Price Discovery and Segmentation in the Public and Private Housing Markets in Singapore Tien-Foo Sing Department of Real Estate National University of Singapore, Singapore Email: rststf@nus.edu.sg & I-Chun Tsai & Ming-Chi Chen* Department of Finance National Sun Yat-sen University, Taiwan Email: mcchen@finance.nsysu.edu.tw Date: 3 August 2004 Abstract: Public housing is the largest housing submarket in Singapore. There is also an active resale public housing market, where public housing dwellers are allowed to trade their houses after a time-bar of five years from the date of their purchase. This segment of resale HDB market is liken the private housing submarkets, where housing prices are more likely to fluctuate in accordance to the market and economic cycles. Using the STOPBREAK tests proposed by Engle and Smith (1999), the study rejected the random walk null hypothesis for relative prices in pairs of the HDB resale price and other private housing prices. The public and private housing market is thus not segmented. When we further examined whether the STOPBREAK process persist in other pairs of private housing submarkets, we found weak evidence to suggest the stratification of the private housing market. We also found that price discovery processes between the resale HDB housing market and other private submarkets occurred through at least one cointegrating equation in our vector autoregressive error correction models (VECM). In the private housing submarkets, we observed significant and positive price effects from detached submarket to other private housing submarkets, which may imply that the increase in housing wealth of detached households, who are less financially constrained, will motivate them to allocate part of their accrued wealth through investment in other private housing submarkets. The wealth accrued in detached housing submarket is translated into price increases in other private housing sector. Keywords: Stochastic Permanent Break (STOPBREAK), Price discovery, Market Segmentation and Stratification. * Corresponding author. Address: Department of Real Estate, National University of Singapore, 4 Architecture Drive, Singapore 117566. Email: Trststf@nus.edu.sg. Comments are welcome. Price Discovery and Segmentation in the Public and Private Housing Markets in Singapore 1. Introduction Housing market in Singapore is characterized by a two-tier housing system comprising a public market and a private market. The public housing market constitutes about 88% of the housing stocks based on the census statistics in 2000. The public housing is built by the government via the national housing agency, the Housing and Development Board (HDB), and allocated to qualified Singaporean citizen at subsidized prices. Social, demographic and income criteria are put in place to ensure that housing subsidies are efficiently distributed to eligible citizens.1 These criteria are only applicable for new flats brought directly from the HDB. The income ceiling and citizen-only restrictions on resale flat were relaxed in 1989. Private property owners and single citizen above 35 years were also subsequently allowed to purchase the resale HDB outside central area for owner occupancy (Phang and Wong, 1997; Phang, 2004). Prices of resale HDB flats are not regulated, but market determined. Many HDB flat owners have amalgamated and realized substantial wealth by capitalizing on the difference in the new public housing price and resale public housing price through upward mobility decision (Lum, 2002; Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum, 2003). However, Phang (2004) found no significant evidence to support the wealth effects created though owning public houses on private consumption. She attributes the findings to the rigid Central Provident Fund (CPF)2 scheme that disallows the withdrawal of the surpluses accrued in housing wealth to finance personal consumption. Private housing market operates in a laisser-faire economic system, where private housing prices are mainly determined by a function of the demand and supply in the market. This segment of the market is dominated by few major private developers. The government’s involvement through the sale of leasehold private residential lands program and the government linked property companies also helps indirectly to cushion unnecessary price inflation that may dampen Singaporeans’ dream of owning private residential properties (Phang, 2001). Unlike the public housing, private housing units are not only more expensive, they are also differentiated though better designs, quality of finishes and fully-equipped recreationally facilities. A variety of housing forms, which include landed houses like detached house, semi-detached house, terrace, and non-landed houses like condominiums and apartments in various price ranges, is made available by private developers to meet different aspiration and preference of potential house buyers. With the exception of landed houses, where some restrictions are imposed on the foreign ownerships of these properties under the 1 2 Some of these eligibility criteria include, for example, the qualified buyers for 4-room and larger HDB flats must form a nucleus family upon delivery of the flats. The income ceiling criterion for the household is set at $8000 per month to make sure that the subsidies are channeled to the target group of citizens. The Central Provident Fund (CPF) is a comprehensive pension scheme, which has been expanded to provide financing for the public housing purchases in 1968, and subsequently for the private housing purchases in 1981 under the Residential Property Scheme (RPS). (See Ambrose, Chu, SaAadu, and Sing, 2003 for details) 1 Residential Property Act (Chapter 274),3 all other private non-landed houses are freely transacted in the market. The private housing market activities are found to be highly dependent on the lagged period economic performance (Sing, 2001). The strong gross domestic products (GDP) growths in the earlier and mid 1990s attracted large influx of foreign capitals into the private housing sector, especially in the medium and luxury classes of nonlanded private properties. The proportion foreigner ownership in the private nonlanded property stocks was estimated at 13.5% in 1996, but declined to 11.0% in 2Q2004 following the Asian’s financial crisis that has dampened the flow of funds into the private housing market (Figure 1). Active upgrading market in the lower-end non-landed property submarket, however, partly mitigated the impact caused by the exodus of the foreign buyers in the upper segment of the private housing markets in the post-1997 periods. [Insert Figure 1] Over the period from the previous peak in 2Q1996 to 2Q2004, the private residential property price index published by the Urban Redevelopment Authority (URA)4 dropped by nearly 38%, whereas the HDB resale price index was corrected downward by only 17.18% over the same period (Figure 2). The unparallel rates of decline in private and public housing prices narrowed the price gap between the two submarkets in the post-crisis periods. Public housing owners found the upward mobility to lower-end private residential properties more affordable and less constrained on their income. More households took the upward path by selling their public houses and move to private houses. This group of public housing upgraders is identified by Stein (1995) and Lamont and Stein (1999) as “constrained movers.” In Singapore, the upward mobility of these constrained movers was not only driven by price volatility in the private housing market; their decisions are also influenced by the changes in the HDB prices (Ong, 2000; Lee and Ong, 2003). Ong and Sing (2002) also found further evidence to support Stein’s (1995) hypothesis in the forms of significant price discovery process between the private and public housing markets in Singapore. [Insert Figure 2] Coinciding with the convergence in prices, the quality disparity between the two submarkets is also reduced with the improvement in the quality of the public housing units and also the shift by private developers in their product designs towards smaller units that appeal to the upgraders (Lum, 2002). Quality asides, there is, however, still a clear hierarchical stratification of housing sub-markets that dictates the upward mobility path of households. The hierarchical or pyramid structure of housing submarkets is composed of public houses as the base, followed in an ascending order by 3 4 Under the Residential Property Act, foreigners are only allowed to purchase properties with “condominium” status or apartments with buildings more than six levels. They have to obtain written approvals from the Controller of Residential Property and Land Dealings to purchase landed properties. The Urban Redevelopment Authority (URA) is the national physical planning agency, which is also tasked to provide property transaction information on private residential property market in Singapore. The private residential property price indices published by the URA are transaction based indices compiled from caveats lodged with the Land Registry. 2 lower-end apartments, condominiums, terraces, semi-detached houses and detached houses at the top of the hierarchy (Lum, 2002; Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum, 2003). There is a clear differential price structure between different housing strata over the hierarchy, where prices of properties in one stratum support prices of the properties in the stratum immediately above it. Prices of new HDB flats, being the lowest in the housing strata, support the prices of resale HDB flats, which in term support the prices of non-landed and other landed housing submarket in the strata above. The segmentation of the housing markets in this hierarchical structure implies that the upward mobility for households is not a continuous path. Households, in particularly the constrained movers, will have to “climb up the ladder” of the hierarchy in a “stepby-step” process. In other words, we will expect the HDB upgraders to make the immediate mobility choice by purchasing entry-level condominiums, rather than going directly for detached houses at the top of the hierarchy. Therefore, the intra- and inter-stratum segmentation in the housing sub-markets, if exists, will suggest that price discovery will not occur ubiquitously across different segments. The process, however, will only likely to take place between two housing sub-markets that are immediately above or below each other in the hierarchical stratum. This paper aims to test the segmentation and stratification between public resale housing market and other private housing submarkets, in a hierarchical order from apartment, condominium, terrace, semi-detached and detached. We would also examine how price discovery process will occur across various strata of the submarkets, if segmentation of housing clientele is proven to be significant. The empirical tests of the long run relationships between the two sub-markets will be conducted using the stochastic permanent break (STOPBREAK) model proposed by Engle and Smith (1999). Compared to the traditional conintegration methodology, the STOPBREAK model is able to explicitly capture permanent breaks in the price series between two markets. This paper is organized into six sections. Section I provides the background and motivation of the study. Section II reviews relevant literature in the households’ upward mobility decision and the priced discovery. Section III gives a brief review of the housing system and market in Singapore. The testable hypothesis and empirical methodology are laid down in Section IV. Section V discusses the results of the empirical tests. Section VI concludes the findings with relevant policy implications. 2. Literature Review 2.1 Price discovery and Upward Mobility Price discovery studies in real estate have thus far concentrated on the relationships between direct real estate and other asset classes including the exchange traded or securitized real estate. Equity real estate investment trusts (EREITs), which are widely regarded as the proxy of indirect real estate investment vehicle, were found to provide positive leading signal to the price generating processes in direct real estate market (Gyourko and Keim, 1992; Ong, 1994; Barkham and Geltner, 1995). Prices of securitized real estate reflect the market values of underlying real estate assets (Martin and Cook, 1991). The results imply that information in one market can be used to efficiently predict the price changes in another market, despite a time lag between the responses in the two markets. 3 Liu, Hartzell, Greig and Grissom (1990) use the arbitrage rationality in the asset pricing framework to link the price discovery process to the existence of market integration. The define that two markets are deemed to be integrated, if systematic market risk is the only risk undiversified by holding assets in two markets, investor should then earn the same risk adjusted expected returns on the two assets. They found that the United State (US) securitised real estate market was integrated with the stock market, but the same evidence was not found in the commercial real estate market. Okunev and Wilson (1997) provided further evidence of market integration between securitized real estate and stock markets in the US, but they found tha relationships between the two markets were non-linear. Lizieri and Satchell (1997) obtained the same conclusion on the integration of the securitized real estate and stock markets in the UK. In the Australia’s study, the results of Wilson, Okunev and Ta (1996) showed no conclusive evidence for the integration of the two markets. Studies on the long-run contemporaneous relationships between securitized and direct real estate markets in Singapore have also been widely published, but the results were mixed and inconclusive (Ong, 1994 and 1995; Liow, 1998 and 2001; Sing and Sng, 2003; Sing, 2004). Schwann and Chau (2003) found that the price discovery between securitized and unsecuritized real estate markets was not stable over time, and the new effects significant reduced the amount of real estate information conveyed from one market to another. Ong and Sing (2002) empirically tested the market integration hypothesis and the inter-market price discovery process between private and public housing markets in Singapore. They found significant evidence to support that the two markets were integrated. Market forces play a significant role in regulating the price information flows between the two highly differentiated markets. The price discovery process was also evidenced between the two markets in bi-directional Granger causality tests, which supported the upward mobility hypothesis in the two housing sub-markets in Singapore. The results reaffirmed the findings by Ong (2000), which showed that resale HDB prices will have significant effects on upgraders’ mobility choice. He computed the theoretical threshold upgradability prices, which was found to have closely tracked the actual private residential property prices from 1990 to 1998. In another study of the public households’ upward mobility behavior in Singapore, Lee and Ong (2003) found evidence to support Stein’s (1995) hypothesis, which suggests that households’ decision to consume more housing goods is triggered by improved affordability of households caused by changes in HDB house prices. The questions of the persistence of hierarchical structure between different housing types within the private housing market and between the private and public housing market, however, have not been examined. We hypothesize that there is noncontinuous path of intra- and inter-market price discovery path in Singapore’s housing markets. The hypothesis will be empirically tested in this study. 2.2. Other Housing Studies in Singapore Ownership of private residential property is well regarded as a social status, and a dream of HDB dwellers, and those who have not owned a house. Despite the small market share of the private residential property market in Singapore, research, 4 however, has been concentrated on this sector of the market. The free-market operation of the private market also implies that the market is more responsive and susceptible to shocks in economics, and price correction should be less “sticky” vis-àvis public housing market. This hypothesis was, however, rejected by Phang and Wong (1997), who found that macro-economic factors like GDP, interest rate and supply of housing, were not significant in explaining the price variations in private housing prices in Singapore. They, instead, showed that government determined public housing prices, and various policies public housing and CPF financing to have significant impact on private housing prices. The linkage between the state-controlled public housing market and the market-driven private housing market was again affirmed by Lum (2002) using a structural housing price model corrected for nonstationary roots. Unlike Phang and Wong (1997), her model showed that demand and supply macro-variables were significant determinant private housing prices over the long run. The land sale program and the liberalization of public housing market were proven to be effective short-run policy tools adopted by government in stabilizing the private housing markets. In an opposite direction of causality, economists are attracted to research into the effects of housing wealth in the life cycle theory of consumption. Using Singapore data on personal consumption expenditure and private housing prices from 19812000, Phang (2004) found no evidence to support the existence of wealth associated with increases in price house price on the aggregate consumption. She also tested the asymmetric response in the aggregate consumption function, and found that households are bounded by liquidity constraints, which was evidenced by the negative effects of private housing price increases on consumption. Ng (2001), in another separate study using a shorter time-series data from 1990 to 2001, in contrary, found positive wealth effects from private housing price increases to consumption in the short run. In the long run, however, the impact of private housing price changes on consumption was negative because of the increases in financing costs in owning private houses. Edelstein and Lum (2003) tested the independent effects of housing wealth in public housing and private housing markets on aggregate consumption over two different periods: 1Q1990-2Q1997 and 3Q1997-4Q2004, and they found the impact of increases in public households’ wealth to be far more significant than the private households’ wealth on aggregate consumption. In the impulse response test, they showed that the shocks on public housing wealth of households on consumption were more persistent, particularly in the second sub-period. Increases in public resale (HDB) housing prices created wealth effects not only on household aggregate consumption, Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum (2003) also found that the wealth effects were also extended to private housing sales. Positive wealth amalgamated by HDB households mitigates their upward mobility constraint, and increases the sales of private houses to this group of constrained HDB upgraders. They also showed that stock equity wealth and real home rate were two significant determinants of the volume of private housing sales in Singapore. Again, the results were consistent with Stein’s hypothesis on the effects of housing price changes on upgradability. 5 3. Stratification of Singapore Housing Sub-Markets Studies (Phang and Wong, 1997; Ong, 2000; Lum, 2002; Ong and Sing, 2002; Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum, 2003) have found close interactions between the public and private housing markets in Singapore. The public housing wealth is clearly an important factor in not only stimulating private housing sale (Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum, 2003), but also a key driver of aggregate consumption (Edelstein and Lum, 2003). The inter-market mobility has also been proven to have driven the housing price volatility (Ong, 2002, Lee and Ong, 2003). However, the previous studies have omitted the impact of diversity of housing types in two sub-markets on the price discovery and wealth creation process for different households. There are clear differences in various housing classes and household groups in each housing class. According to Stein’s (1995) hypothesis, the affordability levels for different families: unconstrained mover, constrained mover, and constrained non-mover, will dictate the housing choice that are available for them when mobility decision is made. The heterogeneity in different housing sub-markets and sub-types would no doubt have influence on household mobility and housing choice decision. Lum (2002) and Bardhan, Datta, Edelstein and Lum (2003) have highlighted the unique pyramid structure of public and private housing sub-markets in Singapore, when describing the Singapore housing system in their papers. The prices of house in the lower stratum in the pyramid support prices in the stratum immediately above it. The housing stock as a proportion of total stock is smaller when we move up the housing stratum. The hierarchical price structure and the different market size for the two markets create a pyramid shape in the housing submarkets (Figure 3). There is another hybrid housing class, known as executive condominium, which is developed by private housing developers for sale to constrained HDB households. The eligible households will entitled to government grants of S$30,000 to $40,000 through their CPF account in the purchase of the executive condominiums. The buyers of executive condominiums, on the other hand, are subject to some of the public housing restrictions, such as a time-bar that prevent them from freely selling their units in less than 5 years. This housing type is excluded in this study because its unique features of this housing type that appeal to only a target group of households.5 [Insert Figure 3] Public housing is a highly regulated submarket in Singapore, and its sheer market size eclipses the private housing market. However, the public housing markets are more homogenous and standardized in term of design and unit size, although quality of flat have been improved over time by the HDB to meet rising inspiration and expectation of new HDB dwellers. The prices of resale housing HDB flats are determined in the open-market, and they are used to represent the public housing submarket in this study. However, we do not further differentiate the housing types, such as executive flat, 5-room and 4-room, within the public housing submarket in this study. Figure 3 shows the hierarchical structure of both the private and public housing submarkets. 5 Executive condominium (EC) is a hybrid housing class that is created in the mid 1996 to meet the “sandwiched” class of young professionals, and also to stabilize the overheating private housing prices. The EC sites are sold by the government at discounts to make ECs more affordable (Chua, 2000). The prices of ECs may be “distorted” and they are excluded in the study. 6 The private housing sub-market by the pricing structure6 into different hierarchical strata, which follow in an ascending from the highest priced landed houses, such as detached house, semi-detached house, and terrace, to non-landed houses like condominium and apartments (Table 1). Table 1 summarizes some key characteristics in both private and public housing submarkets in Singapore. Based on the caveats lodged on 2,875 transactions of private housing units in 4Q2003, the average prices for the five classes of private housing were computed. There is a clear hierarchical order in the transaction prices, with detached house with an average land area of 1,314.75 square meters (sqm) sold at S$4,927,479 on average. Apartment units have smaller average floor area of 125.46 sqm, and the average selling price was S$743,830 in 4Q2003. In comparison, the resale HDB price was relatively lower ranging from S$403,400 to S$159,300 for executive flat to 3-room flat respectively. In term of the housing stocks, the proportion of stock of public housing skews the scale with nearly 80% of the total stock as in 4Q2003. The non-landed private housing consisting of condominium and apartment was the second largest housing sector with 14% of the total housing stock. Due to the scarcity of land, the landed sector commands market premiums, and they are only owned by a small “unconstrained” group of households in the higher income category (6.54%). [Insert Table 1] The hierarchical price structure in the hosing submarkets implies that there exists segmentation between different sub-sectors of the housing markets. Empirical tests of the segmentation hypothesis for the sub-sectors in both private and public housing markets will be conducted in this study. With the price hierarchy in the housing markets, price discovery and mobility are likely to occur in a more progressive and incremental process from one sub-market to another. We hypothesize that upgrading of households will more likely to occur from one stratum of housing submarket to the one immediately above or below it. For example, HDB upgraders who faces financial constraint will more likely to sell their public housing, and use the accrued equity to purchase an apartment or condominium. Landed houses may be out-of-the-reach of these constrained movers. There are two hypotheses on price discovery and upward mobility that will be tested in this study. Firstly, we will test whether segmentation exists in a hierarchical order between the different sub-sectors of housing markets. We use the modified Engle and Granger (1987) bivariate conintegration tests to test whether hierarchical stratification of the hosing submarkets. The hierarchical strafication of housing market hypothesis is not rejected, if we find only significant bivariate cointegration between two intermediate stratums of the housing submarkets. There are no significant long-rum contemporaneous relationships between two submarkets that are not in contiguous order in the hierarchy. In other words, we expect that the public housing to have significant cointegration with apartment submarket, rather than with detached housing submarket. The second hypothesis involves testing the price discovery in different housing submarkets using the vector autoregressive (VAR) analysis. The stratification 6 This price structure is based on the total price of typical type of house in each class. As shown in Table 1, the unit prices of landed houses are smaller than non-landed because of the larger land area taken by most of the landed houses. 7 and segmentation of the submarket structure will also means that price discovery process is likely to take place between two contiguous strata in the hierarchical market structure. Shocks in condominium market will likely to cause price changes in terrace and apartment, rather than price variations in public housing market. 4. Empirical Methodology 4.1. Data Collection Based on the hierarchical housing market structure proposed in Figure 3, prices of different housing classes, transformed into logarithm form, are obtained for the tests. Time series price data for the private submarkets: detached, semi-detached, terrace, condominium and apartment, and the public resale were collected on a quarterly basis for a 14-year sample period from 1Q1990 to 2Q2004. The private housing market price indices were obtained mainly from the Real Estate Information System (REALIS) of the URA, and the public resale price index was collected from the HDB. We also obtained time series data for other exogenous macro-economic variables that are included in the VAR model include GDP, mortgage interest rate.., from the Singapore Time-Series System of the Department of Statistics (DOS), Singapore. The housing submarkets are differentiated by a subscript i in the price variable, Pi, where [i = (det, sdt, ter, cod, apt, hdb)], and the natural log-version of the price is represented by the lower case of the variable, [pi = log(Pi)]. The return of the housing prices is computed by taking the first order difference of the log-price for each of the housing sector, [ri = dpi,t = (pi,t – pi,t-1)]. The notations used for the variable and their respective sources are summarized in Table 2. [Insert Table 2] 4.2. Model Specifications and Modeling Strategies 1990s is a highly volatile period in the housing market, which witnessed sharp rise in the prices in the 1994 to 1995 period, followed by price crashes associated mainly with the government intervention and the regional financial crisis in the 1996 and 1997. Many housing studies have used a-priori defined regime shift dummy variable to capture the permanent shocks to the housing price trends in their models (Phang and Wong, 1997; Sing, 2001; Lum, 2002; Phang, 2004). This approach of modeling structural break and regime shift, coupled with the Chow test, may not be accurate when the break effects are more difficulty to ascertain when the number of break points increases. When shocks is permanent, rather than transitory, cointegration results based on the standard Engle-Granger (1987) tests will produce biased conclusions. This paper one of the first works that applies the STOPBREAK model developed by Engle and Smith (1999) to empirically test the stratification and segmentation hypothesis in the housing market. The STOPBREAK model allows for time-varying or stochastic shocks in the long-run relationships between two time series. Next, we would test the inter- and intra-market price discovery hypotheses using the vector autoregressive approach. 8 4.2.1. Cointegration and Stochastic permanent break (STOPBREAK) model The Engle and Granger (1987) and Johansen (1988) cointegration methodologies have been well established and widely applied in economics and finance literature. According to Engle and Granger (1987), two series integrated in the order d, I(d), are cointegrated, if the linear combination of the two series, [Yt = βXt + ut], results in a residual, ut, that is stationary in less than order d. The results hold if there are no short-term shocks that will destabilize the equilibrium in the system. When economic shocks cause permanent and transitory shift to the equilibrium, the long-term impact of the shocks is time-varying or stochastic. Engle and Smith (1999) propose a stochastic break (STOPBREAK) approach to model a class of processes that incur random structural shift at random intervals. They conjecture that a pair of variables may move together for periods of time and jump apart occasionally. Engle and Smith (1999) call this process a temporary cointegration. Engle and Smith (1999) define the simplest form of STOPBREAK process for a time series yt is given as follows: y t = mt + ε t , t=0,1,...,T (1) where mt = E[ yt I t −1 ] is a time varying conditional mean, and ε t is error term. t mt = mt −1 + qt −1ε t −1 = m0 + ∑ qt −i ε t −i , t=1,2,...,T (2) i =1 where qt = q(ε t ) ∈ (0,1) s.t E[qt ε t I t −1 ] = 0 The above STOPBREAK process is a process where shock effects are permanent and determined endogenously in the process. If q~t =1, the realized process at time t is a random walk. If q~t = 0, the conditional mean will be a constant, the long-run forecast for y will not be deviated from the mean value of q~ . t t When a pair of time-series variables ( Yt , X t ) is involved, the general STOPBREAK process can be specified as follows: A( L) B( L)(Yt − X t δ ) = z t −1 A( L)ε t + (1 − z t −1 ) B ( L)ε t , t=1,2,...,T (3) where A( L) = 1 − α 1 L − α 2 L2 − ... − α p L p , B( L) = 1 − β 1 L − β 2 L2 − ... − β p L p , L is the lag operator, z t denotes measurable function of information up to t, and ε t is an innovation term. If δ =0, B(L)=1-L, A(L)=1, the model comply with the simplest form of STOPBREAK process. Alternatively, if δ ≠ 0, then we can say that the two series establish only temporary cointegration effect, where the two series jump apart occasionally and revert back to the equilibrium relationship in the long-run. To test the persistence of STOPBREAK process, let’s assume that q t (γ ) = ε t2 , γ + ε t2 and the process in (1) and (2) can be written as follows: 9 ∆yt = − γε t −1 + εt γ + ε t2−1 (4) Based on equation (4), the random walk null hypothesis can be tested as, [Ho: γ = 0], against the alternative hypothesis, [H1:γ = γ ]. Engle & Smith (1999) found a locally best test with sufficient to test the null hypothesis Ho: ϕ =0 against a negative alternative using t-tests, where ϕ can be estimated using the following regression: ∆y t −1 ∆y t = ϕ + µt (5) γ + ∆y t2−1 In this study, the STOPBREAK approach will be used to test the dynamic long-term process of relative prices of different pairs of housing sub-markets over time, after endogenously correcting economic shocks that are either transience or permanence. 4.2.2. Vector Autoregressive Error Correction Model (VECM) After establishing whether there exist significant segmentation and hierarchical stratification of the housing submarkets in Singapore, we would proceed with the tests of price discovery across different submarkets using a dynamic Vector Autoregressive (VAR) framework proposed by Sims (1980). In the earlier cointegration tests, we found evidence of cointegration among the public housing market and the five private housing sub-markets. Therefore, it would be useful to include cointegrating vectors in the VAR process to adjust for the short-term variations between the two time series. Vector autoregressive error-correction models (VECM) comprising the price variables of different submarkets and other exogenous macro-economic variables are specified, together with the cointegrating vectors that are used to explicitly deal with the issue of stationarity in the proposed model.7 For a bivariate VECM system, the generalized equations for both the residential property price and inflation variables with n-period lags could be formally represented as follows, n n p =1 q =1 ∆y t = γ y µ t −1 + ∑ α p ∆y t − p + ∑ β q ∆xt − q + ε t (6) where yt are 6x1 vectors of endogenous log-price variables for public resale HDB, apartment, condominium, terrace, semi-detached and detached houses; xt are k- vector of exogenous variables, which include both demand and supply side factors like building material price, all-share return, gdp growth rate, prime lending rate, household formation as represented by increase in number of marriage, and unexpected inflation rate in our study; A time dummy is also included to capture the break that occur after the Asian financial crisis, and it is represented by dum1Q98, which has a value 1 for periods after 1Q1998, and zero otherwise; αp and βp are matrices of coefficients to be jointly estimated in the VAR process with appropriate p 7 The controversy is whether the variables included in a VAR should be stationary or not. According to Engle and Granger (1987), if the variables are differenced and are cointegrated in the same order, the correct method is to estimate the Vector ECM, which is a VAR with the addition of a vector of cointegrating residual. Thus, this VAR system does not lose long-run information. 10 and q lags, and εt is a vector of innovation term. For the cointegrated series, the error correction term (µt-1), which represents the speed of adjustment toward the long-run values, is added in the VAR model. To differentiate VARs with cointegrated vectors from the standard VAR in equation (6), γ with a binomial discrete value of 0 and 1 is included, such that γ= 0 if the two variables are not cointegrated, and γ≠0 otherwise. 5. Data Analysis and Empirical Tests 5.1. Unit Root Tests The standard Augmented Dickey-Fuller (1984) and Phillips-Perron (1988) tests are conducted to test the order of integration of the log-price variables for different housing sub-markets and the macro-economic variables. The results are summarized in Table 3. The results showed that most of the housing market price variables are I(1) stationary. The consumer price index is clearly a I(0) stationary variable as indicated by both the ADF and PP test statistics. There was sufficient evidence, based on the two tests, to suggest that all other macro-economic variables like building material price, gdp growth, all-share return, prime lending rate and household formation are first order stationary. In the subsequent EVCM tests, we would include the unexpected inflation and prime lending rate, which are stock variables, in level term in the VECM model, whereas other supply and demand side variables are included in the first order difference terms. [Insert Table 3] 5.2. Cointegration and STOPBREAK Tests We first conducted the pair-wise cointegration tests using firstly the standard Johansen (1988) estimation, and then the time-varying stochastic shocks are allowed in the Engle and Smith (1998) STOPBREAK model. The results of the Johansen’s cointegration tests, which do not adjust for possible transitory and permanent shocks, give weak evidence of cointegration between HDB resale price and the three landed housing submarkets.8 We next move on to adjust for possible shocks that could be transient or permanence in nature caused by economic events in the 1990s like the Asian financial crisis in 1997. The STOPBREAK model proposed by Engle and Smith (1999) provides a useful framework for testing the long-run relationships between pairs of sub-housing market prices, which will not restrict temporary deviation of the price series as a result of shocks. The t-statistics of the STOPBREAK tests are summarized in Table 4. The results showed that the number of significant pair-wise cointgration relationships between the housing sub-sectors increase when permanent and transitory shocks are made endogenous in the STOPBREAK models. We rejected the random walk null hypothesis for the HDB resale price and the prices of all private housing sub-markets, indicating that shocks may have established some permanent and transitory impacts on the relative price processes in the public and all strata of the private housing market. While we rejected that the public market and private market are segmented, but we found no evidence to justify the hierarchical stratification in the two housing 8 The Trace test statistics at the asymptotic 5% critical values for the pair-wise cointegration tests using Johansen’s (1988) estimation methodology are given in Table 4(b) in the Appendix 11 markets. However, based on the STOPBREAK test results in the private housing submarkets, we did observe cointegration on two pair of private housing sub-sectors: apartment-condominium and terrace and semi-detached, which may not fully rule out the stratification hypothesis in the private markets. The reactions of detached housing price to economic shocks were significantly different from those experienced by other private housing sub-markets, which thus explain that detached housing sector is rather segmented from other private housing submarkets. In shorts, we rejected the segmentation hypothesis between public housing and other private housing submarkets. We also found stratification in selected strata of the private housing submarkets, where cointegrations were only significant between a pair of non-landed and also a pair of landed housing markets (terrace and semi-detached). Stochastic price shocks were not observed between the detached housing market and other private housing submarkets. [Insert Table 4] 5.3. Vector Autoregressive Error Correction Models Other testing the pair-wise stochastic shocks and cointegration relationships across the housing submarkets, we continue our price discovery tests by first testing the multivariate cointegration in the housing submarkets using the Johansen and Juseliu’s (1990) methodology. In the multivate tests, the exogenous variables like dbmp, dgdp, dmar, PLR and unexp are included to control for demand and supply side effects, and dum1Q98, the time dummy to correct for the impact of 1997 financial crisis is also added. The unrestricted cointegration rank test results were summarized in Table 5. The trace tests showed that there were six cointegrating vectors at 5% significant level among the six housing submarkets, whereas, the Eigenvalue statistics showed that there exist only four significant cointegrating vectors in the multivariate equations. [Insert Table 5] We incorporate four normalized cointegrating equations in the VECM models that comprise six endogenous housing submarket prices, and other exogenous variables to test the price formation processes for different housing submarkets. The results of the VECM estimation with only one-period lag term for different housing price variables were summarized in Table 6. The findings differ from the earlier results in Ong and Sing (2002), who found significant bi-directional price discovery between public and private housing markets. Our results indicate that price changes in various private housing submarkets have not significant explanatory relationships on the price variations in HDB resale houses. The price discovery process in the HDB resale market is fully rejected, because there was still a price correction mechanism through the cointegrating vector, which captures some of the private housing market price dynamics. The price variations for HDB resale houses were also explained by the building material price, prime lending rate and unexpected inflation. [Insert Table 6] All of the private housing price models have at least one significant cointegrating vector reversing the price back to long-run equilibrium. We also observe that the lastquarter detached housing price have significant explanatory impact on other four 12 private housing submarkets. The coefficients of dpdet(-1) are significant and positive, which may imply that the increase in housing wealth of detached households, who are less financially constrained, will motivate them to allocate part of their accrued wealth through investment in other private housing submarkets. The mobility behavior of this group of unconstrained households may not fit into the unconstrained mover group described by Stein (1995), who moves when price declines. In land scare Singapore, housing can be regarded as a symbol of wealth, which can be included an investment asset in a household’s portfolio, the wealthy or unconstrained households are likely to increase their housing consumption by adding new housing into their portfolio, while staying put at their existing detached houses that have appreciated in prices. Therefore, the wealth accrued in detached housing submarket is translated into price increases in other private housing sector. Lagged-period condominium housing price changes were also found to convey significant price information to the price generating processes in semi-detached and detached housing submarkets. The results may fit well into the constrained mover group of Stein (1995), who may find the wealth accumulated from the rising prices in their private condominium increases their affordability to move up the housing hierarchical “ladder” to landed houses. Negative price discovery effects were observed from apartment submarkets to condominium and terrace submarkets. The reverse negative price discovery process was also noted from terrace to apartment submarkets. The close-substitutability of the types and relative pricing of the housing options in the three housing submarkets could be one of the reasons explaining the negative price effects. The same observation was also found between semi-detached and detached housing submarkets. Other exogenous macroeconomic variables that have significant explanatory effects on housing prices include the building material price, prime lending rate, stock market wealth, and unexpected inflations. The coefficients of these variables are of correct signs. We also noted that the time dummy that represent that the post-1997 Asian financial crisis structural adjustment was significant in the landed housing pricing models: terrace, semi-detached and detached housing submarkets. 6. Conclusion Public housing is the largest housing submarket in Singapore, which constitutes a nearly 80% of the total housing stocks as in 4Q2004, and public housing units are normally sold at a subsidized rate by the government via its housing agency, the Housing Development Board. The public housing price is regulated and less susceptible to market volatility compared to the private housing prices. There is an active resale public housing market, where public housing dwellers are allowed to trade their houses after a time-bar of five years from the date of their purchase. This segment of resale HDB market is liken the private housing submarkets, where housing prices are more dependent on the market demand and supply conditions. The prices are also more likely to fluctuate in accordance to the market and economic cycles. This study examined whether there is clear stratification of the two housing submarkets in some hierarchical structure. Price discovery processes between the private and public housing sub-markets were also tested in this study using vector error correction models (VECM). 13 Using the STOPBREAK tests, we rejected the random walk null hypothesis for the HDB resale price and the prices of all private housing sub-markets, indicating that shocks may have established some permanent or transitory impacts on the relative price processes in the public and all strata of the private housing market. While we rejected that the public market and private market are segmented, but we found no evidence to justify the hierarchical stratification in the two housing markets. The segmentation in the private housing sub-markets was less clear cut. We observe STOPBREAK cointegration in the relatively prices of two pair of private housing sub-sectors: apartment-condominium and terrace and semi-detached, which may not fully rule out the stratification hypothesis in the private markets. In shorts, we rejected the segmentation hypothesis between public housing and other private housing submarkets. We also found stratification in selected strata of the private housing submarkets, where cointegrations were only significant between a pair of non-landed and also a pair of landed housing markets (terrace and semi-detached). In the Johansen’s multivariate cointegration tests, we found at least four significant cointegrating vectors in the six endogenous housing submarkets. At least one cointegrating vector was found to be significant in explaining the short-term price dynamics in the housing submarkets in our VECM models, which provide some evidence of price discovery in the short-run price processes in the housing submarkets. Our results indicate that after incorporating the error correction term, price changes in the private housing submarkets have not significant explanatory relationships on the price variations in HDB resale houses. In the private housing submarkets, we observed significant and positive price effects from detached submarket to other private housing submarkets, which may imply that the increase in housing wealth of detached households, who are less financially constrained, will motivate them to allocate part of their accrued wealth through investment in other private housing submarkets. The wealth accrued in detached housing submarket is translated into price increases in other private housing sector. Lagged-period condominium housing price changes were also found to convey significant price information to the price generating processes in semi-detached and detached housing submarkets. However, negative price discovery effects were observed from apartment submarkets to condominium and terrace submarkets, also from semi-detached to detached submarkets. The close-substitutability of the types and relative pricing of the housing options in the private housing submarkets could be one of the reasons explaining the negative price effects. 14 Reference: Ambrose, B.W., Chu, Y.Q., SaAadu, J. and Sing, T.F. (2003), “Default Risk in Adjustable Rate Mortgages: Effects of Change to CPF Withdrawal Limits in Singapore,” working paper, Department of Real Estate, National University of Singapore. Bardhan, A.D., Datta, R., Edelstein,R.H. and Lum, S.K. (2003), “A Tale of Two Sectors: Upward Mobility And The Private Housing Market In Singapore,” Journal of Housing Economics, 12, 83-105. Barkhan, R. and Geltner, D. (1995), “Price Discovery in American and British Property Markets,” Real Estate Economics, 23(1), 21-44. Chua, B.H. (2000), “Public Housing Residents as Clients of the State,” Housing Studies, 15(1), 45-60. Edelstein, R.H. and Lum, S.K. (2003), “House Prices, Wealth Effects and The Singapore Macroeconomy,” paper presented at the International Workshop on “Housing Market and the Macro Economy: the Nexus,” jointly organized by the Centre for Public Policy Studies at Lingnan University and the Economics Department of the Chinese University of Hong Kong, 15-16 August 2003. Engle, R.F. and Granger, C.W.J. (1987), “Cointegration and Error Correction Representation, Estimation and Testing,” Econometrica, 25,1225-1228. Engle, R.F. and Smith, A.D. (1999), “Stochastic Permanent Breaks,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 81(4), 553-574. Gyourko, J. and Keim, D. (1992), “What does the Stock Market tell us about Real Estate Returns?” Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 20, 457-485. Johansen, S. (1988), “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, Vol. 12, pp. 231-254 Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990), “Maximum Likelikhood Estimation and Inference on Cointegration – with Application to the Demand for Money,” Oxford Bulletin Economics and Statistics, 52(2), 169-210. Lamont, O. and Stein, J.C. (1999), “Leverage and House-Price Dynamics in U.S. Cities,” RAND Journal of Economics, 30(3), 498-514. Lee, N.J. and Ong, S.E. (2003), “Upward Mobility, House Price Volatility and Prepayement Risk, working paper of Department of Real Estate, National Universityo of Singapore. Liow, K.H. (1998), “Singapore Commercial Real Estate and Property Equity Markets: Close Relations?” Real Estate Finance, 41,603-616. 15 Liow K.H. (2001), “The Long-term Investment Performance of Singapore Real Estate and Property Stocks,” Journal of Property Investment and Finance, 19(2), 156-174. Liu, C.H., Hartzell, D.J., Greig, W. and Grissom, T.V. (1990), “Integration of the Real Estate Market and the Stock Market: Some Preliminary Evidence,” Journal of Real Estate Finance & Economics, 3, 261-282. Lizieri, C. and Satchell, S. (1997), “Interactions Between Property and Equity Markets: An Investigation of Linkages in the United Kingdom 1972-1992,” Journal of Real Estate Finance & Economics, 15(1), 11-26. Lum, S.K. (2002), “Market Fundamentals, Public Policy and Private Gain: House Price Dynamics in Singapore,” Journal of Property Research, 19(2), 121-143. Ng, H.M. (2001), “Private Residential Property Market and the Macroeconomy,” Economic Survey of Singapore, First Quarter 2002, Ministry of Trade and Industry, Singapore. Okunev, J. and Wilson, P.J. (1997), “Using Nonlinear Tests to Examine Integration Between Real Estate and Stock Markets,” Real Estate Economics, 25(3), 487-503. Ong, S.E. (1994), “Structural and Vector Autoregressive Approaches to Modelling Real Estate and Property Stock Prices in Singapore,” Journal of Property Finance, 5(4), 4-18. Ong, S.E. (1995), “Singapore Real Estate & Property Stocks – A Cointegration Test,” Journal of Property Research, 12, 29-39. Ong, S.E. (2000), “Housing Affordability and Upward Mobility from Public to Private Housing in Singapore,” International Real Estate Review, 3(1), 49-64. Ong, S.E. and Sing, T.F. (2002), “Price Discovery between Private and Public Housing Markets,” Urban Studies, 39(1), 57-67. Phang, S.Y. (2001), “Housing Policy, Wealth Formation and the Singapore Economy,” Housing Studies, 16(4), 443-459. Phang, S.Y. (2004), “House Prices and Aggregate Consumption: do they Move together? Evidence from Singapore,” Journal of Housing Economics, 13, 101-119. Phang, S.Y. and Wong, W.K. (1997), “Government Policies and Private Housing Prices in Singapore,” Urban Studies, 34(11), 1819-1829. Schwann, G.M. and Chau, K.W. (2003), “New Effects and Structural Shifts in Price Discovery in Hong Kong,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 27(2), 257-271. Sims, C. (1980). “Macroeconomics and Reality,” Econometrica. 48, 1-48. Sing, T.F. (2001), “Dynamics of the Condominium Market in Singapore,” International Real Estate Review, 4(1), 135-158. 16 Sing, T.F. (2004), “Common Risk Factors and Risk Premia in Direct And Securitized Real Estate Markets,” working paper of the Department of Real Estate, National University of Singapore. Sing, T.F. and Sng, S.B.S. (2003), “Conditional Variance Tests of Integration Between Direct and Indirect Real Estate Markets,” Journal of Property Investment & Finance, 21(4), 366-382. Stein, J.C. (1995), “Prices and Trading Volume in the Housing Market: A model with Down-payment Effects,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 379-406. Wilson, P., Okunev, J. and Ta, G. (1996), “Are Real Estate and Securities Markets Integrated? Some Australian Evidence,” Journal of Property Valuation & Investment, 14(5), 7-24. 17 Table 1: Characteristics of Private and Public Housing Markets in Singapore Housing Type Average Floor/ Land Area (sqm)# A) Private Housing Market: Detached 1314.75 House Semi-Detached 340.10 House terrace 208.18 Condominium 133.79 Apartment 125.46 Average Transacted Price (S$)# Average Unit Price (S$ psm)# No of Caveat Lodged (as at 4Q03)# Housing Stock (as at 4Q03)@ % of Total Housing Stock 4,927,479 4,062 104 9,915 0.97% 1,440,098 4,452 143 20,628 2.01% 1,052,364 803,168 5,344 5,867 314 1513 36,549 85,869 3.56% 8.36% 743,830 6,274 801 57,973 5.65% Total*3 815,633 65,143 201,152 318,668 220,696 79.45% 7.99% 24.66% 39.07% 27.06% B) Public Housing Market: HDB data: Executive Flat 5-Room 4-Room 3-Room *1 *2 130 110 90 69 403,400 321,500 232,800 159,300 3,103 2,923 2,587 2,309 # The statistics are computed based on caveats lodged on all private residential properties transacted from 1 September 2003 to 31 December 20003, as captured in Real Estate Information System (REALIS) of the URA. @ The cumulative housing stock information is obtained from the time-series data in REALIS, URA *1 The size of different public housing types is taken from typical new housing flat type built by HDB. The size for different HDB flats may have changed over time. *2 The resale price was the 4Q average resale HDB flats that were published on the Business time, “Prices of HDB resale flats rise 1.2% in Q2 from Q1,” by Andrea Tan, 24 July 2004. *3 The total housing stock number was obtained from the HDB annual report 2002/2003, and the number does not include rental flats (53,141) Note: Condominium and apartment are two common non-landed housing types built by private developers, they are quite homogenous in physical, but prices differs especially between the high- and middle-end condominium, and apartment. The total stock size of apartment is also smaller, but the hierarchy structure is determined based mainly on price structure in this study. Source: URA, HDB 18 Table 2: List of Variables and Derivations Notation Variable Description A) Public housing market: Phdb Resale HDB housing price index B) Private housing market: Papt Apartment price index Pcod Condominium price index Pter Terrace price index Psed Semi-detached housing price index Pdet Detached housing price index C) Macro-economic variable: GDP Gross domestic products SGX Singapore Exchange All-share index PLR Prime lending rate CPI Consumer price index MAR Total number of marriages Derivation of Variable: dphdb ln-return of HDB price dpapt ln-return of apartment price dpcod ln-return of condominium price dpter ln-return of terrace price dpsed ln-return of semi-detached price dpdet ln-return of detached price dgdp Growth in GDP dsgx All-share return in natural log term dmar Change in number of marriage in natural log term uxcpi Unexpected inflation rate * Source HDB URA URA URA URA URA DOS DOS DOS DOS DOS phdb,t – phdb,t-1 papt,t -papt,t-1 pcod,t – pcod,t-1 pter,t – pter,t-1 psed,t – psed,t-1 pdet,t – pdet,t-1 gdpt - gdpt-1 sgxt - sgxt-1 mart - mart-1 Derived using Fama & Gibbons (1984) (Appendix 1) The natural logarithm form of the variables are represented in lower case of the respective notations 19 Table 3: Results of Unit Root Tests Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) Unit Root Test ADF t-statistics Variable PP Adj. t-statistics -1.957 1st order difference -3.266* Order of integration I(1) -1.784 1st order difference -3.241* Order of integration I(1) -2.570 -3.978* I(1) -2.174 -4.078* I(1) -2.138 -3.517* I(1) -1.997 -3.568* I(1) -2.253 -3.203* I(1) -2.052 -3.217* I(1) -2.471 -3.443* I(1) -2.031 -3.475* I(1) -2.111 -3.392* I(1) -1.899 -3.406* I(1) -2.127 -4.204* I(1) -1.546 -4.204* I(1) -3.110* -4.023* I(0) -4.562* -3.855* I(0) -2.819* -5.304* I(0) -1.544 -5.157* I(1) -3.296* -5.263* I(0) -2.479 -5.287* I(1) -2.157 -6.967* I(1) -3.330* -6.300* I(0) 2.131 -2.035 I(2) -1.369 -3.276* I(1) Level symbol HDB housing phdb price Apartment papt price Condominium pcod Price Terrace Price pter Semi-detached psed Price Detached Price pdet Building bmp Material Price Consumer cpi Price Index Prime Lending PLR Rate All-Share sgx Index GDP gdp Total Number mar of Marriages *significant at the 5% level Phillips-Perron (PP) Unit Root Test Level Table 4: t-Statistics of STOPBREAK Hypothesis Tests Variable HDB Resale price, phdb Apartment price, papt Condominium price, pcod Terrace perice, pter Semi-Detached price, psed Apartment price, papt Condominium price, pcod Terrace perice, pter Detached price, pdet 3.79* SemiDetached price, psed 3.75* 3.29* 3.59* -2.53* -0.01 0.15 1.13 -1.37 1.15 1.75 -3.05* 0.23 3.38* -1.23 Ho: the relative price follows a random walk process, i.e. there is no cointegration in the series. * indicates significance at 5% 20 Table 5: Results Johansen and Juselius’s (1990) Cointegration Tests Sample (adjusted): 1990Q4 2004Q1 Trend assumption: No deterministic trend (restricted constant) Series: dphdp, dpapt, dpcod, dpter,dpsed, dpdet Exogenous series: dbmp, dsgx, dgdp, dmar, PLR, uxcpi, dum1Q98 Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1 A) Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Trace) Hypothesized Trace 0.05 No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value Prob.** None * 0.6742 222.6559 103.8473 0.0000 At most 1 * 0.6269 162.0982 76.9728 0.0000 At most 2 * 0.6030 108.8610 54.0790 0.0000 At most 3 * 0.4714 58.9699 35.1928 0.0000 At most 4 * 0.2312 24.5437 20.2618 0.0121 At most 5 * 0.1744 10.3481 9.1645 0.0297 Trace test indicates 6 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values B) Unrestricted Cointegration Rank Test (Maximum Eigenvalue) Hypothesized Max-Eigen 0.05 No. of CE(s) Eigenvalue Statistic Critical Value Prob.** None * 0.6742 60.5577 40.9568 0.0001 At most 1 * 0.6269 53.2372 34.8059 0.0001 At most 2 * 0.6030 49.8911 28.5881 0.0000 At most 3 * 0.4714 34.4262 22.2996 0.0006 At most 4 0.2312 14.1956 15.8921 0.0906 At most 5 * 0.1744 10.3481 9.1645 0.0297 Max-eigenvalue test indicates 4 cointegrating eqn(s) at the 0.05 level * denotes rejection of the hypothesis at the 0.05 level **MacKinnon-Haug-Michelis (1999) p-values 21 Table 6: Vector Error Correction Estimates Dependent Variables:: dphdb dpapt dpcod dpter Dpsed dpdet -0.3571** [-2.6060] 0.1989 [ 0.6009] -0.0945 [-0.2977] 0.5942 [ 1.3035] -0.0770 [-0.4140] -0.2291 [-1.1361] 0.0869 [ 0.3864] 0.0803 [ 0.2836] 0.3633 [ 1.5200] -0.0978 [-0.5324] 1.4684** [ 2.0573] -0.0093 [-0.1358] 0.1254 [ 0.5050] 0.0039 [ 0.9016] -1.3569** [-2.0035] 0.0249* [ 1.7086] -0.0263 [-1.6589] -0.0884 [-0.8810] -0.9571*** [-3.9487] 0.5473** [ 2.3548] 1.0251*** [ 3.0710] -0.2004 [-1.4726] -0.2576* [-1.7442] -0.0324 [-0.1970] -0.5396** [-2.6026] 0.0751 [ 0.4292] 0.5560*** [ 4.1331] 0.6902 [ 1.3204] 0.2122*** [ 4.2481] -0.1107 [-0.6084] 0.0013 [ 0.4288] 0.1027 [ 0.2071] 0.0082 [ 0.7659] -0.0061 [-0.5282] -0.0641 [-0.4734] 0.5483* [ 1.6761] -0.8129 [-2.5913] 1.1597** [ 2.5741] -0.2309 [-1.2566] -0.3831* [-1.9222] 0.0793 [ 0.3566] -0.4078 [-1.4574] 0.3297 [ 1.3956] 0.3673** [ 2.0226] -0.7683 [-1.0891] 0.1022 [ 1.5159] -0.3013 [-1.2275] 0.0012 [ 0.2922] -1.2825* [-1.9159] 0.0106 [ 0.7354] -0.0213 [-1.3594] -0.5770*** [-5.0257] 0.3030 [ 1.0927] 0.4109 [ 1.5452] -0.9809** [-2.5686] 0.1578 [ 1.0133] -0.3187* [-1.8866] 0.1463 [ 0.7763] -0.1391 [-0.5863] -0.2587 [-1.2922] 0.3807** [ 2.4737] 0.7888 [ 1.3191] 0.2189*** [ 3.8317] -0.3042 [-1.4620] 0.0031 [ 0.8655] -1.9882*** [-3.5040] 0.0226* [ 1.8464] -0.0396*** [-2.9756] -0.5763*** [-4.8338] 0.3792 [ 1.3166] -0.0489 [-0.1772] 0.3072 [ 0.7745] 0.3013* [ 1.8631] -0.2735 [-1.5588] 0.4291** [ 2.1929] -0.3641 [-1.4779] -0.3997* [-1.9219] 0.4863*** [ 3.0423] 1.0741* [ 1.7295] 0.2508*** [ 4.2263] -0.0571 [-0.2643] 0.0051 [ 1.3730] -2.4431*** [-4.1458] 0.0022 [ 0.1720] -0.0502*** [-3.6334] -0.6717*** [-4.6849] 0.7346** [ 2.1216] -0.4538 [-1.3668] 0.4436 [ 0.9301] 0.2459 [ 1.2645] -0.3466 [-1.6431] 0.6533*** [ 2.7768] -0.1847 [-0.6237] -0.6773*** [-2.7087] 0.6605*** [ 3.4366] 0.7299 [ 0.9774] 0.2298*** [ 3.2202] -0.1944 [-0.7483] 0.0053 [ 1.1907] -4.3526*** [-6.1428] -0.0027 [-0.1768] -0.0690*** [-4.1535] Adj. R2 0.3216 0.6708 0.3138 0.5021 0.6217 0.6284 Cointegrating Equations: dphdb(-1) dpapt(-1) dpcod(-1) dpter(-1) dpsed(-1) CointEq1 CointEq3 CointEq4 CointEq1 CointEq2 CointEq3 CointEq4 dphdp(-1) dpapt(-1) dpcod(-1) dpter(-1) dpsed(-1) dpdet(-1) dbmp dsgx dgdp dmar PLR uxcpi dum1Q98 CointEq2 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.0000 -9.4201*** -12.7422*** -14.5032*** -5.1417*** [-6.4587] [-6.1960] [-6.1487] [-6.6782] 8.4592*** 10.4345*** 11.9896*** 3.6293*** dpdet(-1) [ 6.9299] [ 6.0624] [ 6.0735] [ 5.6324] C -0.6859** -0.4903 -0.6437 -0.1737 [-2.4254] [-1.2297] [-1.4074] [-1.1634] t-statistics in brackets [ ]; C is the intercept term; and CointEq(k) is cointegrating vector. *10% significance: 1.674; **5 % sigificance: 2.005; *** 1% significance: 2.670 22 200 35% 180 30% 160 25% 20% 140 15% 120 10% 100 5% 80 0% 60 -5% Rate of Change in Price Index (% Property Price Index Figure 1: Historical Price and Return Trends of Private Residential Properties and HDB Resale Flats 40 -10% 20 -15% 0 -20% 3 2 1 0 7 8 9 5 4 6 1 3 2 0 4 99 199 199 199 199 199 199 199 199 199 200 200 200 200 200 -1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Q Private Residential Property Price Index Return of Private Residential Prperty Price Qtr-year HDB Resale Price Index Return of HDB Resale Price 23 Figure 2: Distribution of Private Non-Landed Property Stock by Ownership 100% Proportion of Homeownership in Private Non-Landed Properties (%) 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 2 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4Q 3Q 2Q 1Q 0Q 9Q 8Q 7Q 6Q 0 0 0 0 0 9 9 9 9 Year-Qtr 20 20 20 20 20 19 19 19 19 Foreigner Permanent Resident Singaporean Company 24 Figure 3: Hierarchical Stratification of Public and Private Housing Types Increase in Price (typical Unit) Increase in Market Share (Stock) Stein’s (1995) Mobility Classes Detached House Unconstrained Mover SemiSemi-Detached House Terrace House Constrained Mover Condominium Apartment* Public Housing / HDB Flat Constrained Non-mover *See Table 1. The market share of apartment is smaller than condominium. These two housing types are quite homogeneous in design and appeal, and are always grouped as non-landed private residential housing. Besides price, the two housing types are differentiated by the size of land parcel they are built thereon, and the facilities provided in the development. Condominium will be equipped full-scaled facilities and services, and must be built on land that are larger than 0.4 hectare. With the condominium status, there are no restrictions on foreign ownership. Whereas for apartment, which is smaller in scale, only units in block more than 6-storey height could be sold to foreigners. 25 Appendix 1 Table 4: t-Statistics of STOPBREAK Hypothesis Tests Variable Apartment price, papt Condominium price, pcod HDB Resale 14.40 14.34 price, phdb Apartment 10.40 price, papt Condominium price, pcod Terrace perice, pter Semi-Detached price, psed Ho: the number of cointegration equation is zero * indicates significance at 5% Terrace perice, pter Detached price, pdet 16.43* SemiDetached price, psed 26.99* 14.77 13.45 14.44 10.64 14.42 14.13 12.59 9.05 19.87* 8.07 26