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cjht20 The Tercentenary Of Henry Martyn's Considerations Upon The East-India Trade Andrea Maneschi Available online: 03 Aug 2010 To cite this article: Andrea Maneschi (2002): The Tercentenary Of Henry Martyn's Considerations Upon The East-India Trade, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 24:2, 233-249 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10427710220134385 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Full terms and conditions of use: http://www.tandfonline.com/page/ terms-and-conditions This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. The publisher does not give any warranty express or implied or make any representation that the contents will be complete or accurate or up to date. The accuracy of any instructions, formulae, and drug doses should be independently verified with primary sources. The publisher shall not be liable for any loss, actions, claims, proceedings, demand, or Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 costs or damages whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with or arising out of the use of this material. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, Volume 24, Number 2, 2002 Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 THE TERCENTENARY OF HENRY MARTYN’S CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE BY ANDREA MANESCHI I. INTRODUCTION Henry Martyn’s Consideration s Upon the East-India Trade, published anonymously in 1701, stands out as a major contribution to the ® eld of political economy that took root in Britain in the eighteenth century, and to the demonstration of the gains from free trade (Martyn 1701). Martyn provided one of the earliest formulations (and by far the clearest) of what Jacob Viner termed the ``eighteenthcentury rule’ ’ for the gains from trade, that ``it pays to import commodities from abroad whenever they can be obtained in exchange for exports at a smaller real cost than their production at home would entail’ ’ (Viner 1937, p. 440). The numerical examples that Martyn used to illustrate it went even beyond the case for free trade advanced seventy-® ve years later by Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations. Martyn’s tract contains other remarkable insights that became important features of classical political economy, such as the nature and advantages of the division of labor, the dependence of the latter on the extent of the market, the workings of a market economy, the role of money, and the impact of international trade on resource allocation, on productivity, and on economic welfare. After being forgotten for a century and a half, the Consideration s Upon the East-India Trade was reprinted in 1856 by John R. McCulloch as one of eight early English tracts on commerce dating from 1621 to 1701, which included Dudley North’s celebrated Discourses upon Trade of 1691 (McCulloch 1856). In the Preface, after commenting that ``notwithstanding the deference so justly due to North, [the Considerations] probably also is the ablest and most profound’ ’ of the tracts in his volume, McCulloch ventured the opinion that ``we have sometimes been half inclined to suppose that it might have proceeded from the pen of Mr. Henry Martin, who contributed some papers to the Spectator’ ’ (pp. xiii, xv). Martyn (whose name is alternatively spelled Martin) was a lawyer Department of Economics, Vanderbilt University, Nashville, TN, USA. The author is grateful to Tony Aspromourgos, Melvin Cross, and two anonymous referees for useful comments on an earlier draft of this paper. ISSN 1042-7716 print; ISSN 1469-9656 online/02/020233-1 7 © 2002 The History of Economics Society DOI: 10.1080 /1042771022013438 5 Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 234 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT and an able writer who in 1715 became Inspector-General of Exports and Imports in a Whig government and died in 1721. 1 P. J. Thomas (1926) went further than McCulloch and argued convincingly that ``on various grounds it seems highly probable that Henry Martyn was the author of the tract.’ ’ According to him, ``the best exposition of the Free Trade view during this period (and perhaps until the time of Adam Smith) is contained in the Considerations . . . the ® rst work to tackle some of the fundamental questions of economics in a scienti® c spirit. It is head and shoulders above the economic writings of that age; and it doubtless deserves a place among the masterpieces of English Political Economy’ ’ (Thomas 1926, pp. 89, 93± 94). Viner (1937) mentioned ``the author of Consideration s on the East-India Trade’ ’ several times in his book, particularly in connection with the ``eighteenth-century rule’’ for the gains from trade. In a paragrap h devoted to mercantilist writers who presented free-trade arguments, he argued that ``it requires only mildly generous interpretation to justify the conclusion that they approached more closely than did Adam Smith the high point of free-trade reasoning, the statement of the bene® t of regional specialization in terms of comparative advantage.’ ’ 2 These writers include the ``unknown author’ ’ of the Considerations, who ``reveals almost no trace of the mercantilist or protectionist fallacies’’ (p. 104). After quoting the passage of that tract formulating the eighteenth-century rule, Viner noted that the tract ``does not appear to have exerted any in¯ uence on contemporary writers.’ ’ Both Thomas (1926, p. 94) and Viner (1937, p. 105) proved that the attribution of the authorship of the Considerations by some writers to Dudley North could not be correct. While McCulloch, Thomas, and Viner lavished praise on Martyn, E. A. J. Johnson (1937, p. 348) poured scorn on him by alleging that ``a great many ideas and some of the language of the Considerations were copied directly from the writings of Sir William Petty. This is what one would expect from a hired journalist! Thomas failed to notice the plagiarism and has given undeserved praise to the author of the Considerations for originality.’ ’ Johnson’s primary interest in Martyn, however, was in his role as writer for The Spectator and for The British Merchant, publications that asked him to argue the Whig viewpoint against lowering Britain’s restrictions on trade with France. His apparent volteface with respect to the free trade views expressed in the Considerations can be explained on political grounds (see section V). 3 A diVerent view was expressed by Max Beer (1938, p. 217), who referred to Martyn as ``the most valued contributor to the British Merchant . . . to whom some writers are inclined to ascribe the authorship of the Consideration s on the East India Trade.’’ 4 1 For details of Martyn’s life, works, and likely authorship of the Considerations, see Thomas (1926, Appendix B) and MacLeod (1983). 2 Several commentators besides Viner claim that Martyn came close to formulating (or actually formulated) the Ricardian principle of comparative advantage. This claim is examined in section IV. 3 Both Thomas (1926, pp. 171± 73) and MacLeod (1983, p. 225) examine the issue of the consistency of Martyn’s views. The separate issue of Martyn’s indebtedness to Petty and of his alleged plagiarism is discussed in section III. 4 After comparing the rationales for free trade expressed by Martyn and Charles Davenant on the one hand, and Dudley North on the other, Beer (p. 212) concluded that ``North gave only the ® nal Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 235 In the past ® fty years, Martyn’s Considerations was evaluated at some length by Marcus Arkin (1955), William J. Barber (1975), Christine MacLeod (1983), Terence W. Hutchison (1988), and Douglas A. Irwin (1996). A unique perspective is oVered in British Economic Thought and India 1600 ± 1858: A Study in the History of Development Economics (Barber 1975), where an entire chapter is devoted to Martyn’s Considerations. According to Barber, the latter was inspired by the radically new ``master model’ ’ of economic development that took shape in Britain in the 1690s, marking the transition from the commercial revolution of the seventeenth century to the industrial revolution of the eighteenth. The earlier vision of economic development re¯ ected in Thomas Mun’s tracts, where the pro® ts earned in international trade were reinvested in working capital so as to expand this trade even further, was becoming obsolete. The monopoly exercised by the East India Company restricted this trade, and the Company was increasingly importing into Britain textiles that competed with domestic manufactures, rather than commodities such as spices designed for re-export to other countries. 5 These changed conditions required a new vision expressed, ® rst and foremost, in Martyn’s Considerations. Its focus shifted from the importance of international trade to England, to the need to increase its domestic real income. Trade had a strategic role to play since it allowed the import of products, such as Indian textiles, that could be produced much more cheaply overseas, thus releasing labor and capital for more productive uses. Free trade was thus prized for its instrumental role in promoting economic development via an appropriat e reallocation of resources. Although the authorship of the Considerations was attributed to Martyn (with varying degrees of certainty) by several of the above writers, Christine MacLeod (1983) was the ® rst to provide incontrovertibl e evidence that Martyn was indeed the author. 6 She examines inter alia how Martyn’s political associations colored his writings, and why the Considerations failed to have a greater impact on the burgeoning ® eld of political economy. The pioneering character of Martyn’s Considerations has more recently been recognized by Hutchison (1988) and Irwin (1996). On the tercentenary of the Considerations, it is ® tting to reconsider Henry Martyn’s tract. Section II examines its structure, and section III notes its many anticipations of classical economics as set out in Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations. Section IV analyzes what may be Martyn’s chief claim to fame, his formulation of the eighteenth-century rule for the gains from trade. Section V attempts an overall evaluation of Martyn’s remarkable tract and explores the reasons for its apparently small impact on the evolving science of political economy. results of his cogitations, without revealing the inductive material of his observations, nor the train of reasoning that led up to them,’ ’ while Davenant and Martyn ``dealt with the main factors of their doctrine.’ ’ 5 The concerns of British textile weavers are epitomized in the title of John Pollexfen’s tract of 1697, England and East India Inconsistent in Their Manufacture s, being an Answer to a Treatise Intituled an Essay on the East-India Trade. 6 John Locke’s papers include a letter of 1701 from the publisher of the Considerations stating that he was forwarding that tract on the instruction of Martyn, who wished to present it to him. 236 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 II. STRUCTURE OF HENRY MARTYN’S CONSIDERATIONS Henry Martyn’s Considerations consists of a preface, an extended table of contents, and eighty-one pages of text divided into twenty-two chapters. In the ® rst chapter, Martyn articulated a panoply of objections that had been raised to the East India trade, particularly that it resulted in (1) the export of bullion by England to pay for Indian manufactures; (2) a higher unemployment in England created by the diversion of demand to Indian imports; and (3) a decrease in landholders’ rents due to a fall in demand for the produce of their estates. The three alleged objections to the East India trade are sequentially rebutted in chapters 2 through 17. Chapters 2 through 9 rebut the ® rst objection by arguing that the exchange of bullion for Indian manufactures amounts to ``an exchange of less for greater value,’’ despite the destruction of some English manufactures. Martyn asserted that the export of bullion to India eventually brought even more bullion to England thanks to re-exports, an argument already made by Thomas Mun and others in the previous century. 7 The country was enriched by the establishment of a second East India Company, replacing the monopoly of the old Company. 8 This occurred despite a decline in the rate of pro® t and despite the restrictions imposed by some governments on English reexports of Indian manufactures. Martyn argued that the idleness of the mint for many years was more than oVset by an increase in paper money. Chapters 10± 13 respond to the second objection related to the increased unemployment and associated destruction of English manufactures caused by the East India trade. Chapter 10 contains the formulation of the eighteenthcentury rule for the gains from trade quoted and examined below in section IV. Martyn argued that no employment was lost that was worth keeping, and no pro® table manufactures were destroyed by the East India trade. In fact the latter generated more rather than less domestic employment, both in existing manufactures, by reducing their prices and raising demand for them, and through the creation of new industries. These industries were encouraged (p. 42) by the technological change (``Arts, and Mills, and Engines, which save the labour of Hands’ ’ ) stimulated by the East India trade (``the eVects of Necessity and Emulation’ ’ ). Martyn stressed that although prices were reduced by free trade, wages were not, so that labor was better oV than before. In describing the introduction of ``more Order and Regularity into our English Manufactures,’’ he devoted several pages of chapter 12 to describing the remarkable eVects of the division of labor on productivity in the clothing, watch, and shipping industries 7 If Martyn really believed that the exchange of bullion for Indian manufactures was ``an exchange of less for greater value,’ ’ why should he want to argue that the exported bullion would return to England in greater quantities? His reasoning may have been politically motivated, to make the argument for greater freedom of trade more palatable to his mercantilist audience. Even more probable is the fact that Martyn, as evidenced by his later contributions to The British Merchant, never gave up his bullionist tendencies. 8 After a decade of confused political events that followed the Glorious Revolution of 1688, a ``new’ ’ East India Company was created in 1698 by an Act of Parliament in order to deprive the ``old’ ’ Company of its former monopoly in the East India trade. On the momentous changes in the structure and functions of the East India Company over the two and a half centuries of its existence, and the political and economic events that shaped them, see Barber (1975) and Lawson (1993). Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 237 (see section III). The East India trade is given pride of place for its role in stimulating the development of skills and the invention of machines in these and other industries. Martyn admitted that trade also results in the displacement of labor from industries that cannot compete with imports, but transformed this apparent drawback into a virtue by observing that the displaced labor is thereby freed to ® nd more productive employment elsewhere in the economy. 9 He noted repeatedly that trade has eVects analogous to those of technical progress, which usually also leads to an initial increase in unemployment. 1 0 To be consistent, opponents of the East India trade should also advocate the destruction of all labor-saving devices, and the return to methods of production abandoned long ago. Martyn pushed his reductio ad absurdum even further by suggesting (pp. 32± 33) that such people should also decline to accept gifts from abroad (or corn appearing like manna from heaven), since the consumption of these goods may throw the producers of similar commodities out of work. Chapters 14± 17 answer the third objection against the East India tradeÐ that it reduces land rents. Martyn used a primitive version of the quantity theory of money to explain that the fall in prices leading to a fall in rents resulted from a reduction in the money supply combined with an increase in the volume of transactions, including those relating to imports. Even though a landholder loses his monopoly, Martyn expected the demand for the produce of his estate to rise more than the supply, leading to an increase in price. The labor force on the estates would become more eYcient, leading to an increase in output that makes landowners no worse oV than before. One of pre-eminent issues that agitated English pamphleteers in the second half of the seventeenth century was the economic success of the Dutch Republic and the dominance of the Dutch in the ® shing industry. They sought to explain the formula underlying this success, and to prescribe policies that would allow Britain to catch up economically with Holland. 1 1 Chapters 18± 22 of the Considerations consist of a digression on the ® shing industry, which Martyn used as a case study for the lessons he wished to draw from his tract. He argued that at that time the ® shing trade was not as pro® table in England as the importation of Irish cattle or Indian manufactures, and he criticized writers claiming that it should be arti® cially encouraged on infant-industry grounds. Holland had acquired an overwhelming advantage over England in the herring trade through lower expenses in catching and curing ® sh, a more expeditious legal system, a lower interest rate resulting from an abundant money supply, greater skills in the construction and sailing of ships, a superior transportation infrastructure, a skilled and disciplined work force, and the invention of appropriate ``Arts and 9 Marian Bowley (1973, p. 33) names this eVect of foreign trade the ``resource allocation thesis’’ of mercantilist writers in the second half of the seventeenth century, and associates it with Dudley North and ``still more clearly in relation to the export of bullion in 1701’’ with the Considerations. 1 0 Martyn thus anticipated economists such as David Ricardo (1817), who noted that trade and technical progress have similar eVects since both cheapen commodities and cause labor to be reallocated among sectors. 1 1 On the interpretations of the commercial and economic prowess of Holland by the English pamphleteers, see Thomas (1926, pp. 85± 88) and Appleby (1978, chapter 4). 238 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 Engines.’’ The only way for the English to compete would be to become more like the Dutch, for example, by being content with the lower rates of pro® t and interest found in Holland. 1 2 Martyn adroitly used the widespread popular desire to acquire a competitive ® shing industry to drive home the conclusions he had drawn in the preceding parts of his tract, such as the importance of promoting ``an universal Freedom of Trade’ ’ (p. 69). In the last chapter he went even further, by proposing the establishment in England of a Free-Port allowing duty-free imports and exports. Economies of agglomeration, such as having workers live in close proximity to each other, would also reduce costs in the ® shing trade. III. HENRY MARTYN’S ANTICIPATIONS OF ADAM SMITH’S THE WEALTH OF NATIONS The East India trade featured prominently in many of the numerous tracts published in England in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. In The Economic History of England, Ephraim Lipson noted that the economic issues surrounding this trade ``played a leading role in the development of economic thought prior to Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations.’ ’ 1 3 In his survey of the English theories of foreign trade before Adam Smith, Viner argued that ``if Adam Smith had carefully surveyed the earlier English economic literature, including, however, tracts apparently always obscure and already scarce by his time, he would have been able to ® nd very nearly all the materials which he actually used in his attack on the protectionist aspects of the mercantilist doctrine.’’ While cautioning his readers that the extent to which free trade views prevailed in the mercantilist literature has often been exaggerated , Viner listed Martyn with four others as ``the only writers prior to Adam Smith whom I have found who seem really to have been free traders’’ (1937, p. 92). In this section I plan to trace the similarities between concepts found in Martyn’s Considerations and in The Wealth of Nations, to gauge to what extent Martyn can be regarded as an anticipator of Adam Smith. As any reader of Hutchison (1988) knows, Smith had a legion of anticipators, among whom Martyn was not pre-eminent. 1 4 Without claiming that Smith ever read Martyn’s tract, it is nevertheless sobering to list and ponder over the numerous anticipations of The Wealth of Nations found in the Considerations. In certain respects, as argued below, Martyn goes farther than Smith, and should not be regarded as a mere anticipator. In other respects, he made use of concepts formulated before him, and should rather be regarded as a connecting link in the ® liation of economic ideas. For example, his indebtedness to William Petty is clear from the ® rst sentence of the preface of the Considerations, where he warns the reader that ``most of the things in these Papers are directly contrary to the receiv’d Opinions . . . instead of using only comparative and superlative Words to amuse 1 2 Josiah Child and other writers preceded Martyn in attributing Dutch primacy to economic factors such as low interest rates. 1 3 As cited by Barber (1975, p. 26). 1 4 A referee has pointed out that Smith was, after all, not such an original thinker! Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 239 the Reader, the Author has endeavour’d after the manner of the Political Arithmetick, to express himself in Terms of Number, Weight, and Measure.’ ’ 1 5 Martyn elaborates at great length on the division of labor, without using that term. 1 6 He mentions all three of the main attributes of the division of labor identi® ed by Smith: the increase in productivity due to the allocation of diVerent tasks to diVerent workers, the advantages of technical innovations and machinery (``Invention of Arts and Engines,’ ’ p. 39), and ``less loss of time and labour’ ’ (p. 45) when tasks are divided. 1 7 Martyn attributes these eVects to the East India trade, whose justi® cation was his principal reason for writing the Considerations. He anticipated what Myint (1958, p. 318) labeled Smith’s ``productivity’’ theory of international trade, according to which the division of labor, which depends on the extent of the market, is enhanced when an export market is added to the domestic one. According to Martyn, once inventions are adopted, ``Necessity and Emulation’’ lead to their diVusion to other producers, which highlights the role of a competitive market economy in the promotion of economic development (p. 42). Three paragraph s extending over two pages describe in detail how the division of labor operates in clothing, watchmaking, and the shipping industry. Indeed, within the shipping industry, labor is divided diVerently in producing one hundred ton ships and ® ve hundred ton ships. With regard to watchmaking and shipping, Martyn adds the important proviso to which Smith devoted chapter 3 of Book One of The Wealth of Nations, that the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. 1 8 Smith concluded chapter 1 of Book One of The Wealth of Nations by commenting on the ``many thousands’’ of laborers whose work contributes to the clothing and household furniture used by ``the very meanest person in a civilized country,’ ’ and to the tools used to make them. The result is that ``the accommodation of an European prince does not always so much exceed that of an industrious and frugal peasant, as the accommodation of the latter exceeds that of many an African king, the absolute master of the lives and liberties of ten thousand naked savages’’ (Smith 1776, pp. 23± 24). This can be compared to Martyn’s statement that: 1 5 This statement, unaccompanied by any reference to Petty, may have led E. A. J. Johnson (1937) to conclude that Martyn (as stated above) had plagiarized Petty’s writings in the Considerations. Arkin (1955, p. 300) dismisses this allegation with an exclamation mark, and Tony Aspromourgos, in private correspondence, also disagrees with it. 1 6 In the preface to his book, McCulloch (1856, p. xiv) argues that Martyn ``has set the powerful in¯ uence of the division of labour in a very striking point of view, and has illustrated it with a skill and felicity which even Smith has not surpassed, but by which he most probably pro® ted.’’ Similarly, after citing the paragraph where Martyn describes in detail the division of labor in watchmaking, Thomas (1926, p. 92) comments that ``one may compare this with similar passages of Adam Smith, and yet may not ® nd much to the advantage of the latter.’’ 17 Martyn denotes by ``Order and Regularity’’ a more eYcient allocation of labor to separate tasks, and observes that when workers are displaced from occupations in which they are ``useless and unpro® table,’’ they will enter ``others the most plain and easie, or to the single Parts of other Manufactures of most variety; for plain and easie work is soonest learn’d, and Men are more perfect and expeditious in it’’ (p. 42). 1 8 ``If the Demand of Watches shou’d become so very great as to ® nd constant imployment for as many Persons as there are Parts in a Watch . . .’’ (p. 43) is the conditional statement preceding the allocation of tasks in the watch industry, and a similar statement is used for shipping (p. 44). 240 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 among the wild Indians of America, almost every thing is the Labourer’s, ninety nine Parts of an hundred are to be put upon the account of Labour: In England, perhaps the Labourer has not two thirds of all the conveniences of Life, but then the plenty of these things is so much greater here, that a King of India is not so well lodg’d, and fed, and cloath’d, as a Day-laboure r of England (Martyn 1701, pp. 45± 6). 1 9 It has become a commonplace to observe that the advantages of the division of labor were analyzed by many writers before Adam Smith. The editors of the Glasgow edition of The Wealth of Nations recognize William Petty for providing in 1690 ``the ® rst considered exposition of the term division of labour by a modern writer’ ’ (Smith 1776, p. 13). They note the later elaborations of the same concept (after the Considerations had been published) by Bernard Mandeville, Joseph Harris, and E. A. G. Turgot, but do not mention the Considerations itself. Salim Rashid (1998) also identi® es Petty as a precursor of Smith, and observes that the three examples that Petty used (clothing, shipping, and watchmaking) appear as well in Martyn’s Considerations. 2 0 One of Smith’s principal messages in The Wealth of Nations is that wealth consists of the ``consumable goods annually reproduced by the labour of the society’ ’ (1776, p. 678), and not of precious metals as interpreted by mercantilist writers. One of the best-known aphorisms in The Wealth of Nations is that ``consumption is the sole end and purpose of all production; and the interest of the producer ought to be attended to, only so far as it may be necessary for promoting that of the consumer’ ’ (p. 660). This is consistent with the way Martyn de® ned a nation’s wealth: The true and principal Riches, whether of private Persons, or of whole Nations, are Meat, and Bread, and Cloaths, and Houses, the Convenience s as well as Necessaries of Life; the several Re® nements and Improvements of these, the secure Possession and Enjoyment of them. These for their own sakes, Money, because `twill purchase these, are to be esteemed Riches; so that Bullion is only secondary and dependant, Cloaths and Manufactures are real and principal Riches (1701, p. 10). While Martyn was not alone among the writers of that period who rede® ned wealth as consisting of consumable goods, his description of bullion as ``secondary and dependant’ ’ was a clear rejection of the mercantilist dogma of the primacy of precious metals among all forms of wealth, as explicit as many similar statements made by Adam Smith. Martyn maintained that the export of bullion to the East Indies in exchange for manufactures, as practiced by the East India company, was a free act of exchange, and hence ``an Exchange of less for greater value’ ’ (p. 11). 1 9 The ® rst part of Martyn’s statement should be compared to Smith’s contention in chapter 6 of Book One of The Wealth of Nations that in the ``early and rude state of society . . . the whole produce of labour belongs to the labourer,’’ but that as soon as stock has accumulated and all the land has been appropriated, the labourer is obliged to share part of the produce of his labour with the owner of stock and with the landlord (Smith 1976, pp. 65± 68). 2 0 Rashid recognizes that Martyn went beyond Petty when he made the division of labor conditional on the extent of the market. After referring to the example of pin-making which Smith appears to have drawn from the French Encyclope die, he comments that ``Smith’s treatment of the division of labor shows some de® nite improvement in formulation and clarity but is disappointing in its treatment of possible sources’ ’ (Rashid 1998, p. 18). Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 241 In his discussio n of pro® ts in The Wealth of Nations, Smith observed that as a colony develops, both the rate of pro® t and the rate of interest gradually decline. However, ``the wages of labour do not sink with the pro® ts of stock.’ ’ The reason is that ``a great stock, though with small pro® ts, generally increases faster than a small stock with great pro® ts’ ’ (1776, pp. 109± 10). Martyn employed similar reasoning. Despite the fact that the competition between two East India companies had lowered the pro® t rate, he claimed that the volume of pro® ts had nonetheless risen: ``’tis better and more pro® table for the Kingdom, that 300l. ( 5 £300) should be imployed in Trade for the pro® t of 10 per Cent. than but 100l. for the pro® t of 20 per Cent. wherefore, less in proportion and more in quantity, must be esteem’d as greater pro® t’’ (Martyn 1701, p. 13). Martyn observes repeatedly that the invention of ``Arts and Engines’ ’ spurred by the East India trade reduces the price of manufactures without reducing wages. ``That this thing may not seem a Paradox,’’ he explains, ``the East-India Trade may be the cause of doing things with less Labour, and then tho’ Wages shou’d not, the price of Manufactures might be abated’ ’ (p. 41). 2 1 He states that the ``price of Labour’’ has declined while leaving wages unchanged, using that rather confusing term to denote the labor embodied in manufacturing output. 2 2 A similar point was made by Smith in The Wealth of Nations: ``there are many commodities . . . which, in consequence of these improvements, come to be produced by so much less labour than before, that the increase of its price is more than compensated by the diminution of its quantity’’ (Smith 1776, p. 104). In that sentence, of course, Smith used the term ``price,’ ’ referring to labor, as a synonym for wage rather than in Martyn’s sense of that term. 2 3 Another similarity between Martyn and Smith, and a point of diVerence between them and many mercantilist writers, is that far from wanting to reduce wages to enhance England’s competitiveness in world markets, both regarded an increase in real wages as the economy develops as a natural (and, for Smith, an equitable) outcome. 2 4 Whether this was suYcient, in Martyn’s case, to allay workers’ fears concerning the impact of the East India trade on their welfare will be considered in section V. 21 This is one of many examples in the Considerations where Martyn shows his adeptness in analyzing comparative static changes. As Arkin (1955, p. 306) points out in relation to chapters 16± 17, throughout them ``runs a clear grasp of the interrelationships between supply, demand, and price.’ ’ This is another respect in which Martyn can be said to have anticipated Smith. 2 2 Martyn argues that, ``Arts, and Mills, and Engines, which save the labour of Hands, are ways of doing things with less labour, and consequently with labour of less price, tho’ the Wages of Men imploy’d to do them shou’d not be abated’ ’ (p. 41, italics added). 2 3 Irwin (1996, pp. 158± 59) quotes a passage from the early draft of The Wealth of Nations which shows an even greater analogy to Martyn’s: ``It is in this manner that in an opulent and commercial society labour becomes dear and work cheap, and those two events, which vulgar prejudices and super® cial re¯ ection are apt to consider as altogether incompatible, are found by experience to be perfectly consistent’’ (Smith 1978, p. 567). Martyn’s word ``paradox’’ captures perfectly the spirit of the second part of Smith’s sentence. 2 4 Joyce Appleby (1978, p. 173) also argues that North and Martyn, among other liberal Restoration writers, ``were endorsing the upward striving of the poor and turning the enjoyment of a higher standard of living into both the motive and the end of productivity.’’ I disagree with Arkin’s contrary view that ``it is perhaps in (Martyn’s) attitude towards labour that the writer of this tract approaches most closely to the mercantilist outlook’’ and that ``there is scant mention of the manner in which the workers themselves can expect to share in the expanding prosperity’’ (1955, pp. 312± 33). Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 242 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Chapter 10 of Book One of The Wealth of Nations discusses wage and pro® t diVerentials in diVerent occupations, and is divided into two parts, the ® rst analyzing the diVerentials arising from the nature of the employments themselves, and the second those arising from the ``policy of Europe, which nowhere leaves things at perfect liberty’’ (Smith 1776, p. 116). This policy prevented free entry into certain occupations, stimulated arti® cially the entry into others, and obstructed the mobility of labor and capital occupationally as well as geographicall y. The eVects of such policies on the English economy of his day were also deplored by Martyn. He noted with irony the measures adopted at the instigation of the ``Gentlemen’ ’ from ``English Estates’ ’ to protect the woolen textile industry from the import of East Indian manufactures: ``a poor Man must not have leave to carry an old Sheet to his Grave; both the Living and the Dead must be wrapt in Woollen’ ’ (1701, pp. 49± 50). Martyn was inclined to reject such policies favoring particular sectors of the economy. In order to make individuals content to earn a pro® t rate in the ® shing trade as low as that found in Holland, he pleaded that ``all our Trades both foreign and domestick, might be driven with the greatest freedom, Corporations and other Restraints might be destroy’d . . . By such an universal Freedom of Trade, our Super¯ uities wou’d be multiply’d, our exportations wou’d be enlarg’d, our Bullion wou’d be increas’d, and the more Money wou’d be still imploy’d in Trade’’ (p. 69). A famous aphorism from Smith’s The Wealth of Nations is that ``As defence . . . is of much more importance than opulence, the act of navigation is, perhaps, the wisest of all the commercial regulations of England.’ ’ While this view can be justi® ed as expressing an important noneconomic goal, some commentators interpret it as a sign that Smith had not succeeded in discarding all types of mercantilist belief. He favored the Act of Navigation even though he recognized that it ``is not favourable to foreign commerce, or to the growth of that opulence which can arise from it’ ’ (1776, pp. 464± 65). Martyn showed no such qualms. To enable England to catch up with Holland in the ® shing industry, he proposed to have ships built in the ``plantations’’ where ``the Work might be perform’d by Negroes.’ ’ His rationale was that ``the Strength of Negroes is as great (as that of Dutch workmen); a way is shewn to make their Skill as great . . . Negroes may build as good Ships with equal Expedition, for half the Wages that must be given in Holland’’ (1701, pp. 72± 73). Martyn believed that the division of labor practiced in shipbuilding would make these ships cheaper than Dutch ones, so that they could be sold even to Holland. Moreover, ``This were the way for us to become the Carriers of the World, to pro® t by all that others eat, and drink, and wear: This were a surer way, and less odious to our Neighbours, than any Act of Navigation for only English Bottoms to be imploy’d, in the Carriage of Things to and from our own Country’’ (p. 76). ``Carriers of the world’ ’ is an interesting alternative way to envisage the economic future of the country that was eventually to become the ``workshop of the world.’ ’ This depiction was expressed by Martyn earlier in his tract in poetic language: For, why are we surrounded with the Sea? Surely that our Wants at home might be supply’ d by our Navigation into other Countries, the least and easiest Labour. By this we taste the Spices of Arabia, yet never feel the scorching Sun CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 243 Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 which brings them forth; we shine in Silks which our Hands have never wrought; we drink of Vinyards which we never planted; the Treasures of those Mines are ours, in which we have never digg’d; we only plough the Deep, and reap the Harvest of every Country in the World (p. 37). This passage occurs in the same chapter that contains Martyn’s formulation of the ``eighteenth-century rule’ ’ for the gains from trade. This rule plays such a strategic part in Martyn’s Considerations that the next section is devoted to it. Martyn not only anticipated Smith in analyzing the gains from trade in this way, but he went beyond him. Given the three centuries that have elapsed since its publication, it would be surprising if the Considerations was not marked by some conceptual ¯ aws that must be balanced against the profound insights for which it should be primarily remembered. One of these ¯ aws was pointed out by Joseph Schumpeter (1954), who extended his critique to other enlightened writers of the mercantilist period and to Adam Smith himself. Smith maintained that whatever makes individuals wealthy automatically enriches the whole society. For example, his advocacy of free trade depended on the assumption that: It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family, never to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy. What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarce be folly in that of a great kingdom . If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it of them with some part of the produce of our own industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantag e (Smith 1776, pp. 456± 57). Martyn used the same logic when he asserted that ``the Riches of every individual Man is part of the Riches of the whole Community. Wherefore, if to erect a Free-Port is to increase the Riches of the Merchant, it must increase the Riches of the Kingdom’’ (1701, p. 78) . 2 5 Schumpeter argued that both ``the anonymous author’ ’ (Martyn) and Isaac Gervaise were much too ready to arrive at conclusions agreeable to their free-trade opinions . . . The case of the anonymou s author is still worse. He leans heavily on the argument that, because internationa l trade consists of voluntar y transactions, which therefore must necessarily be to the advantag e of both contracting parties, nothing but advantag e to the nation as a whole can result from it (1954, pp. 375± 76). Schumpeter went on to tar Dudley North and Adam Smith with the same brush, quoting the above sentence of Smith regarding ``what is prudence in the conduct of every private family.’ ’ The fallacy of composition that Schumpeter alludes to was identi® ed and criticized before him by Alexander Hamilton, John Rae, 2 5 Martyn made the conceptually related point that positive and negative changes in individuals’ incomes should be added algebraically to determine if a nation as a whole is better or worse oV: ``the increase of the Stock of a Part exceeding the diminution of that of the rest of the People, must be esteem’d an increase of the Riches of the whole People’ ’ (p. 22). This is what is known in the welfare economics literature as the Kaldor-Hicks criterion for an increase in social income, which takes no account of the distribution of income. 244 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT Friedrich List, and other writers who argued in favor of a ``national system’’ of political economy. 2 6 Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 IV. THE ``EIGHTEENTH-CENTURY RULE’’ FOR THE GAINS FROM TRADE Martyn is now perhaps best known for giving one of the clearest formulations, accompanied by a numerical example, of the eighteenth-century rule according to which ``it pays to import commodities from abroad whenever they can be obtained in exchange for exports at a smaller real cost than their production at home would entail’ ’ (Viner 1937, p. 440). Smith used this rule several times in The Wealth of Nations to depict the gains from trade. As early as chapter 2 of Book One, he noted that in a tribe of hunters or shepherds a person who excels in making bows and arrows ``frequently exchanges them for cattle or for venison with his companions; and he ® nds at last that he can in this manner get more cattle and venison, than if he himself went to the ® eld to catch them’ ’ (1776, p. 27). A similar view of the gains from trade is expressed in Book Three of The Wealth of Nations in connection with the trade between town and countryside, and in Book Four in connection with the gains from foreign trade (pp. 376, 457). A country that imports commodities from abroad and pays for them with exports incurs only a fraction of the costs required to produce them with its own resources. Present-day trade economists describe the same rule when they argue that trade is an indirect method of production. The numerical example that Martyn presents in chapter 10 of the Considerations to quantify the gains from trade via the eighteenth-century rule is the following: 2 7 If nine cannot produce above three Bushels of Wheat in England, if by equal Labour they might procure nine Bushels from another Country, to imploy these in agriculture at home, is to imploy nine to do no more work than might be done as well by three; . . . is the loss of six Bushels of Wheat; is therefore the loss of so much value (1701, p. 35). Martyn’s measure of the gains from trade represented a major analytical advance that Smith never referred to in numerical terms, though he clearly understood the concept. This measure, and its implied case for free trade, was not improved by other economists for over a century. It can readily be translated into a similar measure used by present-day economists known as the equivalent variation of the gains from trade, and depicted diagrammatically (Maneschi 1998). Ricardo (1817, chapter 7) also appealed to the eighteenth-century rule to describe the gains from trade. In his numerical example of wine and cloth traded between England and Portugal, he argued that Portugal could obtain more cloth 2 6 These writers can be regarded as ``creators of comparative advantage ’’ (Maneschi 1998, chapter 5). Their intellectual descendant was John Stuart Mill, who formulated the argument for infant industry protection (Mill 1848) and convinced his fellow economists of its soundness. 2 7 As shown in Maneschi (1998, p. 36), Martyn’s numbers imply that a unit of labor employed in the export sector produces commodities that exchange for one bushel of wheat, while a unit of labor directly employed in the wheat sector yields only 1/3 bushel. Hence trade results in a gain of 2/3 bushel of wheat per unit of labor employed. 245 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE by exchanging some of her wine for English cloth than by manufacturing the cloth herself, even though her labor was more productive in cloth than English labor. Viner himself held that Ricardo’s principle of comparative costs did not go much further than the eighteenth-century rule: Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 Such gain from trade is always possible when, and is only possible if, there are comparative diVerences in costs between the countries concerned. The doctrine of comparative costs is, indeed, but a statement of some of the implication s of this rule, and adds nothing to it as a guide for policy . . . This explicit statement that imports could be pro® table even though the commodity imported could be produced at less cost at home than abroad was, it seems to me, the sole addition of consequence which the doctrine of comparative costs made to the eighteenth-century rule (1937, pp. 440± 41). Several other commentators of Martyn’s Considerations have expressed the opinion that it anticipated the principle of comparative advantage. According to Thomas (1926, p. 77), the argument in the Considerations that ``it was a loss to the kingdom to carry on manufactures which could be managed elsewhere with the labour of fewer hands . . . foreshadowed the modern theory of comparative costs.’ ’ Barber (1975, p. 61) went even further by claiming that ``in all its essential particulars, the analysis the nineteenth century was to know as the theory of comparative advantage can be found in the pages of an obscure tract produced by a man who sought to unravel the mysteries of the East India trade in 1701.’ ’ Schumpeter took a much dimmer view of Martyn’s contribution. After acknowledging that Martyn was one of only two English authors who achieved ``a technically superior formulation of the bene® ts from territorial division of labor that went some way toward anticipating the most important element in the nineteenth-century theory of international values,’ ’ he went on to critique his treatment of ``international trade as a method of acquiring goods with an amount of labor smaller than would be necessary to produce them at home. He does not seem to have been aware of the relation of this to the principle of comparative cost, but even so we have here a predecessor of Ricardo, though possibly a quite unin¯ uential one’ ’ (1954, pp. 373± 74). Schumpeter’s contention that Martyn’s numerical example does not relate to comparative costs is correct: it does not contain the four numbers needed (that is, the productivitie s of labor in two commodities in each of two countries) to deduce the direction of trade. Martyn provided the labor coeYcients of country A while ignoring those of country B, and short-circuited the determination of the trade equilibrium by postulating given terms of trade. However, it is astonishing that Schumpeter failed to give Martyn any credit for his formulation of the eighteenth-century rule, and chose instead to fault him for not discovering the principle of comparative costs 116 years ahead of Ricardo! V. VICISSITUDES OF THREE CENTURIES MARTYN’S CONSIDERATIONS OVER Commentators on Martyn’s Considerations have praised it as a remarkable tract advancin g concepts that later became important building blocks of classical political economy. But they note its failure to have any signi® cant impact on the Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 246 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT evolution of the latter, as witnessed by the fact that it was hardly noticed until it was resurrected by McCulloch a century and a half after its publication. After discussing North and Martyn as important precursors of Adam Smith, Hutchison (1988, p. 86) observes that ``at this point, at the start of the eighteenth century, this movement [toward what he labels ``mercantilist liberalism ’ ’ ] received a check, the reasons for which are somewhat obscure. North and Martyn had no immediate successors developing the case for economic freedom along similar lines, or in the same style.’ ’ For McCulloch, this seemingly paradoxica l neglect ``is wholly to be ascribed to the author being very far in advance of his age,’ ’ so that much was required ``to dissipate the prejudices which swayed his contemporaries and their successors’ ’ (1856, p. xv). Barber comments similarly on the ``air of puzzlement surrounding the appraisal s of this document oVered by latter-day commentators. Considerations Upon the East-India Trade can thus appear to be not of its time, but ahead of it.’ ’ He oVers some interesting re¯ ections on ``the suppression of intellectual innovation’ ’ such as that embodied in the Considerations. The major organized interest groups in England, such as the textile interests, the two existing East India companies, and other commercial rivals desiring a share of the monopoly pro® ts in the East India trade, had able writers at their disposal, and ``it was to the interest of none of them to draw attention to this publication. The promotion of unbridled laissez-faire was not their objective’’ (Barber 1975, pp. 64± 65). According to MacLeod, ``what Martin was saying in 1701 demanded a great leap of economic faith. Ostensibly reassuring , it implied in eVect a dislocation of the economy that threatened many with ruin and all with social unrest. Henry Martin’s prescription involved far too many risks for his contemporaries’ liking. His arguments were far too radical.’ ’ She concludes that ``Dudley North’s Discourses on Trade and Isaac Gervaise’s System or Theory of the Trade of the World (1720) were virtually ignored’ ’ for the same reason, and that ``thoroughgoing free trade had to wait almost another century to be unashamedly appreciated’ ’ (1983, pp. 227± 29). Thomas (1926) and Joyce Appleby (1978) also explain the genesis and subsequent neglect of Martyn’s Considerations and other liberal writings of that time in terms of the underlying political events and ideological currents. They provide a lively account of the controversy between protectionists and free traders in England in the latter half of the seventeenth century, and they trace the political, economic, and social reasons for the triumph of protectionism in the eighteenth century. According to Appleby, political decisions taken in the period 1696± 1713 caused England to follow a course of economic development diVerent from that envisaged by the liberal pamphleteers. Power shifted from merchants such as those engaged in the East India trade to manufacturers and landowners who did not share their orientation toward laissez faire and free trade. In the very year of publication of the Considerations, 1701, ``the campaign launched earlier by the clothiers against East Indian imports was crowned with success . . . when the special duties of the 1690s were converted into a complete prohibition’ ’ (Appleby 1978, p. 249). In fact, she dates to that time ``the ® rst appearance in England of anything that could be called mercantilism . . . under the sponsorship of landlords and manufacturers rather than that of the merchants from whom its name is derived’’ (pp. 250± 51). Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 247 This ideological shift at the turn of the eighteenth century was accompanied by a renewed importance attached to the balance of trade, a concept that had increasingly been rejected as a guide to policy in the course of the seventeenth century. Pamphleteers began to stress that a more positive balance of trade associated with rising exports would lead to greater employment, whose level had become an increasing preoccupation of policymakers. 2 8 In the Considerations, as mentioned above, Martyn showed himself oblivious to the social problems connected with unemployment resulting from the import of cheap textiles from India, assuming that the displaced labor would readily ® nd employment elsewhere. This attitude toward labor, and Martyn’s accompanying preference for free trade and rejection of the balance of trade as a valid policy concern, help to explain why the Considerations fell on deaf ears after its publication, despite being republished in 1720 with a new title. Martyn himself was aVected by the changed political and ideological climate, as evidenced by his becoming in 1713 a leading contributor to The British Merchant, a journal vehemently opposed to free trade with France. How can one account for Martyn’s volte-face from being a radical free trader in the Considerations to becoming not simply one of several contributors to The British Merchant, but ``The Person to whom our Country is chie¯ y obliged for these Papers, and who had the greatest Hand in them’’ (King 1721, p. xiv)? Thomas (1926) and MacLeod (1983) oVer similar explanations, rooted in the political and ideological currents that marked England at the turn of the eighteenth century. As MacLeod observes, the Considerations and The British Merchant, ``Although widely disparate in their styles of argument, were at least consistent in their attack upon ostensibly tory interests’ ’ (p. 225). As a Whig, Martyn denounced the monopoly of the old East India Company dominated by the Tories and closely allied to the crown, and supported the claims of the rival English East India Company Trading to the East Indies sponsored by Parliament and incorporated in 1698. In chapter 3 of the Considerations he even went beyond promoting the claims of the rival company, advocating the need to ``break both Companies.’ ’ Martyn wished to allow all merchants the freedom to trade with East India not because he was enamored of the free trade ideal, as shown by the conventional mercantilist arguments he later used in The British Merchant, but because the promotion of freer trade to the East Indies seemed the most promising way to prevent the old Tory East India Company from reacquiring the monopoly of that trade (MacLeod 1983, p. 226). Another reason for Martyn’s stance, identi® ed by both Thomas and MacLeod, is the fact that his younger brother Richard was a linen-draper. The economic interests of the linen-drapers (who were also Whigs) made them the most vociferous partisans of free trade with the East Indies. 2 9 As Thomas points out, 28 Johnson (1937) devotes the last chapter of his book to ``The `Export of Work’ and `Foreign-Paid Incomes’,’’ noting that from the latter part of the seventeenth century pamphleteers increasingly viewed exports as providing ``foreign-paid incomes’ ’ for workers, and reinterpreted the balance of trade goal accordingly. See also Magnusson (1994, pp. 134± 38). 2 9 A parliamentary act of 1700 forbidding the wearing of calicoes and silks after September 1701 gave added urgency to the publication of Martyn’s tract, and perhaps explains the hurried composition and ``unnecessary Repetitions’ ’ to which Martyn alludes in its preface, where he claims that he did not have the time to correct or review his manuscript. Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 248 JOURNAL OF THE HISTORY OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT ``Although the Considerations is apparently an impartial defence of a principle, it need not be supposed that the author had no self-interest in maintaining such a thesis. Almost every pamphlet on East Indian trade written in that periodÐ especially from 1696 to 1700Ð was meant to promote the interests of party or faction’ ’ (1926, p. 172). 3 0 Thus, an alternative interpretation of the lack of in¯ uence of the Considerations on Martyn’s contemporaries is that the writers of tracts were automatically regarded as spokesmen for special interests rather than disinterested observers who speculated on the rationale for policies such as free trade and how nations gain from it. Anonymous tracts such as the Considerations could be expected to come under special suspicion. The tract’s strident stand in favor of free trade, which ignored the possibility that free trade could harm even temporarily the manufactures and labor force in import-competing sectors, was hardly designed to win over adherents to its author’s views as scienti® cally based. Martyn’s political proclivities also explain why he advocated the defeat of the Treaty of Utrecht of 1713, by which the Tories hoped to liberaliz e trade with France. Martyn was charged by the Whigs to respond in The British Merchant; or, Commerce Preserv’d to the Tory arguments presented by Daniel Defoe (a ``Hireling Writer,’ ’ according to the Whigs) in the rival publication Mercator: or Commerce Retrieved. As Thomas points out, ``It was not unusual in those days even among honest men to stand for liberal trade relations with one country while opposing the same in the case of another’ ’ (1926, p. 172). Martyn could thus acquiesce in the fact that, while arguing against trade with France, The British Merchant believed in freedom of trade with China and the East Indies (King 1721, p. 30), as well as with other countries whose trade with England was deemed to be advantageous. The vicissitudes in the reception accorded to the Considerations after its publication, and Martyn’s conditional attitude toward free trade depending on which country was England’s trading partner, should not, of course, aVect our view of its quality as an outstanding intellectual contribution to economics and to the case for free trade that was, as McCulloch rightly stated, ``very far in advance’ ’ of its author’s era. As argued above, Martyn’s tract contains a plethora of anticipations of Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations, and in certain respects such as the formulation of the eighteenth-century rule, went well beyond it. Unfortunately, we will never know if Smith bene® ted from reading the Considerations when he composed The Wealth of Nations. But this is not as important as recalling that Henry Martyn’s tract of 1701 contained insights that foreshadowed many of the bene® ts that globalization is still able to deliver to trading nations three hundred years later. 3 0 This self-interest was of course even clearer in the case of pamphleteers such as Josiah Child and Charles Davenant. As employees of the East India company (and, in Child’s case, as its Governor), their protestations on behalf of freedom of trade for a company that wielded monopoly power were naturally suspect, regardless of the logic with which they articulated them. CONSIDERATIONS UPON THE EAST-INDIA TRADE 249 Downloaded by [University of Warwick] at 05:26 06 January 2012 REFERENCES Appleby, Joyce O. 1978. Economic Thought and Ideology in Seventeenth-Century England. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Arkin, Marcus. 1955. ``A Neglected Forerunner of Adam Smith: An Appraisal of the Place of Henry Martin’s (?) Considerations on the East-India Trade (1701) in the History of Economic Thought.’’ South African Journal of Economics 23 (4): 299± 314. Barber, William J. 1975. British Economic Thought and India 1600 ± 1858: A Study in the History of Development Economics. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Beer, Max. 1938. Early British Economics from the Thirteenth to the Middle of the Eighteenth Century. Woking: George Allen & Unwin. Bowley, Marian. 1973. Studies in the History of Economic Theory before 1870. New York: Humanities Press. Hutchison, Terence W. 1988. Before Adam Smith: The Emergence of Political Economy 1662± 1776. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Irwin, Douglas A. 1996. Against the Tide: An Intellectual History of Free Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Johnson, E. A. J. 1937. Predecessors of Adam Smith: The Growth of British Economic Thought. New York: Prentice-Hall. King, Charles. 1721. The British Merchant; or, Commerce Preserv’d. London: John Darby. Lawson, Philip. 1993. The East India Company: A History. London: Longman. MacLeod, Christine. 1983. ``Henry Martin and the Authorship of `Considerations upon the East India Trade’ .’’ Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research 56 (November): 222-29. Magnusson, Lars. 1994. Mercantilism: The Shaping of an Economic Language. London: Routledge. Maneschi, Andrea. 1998. Comparative Advantage in International Trade: A Historical Perspective. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Martyn, Henry. 1701. Considerations Upon the East-India Trade. In John R. McCulloch, ed., Early English Tracts on Commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954. McCulloch, John R., ed. 1856. Early English Tracts on Commerce. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1954. Mill, John Stuart. 1848. Principles of Political Economy. London: Longman, Green, 1920. Myint, Hla. 1958. ``The ’ Classical Theory’ of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Countries.’’ Economic Journal 68 (270): 317± 37. Rashid, Salim. 1998. The Myth of Adam Smith. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Ricardo, David. 1817. On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. In Piero SraVa, ed., The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo, vol. I. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1951. Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1954. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press. Smith, Adam. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1976. Ð Ð . 1978. Lectures on Jurisprudence. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Thomas, P. J. 1926. Mercantilism and the East India Trade. London: P. S. King & Son. Viner, Jacob. 1937. Studies in the Theory of International Trade. New York: Harper.