Fund Performance and Equity Lending: Why Lend What You Can Sell? Richard Evans - Darden School of Business Miguel Ferreira - Nova School of Business and Economics Melissa Prado - Nova School of Business and Economics The Market for Lending/Borrowing Stock Owner of stock • Beneficial owner – fund investors • Owner of record – mutual fund/custodian Shares Fees Collateral (102%) Shares Securities Lender Rebate Collateral Collateral pool (Cash, Treasuries, MBS, uh oh…) Income/Ret. Borrower/ Short seller Should Funds Lend? • Measures of short-selling predict future underperformance - Short interest – Asquith, Pathak, Ritter (2005) - Specialness – Geczy, Musto, Reed (2002) - Loan supply/demand – Cohen, Diether, Malloy (2007) • Short-selling costs and limits to arbitrage - Incorporating borrowing costs, some factor-related short-selling strategies are still profitable – GMR (2002) - Stocks with low inst. ownership (lending supply) exhibit more extreme underperformance – APR (2005) - Abnormal returns to short side for anomalies due ‘solely’ to special stocks - Beneish, Lee, Nichols (2014) Why lend what you can sell? Can Funds Benefit From Short-Selling? • Chen, Desai, Krishnamurthy (2013) show from 1994-2009: - MFs allowed to short increases from 24% to 63% - Funds that actually short increases from 2.2% to 7.1% - Those that short outperform by 1.5% annually, but… …many funds cannot/will not short • If funds cannot/will not short, can they benefit? - Measures of short-selling demand signal future underperformance so managers should sell those stocks - Even for a long-only manager, if relative performance is the performance metric of interest, managers can be ‘short’ relative to the benchmark Supply vs. Demand • Lending income small relative to average underperformance • Supply-side concerns (especially after the financial crisis): “Fidelity Worldwide Investment may be on the verge of scrapping its securities lending programme in the latest blow to the controversial practice….The idea that we would lend the stock that we obviously like, otherwise we would not own it, to someone who is then going to short it does not really make much sense. It is not in the interests of our clients to have to foster that short selling, nor is it in the interests of the company in which we invest.” -Dominic Ross, Chief Investment Officer, Fidelity Worldwide • But evidence suggests that demand-side dominates – for example, Kaplan, Moskowitz, and Sensoy (2012): - Run experiment for an anonymous money manager in 2008-2009 - Returns to stocks made available to lend don’t differ from stocks that were not lent Research Questions • How prevalent is security lending among mutual funds? • Are investors better off purchasing funds that lend securities or prohibit lending? - Does the income generated from stock lending outweigh potential adverse value effects of holding stocks with shortselling demand? - Why lend what you can sell? • If not for fund performance, why do fund families’ initiate security lending programs? The Market for Lending/Borrowing Stock Sources of equity lending demand: • Primary – short-selling • Secondary – voting (Aggarwal, Saffi, Sturgess) • Secondary – tax avoidance (Christoffersen+GMR) Sources of equity lending supply (top 3 in 2012): • US Mutual funds (22%) • Insurance companies (12%) • US Pension funds (11%) • Unidentified/other (36%) Data • N-SAR filings on security lending practices: • Merge N-SAR data with CRSP mutual funds data • Sample: 2,070 open-end domestic equity funds - Dates: 1996 to 2008 - Exclude international, bond, sector, close-end funds - 1,924 active funds and 146 index funds Securities Lending Practices Securities Lending by Index Funds 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Lending Allowed Actually Lent Securities Lending Practices (2) Securities Lending by Active Funds 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 Lending Allowed Actually Lent Security Lending Practices (3) Security Lending and Fund Performance • Active funds that lend underperform (4-factor alpha) • Multivariate regression - Control for expenses, fund and family size, flows, turnover, distribution channel, past performance, style, time, fund FE - Cluster standard errors by fund - Underperform between 0.45% and 0.82% annually • Propensity Score Matching - Treated sample: Funds that lend securities - Control sample: Fund that don’t lend securities but are allowed to with closest propensity score at the same date (nearest-neighbor) - Active funds that lend underperform by 0.46% annually - Index funds that lend outperform by 0.20% annually What We Have Learned So Far • Willingness to lend shares by U.S. mutual funds has increased • Cross-sectional differences among funds that are allowed to engage in security lending and funds that are not allowed • Actively managed funds that lend securities underperform funds that do not lend securities • Why lend what you can sell? Propensity Score Matching Probit Active Funds Coef t-Stat Fund Utilization Expense Ratio ln(TNA) Net Flow 0.021 ** -0.084 0.103 *** 2.55 -0.93 5.35 -0.014 *** -4.93 Turnover 0.001 0.04 ln(Family TNA) 0.065 *** 3.80 Investment Objective Herfindahl -0.424 *** -3.20 Average Family Performance Rank -0.035 ** Index Funds in Family 0.220 -2.49 0.66 0.598 * 1.81 Broker Funds in Family -0.822 ** -2.40 Average Family Expense Ratio -7.810 -0.74 Average Family Active Share Style Fixed Effects Observations -1.758 *** -5.93 Yes 92,820 Sudadvised Funds in Family Why Do Families Initiate Equity Lending Programs? • Family goal: maximize assets under management - Family sets investment restrictions to diversify fund offerings across investment objectives - Require managers not to deviate from their style, regardless style is in favor by investors • Predictions: - Underperformance more pronounced in funds with more investment restrictions - Managers of funds that lend equities are less sensitive to short selling demand signal - Higher likelihood that family “recaptures” outflows to other funds in family Anecdotal Evidence Kevin Parke, Chief Investment Officer of Massachusetts Financial Services: “…some types of stocks are always out of favor and I want our managers to stay with those stocks, picking the best of the worst. When they come back into favor, MFS will be prepared for the inevitable surge in inflows. So I will continue to pay a manager well who is doing a good job in an out-of-favor fund. But they must stick to picking the best stocks in their respective category. I’m not going to reward a value manager who beat her index by including tech stocks (when tech stocks were hot) in her portfolio. That is cheating. We need to build an excellent track record and expertise in each of our asset classes over the long run.” Hall, B., Lim, J., 2004, Massachusetts Financial Services, Harvard Business School Case 902-132. Investment Restrictions • Mutual funds have various investment restrictions, outcome of optimal contracting equilibrium (Almazan, Brown, Carlson, and Chapman (2004)) • Calculate yearly fund-level index of investment restrictions using N-SAR forms (question 70N) - Leverage: borrowing of money, margin purchases, short selling - Derivatives: writing or investing in options on equities or stock index futures - Illiquid assets: investments in restricted securities - Restriction index (0-1) with mean of 0.3 • In alternative, examine if options/futures traded allowed Why Do Families Initiate Equity Lending Programs? • Index funds that use affiliated lending agent earn lower lending income due to agency problems (Adams, Mansi, Nishikawa (2011)) • In 2008 & 2009, beneficial security owners engaging in security lending suffered losses associated with the riskiness of their security collateral pool MR. DAVIS: …The exhibits to [our securities lending] agreement were marvels of simplicity. The exhibit number three, I will never forget. It purported to list the allowable investments for collateral alone. And it said cash, securities and letters of credit, period, the full content of that page. There was nothing about the rating of these various instruments, there was nothing at all about the monitoring of the instruments, there was nothing at all that described how the bank was going to care for those instruments. So I think that even though the document itself, for a small fund like ours, was 30 pages, the meat of it was the protection for the lending agent, not for the beneficial owner. Jerry Davis – Chairman, Board of Trustees - New Orleans Employees' Retirement System SEC Securities Lending And Short Sale Roundtable (9/29/2009) Performance, Restrictions, Affiliated Lending (1) (2) (3) Security Lending Used 0.059 -0.097*** -0.046*** (1.27) (-2.91) (-3.43) Restriction Index 0.116** (2.13) Security Lending Used x Restriction Index -0.187** (-2.20) Options-Futures Allowed -0.035* (-1.66) Security Lending Used x Options-Futures Allowed 0.079* (1.92) Affiliated Lending Agent 0.043 (0.37) Security Lending Used x Affiliated Lending Agent -0.015 (-0.12) Other Controls Yes Yes Yes Style*Time Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Observations 111484 111484 111484 R-squared 0.216 0.216 0.216 Number of Funds 1,701 1,701 1,701 Manager-Fund Pairs • Reaction of fund manager to short selling demand • Manager-fund pairs - same manager in two funds (177 cases): - A fund is allowed to lend, but the other is prohibited • Events: “hard-to-borrow” stocks - Stocks in top quartile of distribution of short interest and below median institutional ownership in a month • Outcome: % change in number of shares held by manager around month stock has become “hard to borrow” (using quarterly holdings) Manager-Fund Pairs Position Change (%) Position Change (%) • • Security Lending Allowed -5.4 Security Lending Allowed and Used -5.8 Security Lending Prohibited -10.9 Security Lending Prohibited -14.5 Difference 5.5*** Difference 8.7*** Manager decreases position less in fund where security lending is allowed - More so when security lending is both allowed and used Manager is less sensitive to short-selling demand in funds with security lending programs in place Fund Inflows and Outflows (1) (2) Fund Inflows Family Inflows Family Outflows Family Security Lending Allowed Family Security Lending Allowed x Family Inflows Family Security Lending Allowed x Family Outflows Fund Inflows (t-1) 0.629*** 0.392*** (10.60) (3.19) -0.009** (-2.41) 0.505*** 0.504*** (11.48) (11.43) 0.179*** 0.184*** (4.88) (5.00) Style Outflows Controls Time Fixed Effects Observations R-squared -0.011*** (-3.64) 0.355*** (3.56) 0.263* (1.80) 0.579*** 0.578*** (20.96) (20.96) Fund Outflows (t-1) Style Inflows (3) (4) Fund Outflows 0.523*** 0.212*** (9.34) (2.84) 0.169** 0.178*** (2.52) (2.63) Yes Yes 98,941 0.446 Yes Yes 98,941 0.447 Yes Yes 98,941 0.353 Yes Yes 98,941 0.354 • Positive correlation between fund inflows (outflows) and family outflows (inflows) • Relation is stronger when family has security lending program Conclusion • Active funds lend securities underperform otherwise similar funds that do not lend securities • Why? - Manager cannot act on short-selling demand due to investment restrictions set by family to diversify its fund offerings across styles - Security lending at least generates some income that minimizes effect of short selling demand Contributions • Contributes to the understanding of the consequences of security lending for mutual funds - There may be important detrimental effects on value of portfolio holdings due to security lending • Shed light on the issue of why fund families initiate security lending programs • Family-level profit maximization concerns dominate fundlevel performance concerns Robustness Security Lending Income Security Lending Collateral Controls Style Fixed Effect Observations R-squared (1) -0.630*** (-2.79) Yes Yes 67,254 0.003 (2) (3) -1.102*** (-3.54) 0.071 0.400*** (0.73) (3.36) Yes Yes Yes Yes 74,587 63,562 0.003 0.003 • Use lending income and collateral (% of TNA), rather than “Security Lending Used” dummy - N-CSR fillings for subsample of funds in 2002-2008 • Funds with higher lending income underperform - Higher collateral value indicates more bargaining power as lender and thus better lending terms