Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103 – 128 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Raising primary school enrolment in developing countries The relative importance of supply and demand Sudhanshu Handa Inter-American Development Bank, 1300 New York Avenue, Northwest, Washington, DC 20577, USA Received 1 June 1999; accepted 1 August 2001 Abstract Few policies are as universally accepted as raising primary school enrolment in developing countries, but the policy levers for achieving this goal are not straightforward. This paper merges household survey data with detailed school supply characteristics from official sources, in order to estimate the relative impact of demand and supply side determinants of rural primary school enrolment in Mozambique. Policy simulations based on a set of ‘plausible’ interventions show that in rural Mozambique, building more schools or raising adult literacy will have a larger impact on primary school enrolment rates than interventions that raise household income. When relative costs are considered, adult literacy campaigns are nearly 10 times more cost-effective than the income intervention and 1.5 to 2.5 times better than building more schools. D 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: D1; I0; I2; O1 Keywords: Primary education; School supply; Africa 1. Introduction Few policies, if any, are as universally accepted as that of raising primary school enrolment in poor countries. Virtually every World Development Report published annually by the World Bank has recognized, in one form or another, the importance of primary schooling as an input to the social and economic progress of poor countries.1 And E-mail address: sudhanshuh@iadb.org (S. Handa). 1 Within the overall policy goal of raising primary school enrolment, raising girls’ enrolment has received special attention, due to the large positive externalities of female education on children and adult health, fertility, and infant mortality. 0304-3878/02/$ - see front matter D 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S 0 3 0 4 - 3 8 7 8 ( 0 2 ) 0 0 0 5 5 - X 104 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 within the academic literature, a host of studies has documented the market and nonmarket return that comes from completing primary schooling, both in poor and rich countries alike.2 However, raising primary school enrolment in developing countries is easier said than done. The relative importance of school supply versus household demand factors remains controversial, with serious implications for education policy.3 For example, if children’s enrolment rates are not responsive to local school infrastructure, government interventions aimed at increasing access to schools will have very limited impact on overall schooling levels, thus effectively reducing the set of options available to policymakers. And even if regional variations in schooling infrastructure can be related to household schooling choices, as several studies have shown,4 efficient policy decisions require knowledge of the particular dimensions of school infrastructure that matter most. This latter issue is contentious in both developing and developed countries alike, and has been the topic of several recent articles seeking to measure the type of schooling infrastructure (access, quality, etc.) that makes a difference for household schooling choices.5 This study makes three main contributions to the literature on primary school enrolment policies and school infrastructure in developing countries. First, the impact of school characteristics on household primary school enrolment decisions are measured using a diverse set of school ‘quality’ indicators. Aside from information on distance to the nearest school, detailed information on school characteristics is hard to find in developing countries, and as a result, the available published literature is small relative to that for developed countries.6 This study thus provides an additional set of estimates with which to assess the role of specific supply side factors in determining student outcomes. Moreover, school characteristics are measured with the actual data that Mozambique’s Ministry of Education uses to formulate its regional and national targets, and to develop its 5-year plans, thus enhancing the policy relevance of the work. Second, unlike most previous studies in this area, the interaction between school and household characteristics is explored to see if complementarity or substitutability exists between these two sets of factors in determining school enrolment.7 The existence of significant interactions can provide important clues about who benefits the most from school supply interventions, and 2 For developing countries see Glewwe (1999), Handa (1999), and Lam and Duryea (1999). For developed countries, see Rosenzweig and Schultz (1982). 3 See Simmons and Alexander (1978) for a discussion of this issue and review of the literature. 4 These studies show that community or regional fixed effects are significant determinants of household schooling choices. For example, see Pradhan (1998) for Indonesia, Handa (1996) for Jamaica, and Alderman et al. (1996) for Pakistan. 5 Recent studies that measure the effect of various school characteristics in developing countries include Lavy (1996) and Glewwe et al. (1995); for developed countries, see Card and Kruger (1992), Betts (1995), and Golhaber and Brewer (1997). The overall importance of school quality is discussed by Hedges et al. (1994), Hanushek (1995), and Kremer (1995). 6 Recent studies that provide estimates of detailed school ‘quality’ indicators on student educational achievement in developing countries include Glewwe and Jacoby (1994) for Ghana, Glewwe et al. (1995) for Jamaica, and Tan et al. (1997) for the Philippines. 7 Birdsall (1985) is one of the few studies that also looks at interactions among supply and demand factors in determining schooling outcomes. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 105 where programs or resources should be placed in order to benefit the most vulnerable. For example, a significant positive interaction between household income and school access in a particular region implies that building additional schools in this region will benefit richer households more than poorer ones. However, policymakers may want to target regions where the poor are more likely to benefit from the provision of schools, hence, knowledge of specific interactions can provide useful information to help prioritize program placement. Third, policy simulations are presented based on separate and ‘plausible’ supply and demand side interventions, and used to evaluate which type of intervention will have the largest impact on primary school enrolment rates. The standard policy analysis contained in studies on school supply typically evaluates the effect on the outcome of interest (for example, test scores or grade attainment) for a given change in a statistically significant school supply variable (e.g. travel time to school) by multiplying the given change by the relevant coefficient. Although statistically valid, the policy relevance of this exercise can be enhanced significantly by recognizing that governments in the short or medium run cannot supply 10 more books to every school, or fix every leaking roof in the country. A typical policy intervention in the short run will involve adding more teachers in some regions and not others, or building a few schools in a few regions. This paper estimates the change in primary school enrolment that would come about from a set of more realistic interventions such as building a few schools in specific regions, or targeting adult education or income-generating programs only among the poorest households. These simulations arguably provide a better picture of the expected benefits of the type of interventions available to developing country governments in the short and medium term. The data used in this paper are from Mozambique, a country that has suffered from over 25 years of armed conflict, and that is acknowledged by development experts as one of the world’s poorest. Estimates from the rural region of this country show that both demand and supply factors are important determinants of primary school enrolment. On the supply side, dimensions of school quality (the number of trained teachers) and access all have significant effects on household enrolment decisions. However, the policy simulations show that school access on the supply side, and adult education on the demand side, are the biggest factors in impeding primary school enrolment. When relative costs are considered, interventions that raise adult literacy turn out to be the most efficient alternative for raising primary school enrolment in rural Mozambique. 2. Data and description of study area 2.1. The study area Mozambique is one of only a handful of African countries that was colonized by the Portuguese, and by all accounts, the period of colonization was extremely repressive for native Africans. Only a select few assimilados were allowed access to the social and economic benefits that the colonial rulers enjoyed, and independence came in 1975 only after a long war of independence and a change in government in Portugal. Almost immediately after independence, the new Mozambique entered an even more brutal civil 106 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 war, instigated by guerrillas backed by neighboring South Africa. This war of destabilization resulted in thousands of land mines being placed in rural areas in the central and northern parts of the country. Hundreds of thousands of Mozambicans fled the countryside for the urban centers or neighboring Malawi and Zimbabwe. The signing of the peace treaty in Rome in 1992 essentially marked the second independence of Mozambique, but the over 25 years of armed conflict have left a huge hole in social and economic infrastructure that require immediate attention in order for Mozambique to realize sustainable growth and reduce poverty. A recent study by the Ministry of Finance (1998) estimates that 70% of the population live below the poverty line, with poverty rates even higher in the central and northern zones that suffered most from the civil war. 2.2. The national education system The national education system’s general education program is divided into two levels— primary and secondary. Primary education consists of 7 years of schooling divided into two levels, Level 1 up to Grade 5 (escola primaria do primeiro grãu or EP1) and Level 2 from Grade 6 to 7 (escola primária do segundo grãu or EP2). Secondary education consists of 5 years also divided into two levels or cycles, first cycle secondary from Grade 8 to 10 (escola secundária geral do primeiro grãu or ESG1) and second cycle secondary from Grade 11 to 12 (escola secundária geral do segundo grãu or ESG2). Unlike most African countries, entrance into successively higher levels of schooling is not based on national examinations, but on actual grades and age. Among students with the same grades, those who are younger (and therefore either started on time or did not repeat as often) are given priority. Access to EP1 in rural areas, and other (higher) levels through out the country, is supply constrained. Fees do not exist in public lower primary schools, but there is an annual matriculation fee of approximately US$5. Private EP1 school fees can range from US$150 to US$600 per year depending on ownership structure and facilities provided. 2.3. Household data The household data used in this paper come from the first post-war national household survey of Mozambique undertaken in 1996/1997 by the National Statistical Institute—the Inquérito Nacional Aos Agregados Familiares Sobre As Condicß ões de Vida (IAF). The IAF is a multipurpose household survey that contains detailed information on consumption expenditures, as well as modules on health (both adult and child), education, employment, demographic composition, and a community questionnaire for rural areas describing local infrastructure.8 The IAF is a three-staged stratified sample. Stage 1 is the 11 provinces of the country, Stage 2 is the localidad (bairro in urban areas), and in Stage 3, households are selected 8 This data set has been used by the International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI) in collaboration with the Mozambican Ministry of Finance to construct a national poverty line and to develop a poverty profile of Mozambique (Ministry of Finance, 1998). S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 107 Table 1 Adult literacy rates by age group (%) 18 – 65 years All Male Female Poor 66 – 99 years Rural Urban Mozambique Rural Urban Mozambique 32.0 52.3 15.7 31.2 71.0 85.1 57.6 61.8 40.0 59.3 23.6 36.6 29.7 42.9 17.5 28.4 69.2 78.4 60.2 59.1 37.7 50.3 26.0 34.2 from villages (or blocks in urban areas). The primary sampling unit is therefore the localidad, and variance estimates provided in this paper account for the sample design of the survey. The full survey covers approximately 42,000 individuals residing in 8250 households. Tables 1 and 2 provide basic indicators of adult and child schooling calculated from the IAF data set. Only 40% of adults aged 18 –65 can read or write; for women, the literacy rate is even lower (24%). Note that women in rural areas have the lowest literacy rates— 16% for the 18 – 65 age group. Table 2 indicates that there are significant signs of improvement. The net enrolment rate for primary school is 49%, and is slightly lower for girls (45%) and rural children (44%). 2.4. School data Information on school infrastructure in the IAF is limited to whether or not a rural village contains a primary school. Detailed information on school characteristics has been gathered from the Direccß ão de Planificacß ão of the Mozambique Ministry of Education (MINED). Since 1992 MINED has administered a beginning and end-of-academic-year questionnaire to each school in the country, soliciting information on enrolment, teachers, teacher qualifications, pass rates, and building characteristics. This information is used by MINED to create and keep track of its internal performance indicators. Coverage is excellent, with over 90% of schools returning questionnaires; summaries of these data are published in an annual report by the MINED entitled Educational Indicators (Republic of Mozambique, various years). Raw data from these school surveys for 1995 and 1996 were acquired from MINED and were merged at the administrative post level with rural households from the IAF survey.9 The analysis presented below focuses on the enrolment decision of rural children (representing 80% of the primary school age children in Mozambique) in order to exploit the small information on rural village level schooling availability provided in the IAF; in all there are 634 villages in the IAF, distributed across 175 administrative posts, 112 districts, and the 10 provinces of the country (excluding the province of Maputo City).10 9 There are three levels of local administration in Mozambique: province, district, and administrative post. The school level data are therefore aggregated to the lowest administrative unit possible. 10 In 17 cases, MINED did not have any school information for an administrative post found in the IAF. In these cases, school information from a bordering administrative post was used. 108 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 2 Children’s current enrolment by age group (%) 7 – 11 years All Male Female Poor 12 – 17 years Rural Urban Mozambique Rural Urban Mozambique 43.9 49.1 39.0 41.7 70.7 73.5 68.0 63.3 49.2 53.9 44.7 45.5 43.3 51.5 33.2 42.3 63.5 65.6 61.4 54.9 48.0 54.5 40.3 44.8 2.5. Choice of school characteristics MINED divides its educational performance indicators into three groups, measuring coverage, quality, and efficiency of the school system, and I follow this classification where appropriate in order for the results to be of policy relevance to the Government of Mozambique.11 MINED has developed a set of indicators to measure each of the three dimensions of the educational system—where possible, I used these same indicators in the regression analysis, although there is a high degree of collinearity among the indicators, both across and within the three dimensions of coverage, quality, and efficiency. The basic quality indicators used by MINED are the number of trained teachers working in the system, average class size, and the pupil – teacher ratio. The number of trained teachers in the administrative post was used as the basic indicator of teacher quality. However, I also find that gender of the teachers matters, and so show some results that measure the proportion of female trained teachers in the administrative post. In addition to teacher training, the average pupil – teacher ratio for schools in the administrative post was included. Class size is not used because many schools in Mozambique are run on a shift system, and so smaller class sizes can be achieved by creating two shifts, but with only a small number of additional teachers (Case and Deaton, 1999 report the same phenomenon for South Africa). School coverage is measured by the number of Level 1 primary schools (EP1) in the administrative post. Given the large variations in the building structure of schools in Mozambique, and evidence from other developing countries on the importance of building characteristics (e.g. Glewwe and Jacoby, 1994), the number of school rooms made of cement in the administrative post was also included. All these school supply variables are measured at the administrative post level, so each household in the administrative post will have the same school infrastructure characteristics. Also included is the (log of) travel time to the nearest EP1 school to the village, taken from the IAF community questionnaire— this controls for the very important travel time cost component of school attendance and also allows for some village variation in school infrastructure. As in other sub-Saharan African countries, girls’ schooling rates lag behind those of boys in Mozambique and are thus of particular policy importance. I allow the impact of all school infrastructure variables to differ by gender, estimating separate models for boys and girls. 11 I do not look at the impact of schooling efficiency, defined by MINED as the pass rate, since this can also be interpreted as a school outcome indicator and not an input indicator. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 109 Table 3 Means for administrative post school characteristics Mean Coverage or access indicators No. of EP1 schools No. of cement rooms EP2 school exists Secondary school exists 21 22 0.59 0.20 Quality indicators No. of trained teachers No. of female trained teachers/total number of teachers No. of female teachers/total number of teachers No. of trained female teachers/total number of female teachers 66 0.08 0.37 0.15 Efficiency indicators Overall pass rate Female pass rate Male pass rate Portuguese pass rate Mathematics pass rate 0.64 0.57 0.68 0.66 0.68 Data taken from survey of schools conducted by the Ministry of Education. Table 3 provides means of the school supply variables used in the regression analysis. These means are calculated over the 175 administrative posts found in the rural sample of the IAF, and show that the mean number of EP1 schools is 21, with an average of one cement room per school. Only 59% of the administrative posts have a Level 2 primary school (EP2) school, and only 20% have a secondary school. 3. Econometric model, sample, and results 3.1. Econometric model and sample The impact of school characteristics on household schooling decisions is measured via reduced form demand equations for children’s schooling of the form Si ¼ FðXc ; Xh ; Xs ; uÞ ð1Þ where Xc are characteristics of the individual child (age), Xh are household characteristics that capture access to resources, differences in taste for schooling, and opportunity costs, Xs is the vector of school infrastructural characteristics discussed above, and u is a random error term with the usual assumptions.12 The household level variables included in the model are the age and sex of the head, whether the head is literate, whether any adult household member has completed Grade 7 (EP2), and whether any adult female has completed Grade 5 (EP1). Household resources are measured with per capita daily 12 See Strauss and Thomas (1995) for a review of this methodology. 110 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 expenditure on all goods and services including home production. This is treated as endogenous following the recommendation of Rivers and Vuong (1988), using the cluster median expenditure for identification.13 Also included are measures of farm assets and production such as total land holdings, access to irrigation, agricultural commercialization, and provincial dummy variables. For Mozambique (and most African countries), raising primary school enrolment rates is a priority and the focus is therefore on the analysis of school supply effects on the primary school enrolment decisions of rural households. The sample is children of primary school age (7– 11 years old), and the dependent variable is whether the child was currently enrolled in school at the time of the survey. Means for these variables are presented in Table A1 of the Appendix A. 3.2. Placement of school infrastructure The analysis of the impact of school infrastructure on school enrolment runs the risk of confounding cause and effect if households with a greater preference for schooling are able to move to areas with better schooling quality. In the United States, for example, households demonstrate preference for schooling quality through higher property prices in districts with better schools. In Mozambique and other poor countries, allocation of infrastructure such as school or health services may be influenced by local demand for services. In such cases, regression estimates that do not account for endogenous program placement will overstate the impact of school characteristics on household educational choices. On the other hand, if policymakers purposely place programs in regions where school outcomes are low, then standard regression estimates will lead to underestimates of the true program effect. Mozambique’s history of armed conflict led to destruction of physical infrastructure including schools, roads, and health centers, and formal provision of educational centers by the state was limited to the southern part of the country and to mostly urban zones. During this period, very few new schools were constructed, and some were constructed through community initiatives, which would reflect community preferences for schooling. Since the peace accord in 1991 and the general elections of 1994, there has been a rapid increase in the number of schools constructed in the rural areas, both due to Government and NGO interventions. This is corroborated by the IAF community survey, which reports that nearly half of all primary schools were built after 1992. The education budget is distributed among the provincial directorates of education, who allocate resources to its districts based on planning and need as articulated by the district education directorates. In discussions with staff at the National Planning Directorate of MINED, considerable scepticism was displayed about the ability of parents and others at the village level to influence school placement and quality. This feeling was also expressed by primary school teachers interviewed by the author in urban Maputo, who felt that 13 Household consumption decisions also affect leisure consumption, and are made jointly with schooling decisions. Due to this simultaneity problem, median per capita consumption of the village is used to instrument household consumption. This variable is highly correlated with household consumption: the simple OLS coefficient of log (consumption) on log (cluster median consumption) is 0.88. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 111 parents had very little influence on how schools were run or how resources were allocated. Presumably, this would be even more so in rural areas which are poorer and where families are more dispersed. As mentioned earlier, there has been considerable rehabilitation of social infrastructure in rural Mozambique since the General Peace Accord in 1991. In the IAF sample of 634 villages, 68% report having a primary school. Of those schools that report a date of construction (82% of cases), 42% indicate that the school was built after the signing of the peace treaty. What determined the placement of these relatively ‘new’ schools in rural areas of Mozambique? To evaluate the extent to which endogenous placement might bias the estimates of program effects, the average characteristics of villages with a ‘recent’ school (i.e. built since the war) and villages without a school were compared to see if village characteristics are sufficient to explain program placement. I constructed program exposure time as (1997 t) where t is the date the school was built in the village. The exposure time of villages who had a school built in the year of the survey (1996), for example, is thus 1, while villages without a school are given an exposure time of 0, and the resulting variable is regressed on a set of village level variables including median village consumption expenditure, the proportion of household heads that are literate, the proportion of households with an adult with EP2, and the proportion of households with a female adult who has completed EP1. Since geographic location is often an important determination of program placement, I also included the distance (km) to the district capital, and the distance to the nearest ‘good’ road. Ordered probit estimates of the village level determinants of program exposure are presented in Table 4. Column 1 shows that none of the village level SES variables or the distance variables are able to predict school placement since Mozambique’s reconstruction. Column 2 of Table 2 adds provincial dummy variables to the equation, and these results show some significant regional variation in program placement, but the village level characteristics remain insignificant in determining placement. Another way that parents can influence programs is by demanding better quality. Among recently constructed schools, are there systematic quality differences that vary by household characteristics? To answer this question, we must go up to the administrative post level, which is the lowest level at which school quality information can be merged with IAF villages. Now, only those administrative posts that contain a recently (since 1991) constructed school are selected and checked to see whether school quality, measured by the average pupil –teacher ratio and the average proportion of teachers with training, varies according to the socioeconomic status of households in the administrative post.14 The socioeconomic variables are the same as those used earlier for the village level analysis, and since the level of aggregation is higher, the average distance (of villages in the administrative post) to the provincial capital was used to capture geographic targeting. Results of this analysis are presented in Table 5, and for either measure of school quality, the F test at the bottom of the table fails to reject the null hypothesis that the set of 14 It is important to realize that I cannot do this for all administrative posts. Administrative posts that have had schools for many years (high exposure) will probably also have higher rates of adult literacy and primary school completion, leading to a positive correlation between school placement or quality, and household socioeconomic status. 112 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 4 Ordered probit estimates of years since primary school built in village (1) Coefficient Median village consumption Proportion of heads literate Proportion of households with female with EP1 Proportion Of households with adult with EP2 Distance to ‘good’ road Distance to district capital Niassa Cabo Delgado Nampula Zambezia Tete Manica Sofala Inhambane Gaza Log likelihood Observations (villages) (2) z-statistic Coefficient z-statistic 0.000 0.037 0.017 1.12 0.14 0.03 0.000 0.012 0.279 0.20 0.04 0.47 0.129 0.22 0.035 0.06 0.001 0.003 0.84 0.60 0.001 0.008 0.616 1.397 0.964 0.518 0.646 1.102 0.771 0.312 1.244 374 0.50 1.59 1.44 3.03 2.44 1.32 1.55 2.67 1.74 0.75 2.85 380 266 Sample is villages that have no school or that had one built after 1991. Dependent variable is equal to 0 if village has no school, and equal to (1997 t) if has school, where t is the year the school was built. SES variables are jointly equal to 0. There is some indication (at the 10% significance level) that median consumption in the administrative post is negatively correlated with the pupil –teacher ratio (the higher the median consumption, the worse the ratio), while there continues to be significant variation across provinces in school quality. Another way to assess the randomness of placement rules is through a difference-indifferences approach that uses cohorts to construct control groups, as in Duflo (1999). Since there was a major expansion in school infrastructure after 1993, children of primary school age before 1993 faced very different school infrastructure availability relative to their younger brothers and sisters. Children aged 14– 17 in the IAF would have been 8 –11 in 1990, just before the revitalization of school infrastructure in the country, and hence, not subject to the ‘program’. I therefore used this cohort as a control group, and constructed a difference-in-differences estimate by comparing the difference in school outcomes between cohorts across administrative posts with large and small increases in schools. I compared the 1993 round of the MINED data with the 1996 round, and defined administrative posts with ‘high exposure’ as those that had more than the median number of new schools built during this period, and those with less than the median as low exposure (the median is 5). Table 6 provides the results of this exercise for two schooling indicators: enrolment and grade attainment adjusted for age. For enrolment, the simple cross-sectional difference in enrolment rates, that is, the difference among 7 –11-year olds across low- and highexposure regions is 0.099, while the difference-in-differences is 0.09, almost identical. Moreover, the pre-program difference (the difference among the control group across S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 113 Table 5 OLS estimates of determinants of school quality at administrative post level Dependent variable Proportion of heads literate Proportion of households with adult with EP2 Proportion of households with female with EP1 Median consumption of administrative post Distance to Provincial capital Niassa Cabo Delgado Nampula Zambezia Tete Manica Sofala Inhambane Gaza Constant R2 F P value for SES variables Observations (administrative posts) Proportion of teachers with training Pupil – teacher ratio Coefficient z-statistic Coefficient 0.043 0.139 0.41 0.68 11.744 13.767 1.34 0.81 0.197 1.21 21.388 1.57 0.000 0.02 0.002 1.74 0.000 0.090 0.232 0.294 0.188 0.218 0.259 0.340 0.149 0.061 0.553 0.30 2.63 0.82 102 0.61 1.19 2.77 4.09 2.69 2.79 3.56 4.05 2.07 0.77 6.77 0.034 28.619 36.078 25.574 0.879 19.038 23.375 14.642 9.368 6.096 72.452 0.60 9.17 0.17 1.46 4.54 5.16 4.27 0.15 2.92 3.85 2.10 1.56 0.91 10.64 z-statistic Sample is rural administrative posts with at least one school built after 1991. All variables are measured at the administrative post level, except for province dummies. regions) is not statistically significant. The last part of Table 6 repeats the exercise using another outcome indicator, standardized or adjusted grade attainment, defined as the highest grade attained by the child divided by the ideal grade s/he should have attained given age.15 In this case, the cross-sectional difference (0.0740) is over twice that of the difference-in-differences (0.033), but even for this outcome, the pre-program difference is not statistically significant. In conclusion, based on the discussion with administrators in the Mozambican MINED, as well as the results on the determinants of placement and quality of new schools in rural areas, it appears that the program effects estimated below are unlikely to represent simply unobserved household or community level demands for schooling. 3.3. Basic results 3.3.1. Results on school access or coverage of the educational system Table 7a presents marginal probability estimates of the impact of school access on EP1 enrolment by gender in rural Mozambique. Columns 1 –3 show estimates using 15 For children out of school, the IAF reports their age when they finished school. 114 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 6 Change in schooling outcomes across cohorts and by intensity of schooling construction Schooling outcome Enrolment Standardized grade attainment No increase Large increase No increase Large increase Control (ages 14 – 17) (N = 2290) Treatment (ages 7 – 11) (N = 4119) First difference 0.407 (0.49) 0.416 (0.49) 0.292 (0.27) 0.333 (0.29) 0.433 (0.50) 0.532 (0.50) 0.298 (0.38) 0.372 (0.39) 0.026 0.116 0.006 0.039 Standard deviation shown in parenthesis below mean. No (large) increase indicates administrative posts with less (more) than the median number of new schools built between 1993 and 1996. Standardized grade attainment is current grade attainment as a proportion of ideal attainment given age, and ranges from 0 to 1. the number of schools in the administrative post, while columns 4 – 6 show estimates using the change in the number of schools between 1993 and 1996. The number of schools in the administrative post has a significant effect on boys but not girls enrolment ( p value for difference in effects is 0.04), while the number of cement rooms has a significant effect on girls’ but not boys’ enrolment ( p value for difference is 0.08). Proximity to a school is a highly significant determinant of enrolment, the point estimates implying that a 30-min reduction in travel time would increase enrolment probabilities by 20 and 17 percentage points for boys and girls, respectively. When the change in the number of schools is used instead of levels, the main difference is the impact of schools on girls’ enrolment, which now increases and becomes significant at 10%. Household characteristics are also important determinants of school enrolment in rural Mozambique, particularly for girls. In columns 1– 3, for example, all the adult schooling variables are statistically significant, and in all cases, the marginal impact of additional adult schooling is larger for girls than it is for boys; the existence of a female adult with completed EP1 is especially important for girls, raising enrolment probabilities by 21 percentage points. Household access to resources (measured by per capita consumption expenditures) also influences enrolment rates, and in this case as well, the impact is larger for girls than it is for boys. 3.3.2. Difference-in-differences estimates of school access The difference-in-differences analysis using older cohorts as controls can also be applied in a multivariate context in order to provide a check on the cross-sectional estimates presented above. Consider the following regression equation estimated over all children ages 7 –17: E ¼ a0 þ B1 *X1 þ B2 *ðCohortÞ þ B3 *ðProgramÞ þ B4 *ðCohort*ProgramÞ þ ui ð2Þ In this framework, X1 is a vector of control variables, B2 measures the difference in enrolment rates between older and younger cohorts in APs without any significant change S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 115 Table 7a Marginal impact of school access indicators on EP1 Enrolment Log p.c. consumption Residuala Head literate Adult with EP2 Female adult with EP1 Age of child in years Log (travel time to nearest school) Number of cement classrooms in AP Number of schools in AP Change in number of schools 1993 – 1996 Observations Log likelihood 1 2 3 4 5 6 All Boys Girls All Boys Girls 0.058 (2.27) 0.085 (2.90) 0.125 (6.02) 0.174 (4.56) 0.172 (4.15) 0.063 (11.39) 0.055 (7.77) 0.001 (2.23) 0.001 (1.53) 0.053 (1.54) 0.112 (2.79) 0.116 (3.83) 0.164 (3.33) 0.137 (2.50) 0.076 (8.69) 0.058 (7.12) 0.001 (0.91) 0.002 (2.52) 0.061 (1.97) 0.060 (1.62) 0.146 (5.51) 0.192 (3.97) 0.210 (4.29) 0.051 (6.57) 0.049 (5.88) 0.002 (2.45) 0.000 (0.27) 0.054 (2.09) 0.090 (3.01) 0.122 (5.69) 0.175 (4.52) 0.163 (3.92) 0.063 (11.28) 0.052 (7.37) 0.002 (2.95) 0.048 (1.36) 0.119 (2.86) 0.108 (3.47) 0.170 (3.42) 0.122 (2.24) 0.074 (8.40) 0.056 (6.96) 0.001 (2.10) 0.058 (1.84) 0.062 (1.60) 0.146 (5.38) 0.188 (3.84) 0.204 (4.10) 0.053 (6.67) 0.046 (5.46) 0.002 (2.54) 0.001 (2.04) 4119 2453 0.002 (1.77) 2010 1189 0.001 (1.64) 2109 1231 4290 2527 2097 1229 2193 1262 Numbers shown are marginal probabilities derived from probit estimation, with absolute z-statistics in parenthesis. School quality variables are measured at administrative post level, except for distance to nearest school. Constant term, provincial dummy variables, land holdings, possession of agricultural equipment, and indicator for commercial crop production not shown. Mean of dependent variable is 0.51 and 0.40 for boys and girls, respectively, and 0.47 for the full sample. a T-statistic is test for exogeneity of log p.c. expenditure. in school infrastructure, B3 measures the pre-program difference in enrolment rates, and B4 is the double difference estimator of the impact of new schools (the ‘program’) on enrolment. Two indicators of program exposure were used: the first measuring the actual change in the number of schools in the administrative post between 1993 and 1996, and the second a dummy variable indicating a high-intensity administrative post, defined as an administrative post where the number of new schools built is above the median.16 Estimates of Eq. (2) are presented in Table 7b for the whole sample, and separately for boys and girls. Columns 1 –3 use the actual change in schools built between 1993 and 1996 as the measure of program exposure, and the coefficient on the relevant interaction term shown in the last line of the table indicates effects that are larger than the crosssection results, although the pattern of significance is the same. For example, the crosssection estimate of the impact of an additional school for the full sample is 0.001, compared to 0.003 in column 1 of Table 7b. The estimates in columns 4 –6, which use the 16 This second indicator eliminates the influence of a few administrative posts reporting unreasonably large increases in school infrastructure. 116 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 7b Double difference estimate of impact of school access on EP1 Enrolment Measure of program intensity: Change in number of schools in AP ( 100) 1 if large change in schools in AP Log (travel time to nearest school) Log (time) * change in schools 1 if treated cohort (7 – 11) Treated cohort * change in schools Observations Log likelihood Number of new schools built Dummy for high intensity AP 1 2 3 4 5 6 All Boys Girls All Boys Girls 0.076 (0.73) 0.163 (1.01) 0.067 (0.54) 0.011 (0.31) 0.039 (5.03) 0.013 (1.82) 0.406 (8.53) 0.094 (2.43) 6409 3900 0.055 (1.22) 0.047 (5.33) 0.010 (1.10) 0.396 (5.00) 0.158 (3.38) 3247 2014 0.049 (0.94) 0.029 (2.77) 0.016 (1.50) 0.395 (4.88) 0.006 (0.10) 3162 1853 0.039 (5.07) 0.012 (1.70) 0.405 (8.66) 0.003 (3.68) 6409 3901 0.047 (5.36) 0.009 (0.95) 0.397 (5.31) 0.004 (2.41) 3247 2017 0.028 (2.73) 0.016 (1.51) 0.394 (4.87) 0.001 (1.23) 3162 1852 In columns 1 – 3, the program is measured by the number of new schools built in the AP between 1993 and 1996. In columns 4 – 6, the program is measured by a dummy variable indicating whether the number of new schools built in the AP during this period is above the median (5). Probit marginal probabilities are shown with associated absolute z-statistics in parentheses. Control variables are the same as those in (a), plus interactions between province and the measure of program intensity. dummy variable for high-intensity administrative posts, also show a similar pattern of statistical significance to the cross-sectional estimates but higher marginal effects. 3.3.3. Results on school quality Table 8 presents probit marginal probability estimates of the impact of school quality on EP1 enrolment by gender in rural Mozambique.17 Columns 1– 3 present the base estimates with quality measured by the number of trained teachers and the average administrative post level pupil –teacher ratio; the latter is insignificant but the former is positive and significant, although the quantitative effect is small.18 Adding 10 more trained teachers will raise the probability of enrolment by 1 percentage point. When the total number of trained teachers is split into the proportion of male and female trained teachers and entered as two variables (columns 4 – 6), only the proportion of female trained teachers is significant, with the impact especially large for girls. Note that there are very few female trained teacher in rural Mozambique (an average of 11 per administrative post, or roughly 11% of all teachers per region). The mean of this variable is 0.08—doubling this would increase enrolment by just over 2 and 4 percentage points for boys and girls, respectively. 17 I do not estimate a difference-in-differences model for the impact of school quality because there was no significant change in the mean values of the quality indicators between 1993 and 1996. 18 When the proportion of teachers who are trained is used, its coefficient is positive but not significant. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 117 Table 8 Marginal impact of school quality indicators on EP1 Enrolment Log (travel time to nearest school) Pupil – teacher ratio No. of trained teachers in AP Proportion of female teachers who are trained Proportion of male teachers who are trained Proportion of female teachers Observations Log likelihood All Boys Girls All Boys Girls 0.054 (7.74) 0.001 (1.08) 0.001 (3.70) 0.058 (7.02) 0.000 (0.35) 0.001 (3.81) 0.049 (5.88) 0.002 (1.30) 0.001 (2.40) 0.056 (8.10) 0.001 (1.15) 0.061 (7.40) 0.000 (0.16) 0.050 (6.15) 0.002 (1.70) 0.356 (2.85) 0.291 (1.65) 0.473 (3.43) 0.033 (0.37) 0.095 (0.78) 0.007 (0.07) 0.061 (0.24) 4290 2530 0.045 (0.13) 2097 1232 0.172 (0.63) 2193 1260 4290 2528 2097 1228 2193 1265 Numbers shown are marginal probabilities derived from probit estimation, with absolute z-statistics in parenthesis. School quality variables are measured at administrative post level, except for travel time to nearest school, which is for the village. The regressions also include all the control variables indicated in Table 7a. Mean of dependent variable is 0.51 and 0.40 for boys and girls, respectively, and 0.47 for the full sample. A recent participatory study sponsored by OXFAM (1999) in Mozambique reports that male teachers often force students to perform chores for them such as fetching wood and water, and that parents are reluctant to send girls to school to be taught by male teachers. This is especially true in the heavily moslem provinces of Zambezia and Nampula, and may explain the strong positive effect of trained female teachers reported in Table 8. 3.4. Adult literacy programs and children’s school enrolment Table 7a reported strong effects of adult education, especially basic adult female schooling, on the enrolment probabilities of children. Adult literacy, particularly female literacy, is well known to be a strong determinant of children’s health, nutrition, and schooling outcomes in developing countries, and this is true in rural Mozambique as well (Ministry of Finance, 1998). The IAF community questionnaire provides information on whether a sample village has had an adult literacy program, and if so, the year of the program. Only 2.5% of the villages report having had such a program, and two-thirds of these programs occurred since 1994. Although the incidence of villages with programs is very small in the sample (and thus unlikely to yield statistically precise results), it is interesting to get some initial idea of whether these programs can have an effect on children’s schooling through their impact on adult literacy. Table 9a shows the enrolment rates of children ages 7 –11 (treatment) and 14 –17 (control) according to whether they live in a village that ever had a literacy campaign, or had a recent campaign (since 1994). The last line of the table indicates that the literacy rate of household heads is higher in villages that had an adult literacy campaign relative to 118 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 9a Village adult literacy programs and cohort enrolment rates Control (14 – 17) Treatment (7 – 11) First difference Literacy of household heads No program Had program Had recent program 0.40 (0.49) 0.46 (0.50) 0.06 0.44 0.52 (0.50) 0.64 (0.48) 0.12 0.52 0.48 (0.51) 0.61 (0.49) 0.13 0.62 Recent program is one that occurred after 1993. Standard deviation in parenthesis beside proportion. those that did not, and enrolment of children 7– 11 is similarly higher (by about 15– 18 percentage points—see row 2) in these same villages. However, the first row of Table 9a indicates that villages with recent literacy programs had pre-program enrolment rates that were also significantly higher (by 8 percentage points: 0.40 versus 0.48) than those with no program. The difference-in-differences in school enrolment rates is 7 percentage points, which is less than half the simple cross-sectional difference, but is still large. Table 9b replicates the regression estimates in Table 7b for school access, but now includes an indicator of whether a village had an adult literacy campaign (column 1) or a recent campaign (column 2). Despite the very small variation in this variable, column 1 reports a large positive and significant relationship between the presence of a campaign and children’s school enrolment probabilities. Column 2 measures only recent campaigns, the mean of which is only about 1.6% in the sample, and the resulting coefficient estimate is not statistically significant, although the point estimate (0.11) is of the same magnitude as that for head’s literacy (0.12), which continues to be statistically significant. Table 9b Marginal impact of village adult literacy campaigns on EP1 Enrolment (1) (2) dP/dX Log p.c. consumption Residuala Head literate Adult with EP2 Female adult with EP1 Age of child in years Log (travel time to nearest school) Number of cement classrooms in AP Number of schools in AP Village had adult literacy program Village had ‘recent’ adult literacy campaign Observations Log likelihood z dP/dX z 0.056 0.084 0.123 0.178 0.174 0.065 0.053 2.22 2.91 5.99 4.66 4.15 11.72 7.77 0.058 0.080 0.124 0.178 0.171 0.065 0.055 2.23 2.72 5.86 4.64 4.08 11.80 8.05 0.001 2.21 0.001 2.10 0.001 0.200 1.59 2.59 0.001 1.61 0.114 1.17 4273 2506 4247 2491 Numbers shown are marginal probabilities derived from probit estimation, with absolute z-statistics in parenthesis. See notes to Table 7a for explanation of variables. Recent literacy campaign means after 1993. a T-statistic is test for exogeneity of log p.c. expenditure. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 119 Table 9c Double difference estimate of impact of literacy program on school enrolment Village had literacy program Treated cohort (7 – 11) Treated cohort * literacy program Observations Log likelihood (1) (2)b 0.088 (1.01) 0.409 (8.87) 0.098 (1.15) 6654 4007 0.024 (0.30) 0.409 (8.92) 0.135 (1.11) 6609 3977 Numbers are marginal probabilities derived from probit coefficients, with absolute z statistics in parenthesis. b Recent literacy programs only (those after 1993). Table 9c presents difference-in-differences estimates of the impact of literacy campaigns on school enrolment rates, based on Eq. (2) and using the two measures (ever had a program, and had a recent program). The results in column 2 are theoretically more valid because the control group did not have exposure to the program during their first few years of eligibility for primary school. In column 2, the difference-in-differences point estimate is 0.135, which is slightly higher than the cross-section estimate in Table 9b, but is not statistically significant, probably because of the very small variation of this variable in the sample. 3.5. Interactions with household characteristics The influence of community infrastructure (such as school quality) may be different in households with different characteristics. For example, the impact of a village school may be greater for richer households if richer households are better able to take advantage of the school. On the other hand, richer households may be able to afford to send children to a neighboring village for schooling, in which case the impact of constructing a school in the village may actually be greater among poorer households, who otherwise would not have sent their children to study. The impact of community infrastructure on household behavior may also depend on the education of adults or parents, due to differences in preferences or access to information. In the child health Table 10 Estimation results for school access indicators interacted with head’s literacy and household income Interactions with: Log (travel time to nearest school) No. of cement classrooms in AP No. of EP1 schools in APs Interactions with head’s literacy Interactions with household income All (1) Boys (2) Girls (3) All (4) Boys (5) Girls (6) 0.011 (1.04) 0.001 (1.36) 0.001 (1.07) 0.015 (1.10) 0.002 (1.54) 0.000 (0.18) 0.008 (0.60) 0.001 (0.45) 0.001 (0.95) 0.029 (3.01) 0.001 (1.01) 0.001 (0.99) 0.029 (2.12) 0.001 (0.93) 0.002 (1.10) 0.027 (2.69) 0.026 (2.31) 0.001 (0.45) Numbers shown are marginal probabilities derived from probit coefficients of the interaction of each variable with literacy of household head (columns 1 – 3) and household consumption (columns 4 – 6). Absolute z-statistics are in parenthesis. Travel time is measured at the village level. Number of observations, mean of dependent variable, and other control variables are the same as in Table 7a. 120 Interactions with: Log (travel time to nearest school) Pupil – teacher ratio No. of trained teachers Proportion of female teachers who are trained Proportion of male teachers who are trained Proportion of female teachers Interactions with head’s literacy Interactions with household income 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 All Boys Girls All Boys Girls All Boys Girls All Boys Girls 0.012 (1.08) 0.016 (1.13) 0.008 (0.58) 0.010 (0.89) 0.013 (0.95) 0.006 (0.44) 0.026 (2.77) 0.025 (1.91) 0.025 (2.46) 0.027 (2.78) 0.027 (2.04) 0.023 (2.26) 0.000 (0.17) 0.000 (0.63) 0.000 (0.06) 0.000 (0.51) 0.000 (0.07) 0.000 (1.10) 0.001 (1.18) 0.000 (0.42) 0.001 (0.76) 0.000 (1.78) 0.002 (1.27) 0.001 (1.90) 0.298 (1.36) 0.462 (1.55) 0.138 (0.53) 0.057 (0.36) 0.025 (0.10) 0.159 (0.82) 0.071 (0.51) 0.050 (0.26) 0.121 (0.70) 0.060 (0.41) 0.002 (0.01) 0.077 (0.48) 0.513 (2.06) 0.415 (1.02) 0.540 (1.72) 0.158 (0.70) 0.096 (0.30) 0.208 (0.75) Numbers shown are marginal probabilities derived from probit coefficients of the interaction of each variable with literacy of household head (columns 1 – 2) and household consumption (columns 3 – 4). Absolute z-statistics are in parenthesis. School quality variables are measured at administrative post level, except for travel time, which is measured at the village level. Number of observations, mean of dependent variable, and other control variables are the same as in Table 8. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Table 11 Estimation results of school quality indicators interacted with head’s literacy and household income S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 121 literature, for example, the impact of mother’s education has been found to vary significantly with community characteristics such as sewerage and sanitation conditions (Thomas et al., 1991; Barrera, 1990). Both household income (measured by expenditures per capita) and adult education significantly influence schooling choices in Mozambique, and school infrastructure also conditions these choices in rural areas. Does the impact of school infrastructure depend on household characteristics? Are certain households more likely than others to change their schooling decisions in response to variations in school infrastructure? These questions are addressed by interacting the different school supply characteristics with household adult education (measured by the literacy of the head) and household income, to see if significant interactions indeed exist between school supply and household characteristics. The interactions are tested sequentially, first by interacting the school supply variables with head’s literacy, and then by interacting the same variables with household (log) per capita consumption. Results are presented separately for two dimensions of school supply (access and quality) in Tables 10 and 11. Starting with school access, Table 10 presents the results of the interactions between each school access indicator and head’s literacy (columns 1 – 3) and household consumption (columns 4– 6). Significant interactions exist among several access indicators and household income (columns 4– 6). For both boys and girls, distance to a primary school and household income are substitutes, hence, the positive impact of constructing a school nearby will be greater among poorer households. Furthermore, the positive impact of cement classrooms on girls’ enrolment is enhanced among richer households, given by the positive and significant coefficient on the interaction term in column 6. Table 10 presents the results of the estimates of school quality indicators interacted with head’s literacy (columns 1 – 6) and household consumption (columns 7 –12). For the full sample, the impact of the proportion of female teachers depends on whether the head is literate or not. The negative coefficient on the interaction term (column 4) implies that these two characteristics are substitutes, and therefore, the impact of these dimensions of school quality is significantly greater among households where the head is not literate. The results for income in columns 7– 12 show one marginally significant coefficient. For girls, the impact of the number of trained teachers in the AP varies with household income; the positive coefficient in this case implying complementarity (column 9). 4. Policy simulations According to the Ministry of Education’s strategic plan, raising basic primary education levels is a priority for Mozambique. In this section, the relative impact of demand side versus supply side interventions on primary school enrolment rates in rural Mozambique is compared. The simulations are based on the probit regressions for the determinants of current enrolment of children aged 7– 11 years old in rural areas. The school characteristics included in the model are the number of trained teachers and the pupil – teacher ratio, and the number of schools and cement rooms in the administrative post. All the household 122 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 level characteristics mentioned above are included in the model, as well as the village level variable indicating the travel time to the nearest school. Because of Mozambique’s vast size and geographical and economic heterogeneity, the impact of the hypothetical policy interventions to vary by province by interacting the policy variables with provincial dummy variables was allowed.19 Systematic differences in the effect of policy interventions on boys’ and girls’ enrolment rates were not found and so estimates for the full sample only are provided. 4.1. Supply side simulations The supply side policy simulations consider the impact on enrolment rates of increasing the number of schools in rural areas in Mozambique. The IAF community questionnaire indicates that approximately 68% of rural villages have a basic primary school, and the regression analysis shows that the distance to a school is an extremely important determinant of children’s enrolment. The increase in EP1 enrolment that would occur due to two separate interventions was calculated: (1) increasing the overall EP1 coverage rate to 79%, which implies building a school in 70 villages per province; (2) increasing the overall EP1 coverage rate to 89%, which implies building schools in 140 villages per province. These rates are attained by increasing the number of schools in each administrative post. In order to capture the impact of school characteristics (and not just access) on enrolment, it was assumed that each school consists of three cement rooms and comes with two trained teachers. The addition of a school in an administrative post will reduce the average travel time to the nearest school. This indirect effect due to changes at the administrative post level is accounted for in the policy simulations by reducing the travel time for villages in an administrative post that receives an additional school.20 4.2. Demand side simulations The impact of policy interventions designed to influence demand side (or household) characteristics is based on the same model used for the supply side simulations. Two types of interventions are simulated, one influencing household income (or consumption) and the other influencing adult education. The income-related interventions involve raising the per capita consumption of all households to at least the level of consumption of the 25th percentile of the per capita consumption distribution (Mt. 2494 per person per day in the IAF, or approximately 25 US cents); the second policy is to raise all households to at least Mt. 3584, which is equal to median consumption in the IAF. Since these interventions only affect poor households, they will not be evenly distributed throughout the country. In particular, the poorer the province, the larger the share of 19 Detailed simulation results by province are not presented here, but are discussed in Handa (2000). The average reduction in travel time was calculated by estimating an OLS regression for the relationship between number of schools in an administrative post and village travel time. The estimated coefficient on the variable ‘number of schools in the AP’ is used to adjust the travel time variable in the simulation. 20 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 123 households in the bottom 25th percentile or bottom half of the per capita consumption distribution, and thus, the larger the number of households who will be affected by the policy. The second demand side simulation is motivated by the results presented above, indicating that adult household education significantly conditions children’s schooling. The impact on enrolment rates was simulated if all household heads in the bottom quartile of the per capita expenditure distribution were literate. As in the income case, the benefits of this intervention will not be distributed equally across provinces. While poorer provinces have more eligible households, the policy only affects heads of households who are not literate and so the proportion of heads who are literate also matters. 4.3. Results of simulations Results of the supply and demand side simulations are presented in column 1 of Table 12. These are calculated as the percentage change in overall mean enrolment with respect to the baseline figure for predicted enrolment derived from the probit estimates without any simulations. The policy of increasing EP1 coverage to 79% (row 1) will increase overall enrolment by 13%, while doubling the size of the intervention would raise enrolment by 35%. Rows 3 and 4 provide estimates of the percentage change in enrolment due to the two income-related policy interventions described above. The overall (national) impact is to raise enrolment rates by 2% and 4%, respectively—these effects are significantly smaller than the estimated enrolment effects of building more schools. The last two rows of column 1 in Table 12 present simulation results based on interventions that raise the literacy level of heads of households in the bottom parts of the per capita consumption distribution. The overall impact of this intervention is substantially larger than the income intervention. Increasing literacy of heads in the bottom quartile would increase overall enrolment by 8%; increasing literacy of heads in the bottom half of the distribution would increase enrolment rates by 15%. Note that if it is not literacy itself, but factors associated with literacy that lead to increased child schooling (such as preferences or value for education), then the simulation Table 12 Policy simulations and cost-effectiveness of supply and demand side interventions Intervention (1) (2) (3) (4) Benefit Unit cost (US$) Total cost (US$ million) Effectiveness: (3)/(1) (US$ million) 13 35 2 4 8 15 70,000 70,000 29b 55b 30 30 49 98 24 91 14.7 27.9 3.8 2.8 12.0 22.8 1.8 1.9 a Build 70 schools per province Build 140 schools per province Bring Households to 25th percentile Bring Households to 50th percentile Literacy to heads in bottom quartile Literacy to heads in bottom 2 quartiles a b Percentage increase in enrolment based on simulation results. See text for details. Average per household for 1 year. 124 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 results are likely to overestimate the benefits of adult literacy campaigns in Mozambique. I have tried to control somewhat for these family-specific tastes or talents for education by including the education level of other adult household members in the regression equations. These other variables actually reduce the estimated impact of head’s literacy by 25%.21 Moreover, one may argue that family-specific preferences for education are likely to be smaller in a supply-constrained society such as rural Mozambique, relative to more developed countries like the United States or Canada, where the spatial supply of schools is relatively abundant. 4.4. Cost effectiveness of policy options The simulations presented above provide an idea of the overall benefit of different policy interventions without considering the cost of these same interventions. I have gathered approximate costs for adult literacy campaigns and school construction from NGOs working in the education sector in rural Mozambique. The cost of building a basic three-room cement school in rural Mozambique is estimated to be US$50,000. To this construction cost, the cost (including administrative costs) of two teachers for 10 years was included, which, according to the pay structure for teachers, adds an additional US$20,000 to the cost of a rural primary school. The policy simulation in row 1 of Table 12 calls for building 70 schools in each of the 10 rural provinces, at a cost of US$70,000 per school, or a total cost of US$49 million. Dividing this figure by the percentage increase in enrolment (13%) gives approximately US$3.8 million per percentage point increase in enrolment. Kulima, a local NGO that has provided adult literacy campaigns in rural Mozambique, estimates a total cost per adult of US$30 for the delivery of a 1-year literacy program in a rural village. According to the IAF, and using population weights, there are approximately 490,000 illiterate heads of household in the bottom quartile (59% of heads in the bottom quartile cannot read or write), and approximately 930,000 illiterate heads in the bottom two quartiles (54% of heads are illiterate among this group). Providing literacy for the heads in the bottom quartile at a cost of US$30 per person leads to a total cost of US$14.7 million, which when divided by the expected percentage increase in enrolment (8) yields US$1.8 million per percentage point increase in enrolment. Finally, using the (population weighted) figures for per capita household consumption in the IAF, the total amount of transfer required to bring all households below the 25th percentile to a per capita household consumption exactly equal to consumption in the 25th percentile was calculated. This figure is US$24 million per year, and when divided by the expected percentage increase in enrolment (2% – see column 1 of Table 12), yields US$12 million per unit of expected benefit. The approximate costs associated with each intervention and the associated costeffectiveness numbers are shown in columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table 12 for each policy 21 When the variables ‘number of adults with EP2’ and ‘number of adult females with EP1’ are excluded from the regressions, the estimated impact of ‘head literate’ increases by 25% for both boys and girls. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 125 simulation. These estimates clearly show that the income intervention is the least costeffective method of raising primary school enrolment in rural Mozambique. The policies of adult literacy and improved access to schools are significantly more cost-effective methods of raising enrolment rates, with adult literacy providing a slightly cheaper alternative among these two options. 5. Conclusions Raising primary school enrolment is a major development imperative, although the interventions that can best raise enrolment are not always straightforward, and can vary both between and within countries. Using the first national household survey of Mozambique, coupled with detailed information on school infrastructure supplied by the Ministry of Education, this paper evaluates the relative importance of supply and demand side factors in determining rural primary school enrolment. Simulations based on a set of ‘plausible’ demand and supply side interventions indicate that in rural Mozambique, building more schools or raising adult literacy will have a larger impact on enrolment rates than interventions that raise household income. For example, raising the EP1 coverage rate to 79% in rural areas will increase enrolment rates by 13%, while making household heads literate in the bottom per capita consumption quartile will raise rural primary school enrolment by 8%. In contrast, bringing per capita consumption of the poorest quartile up to Mt. 2494 per day will raise rural enrolment by a mere 2%. When relative costs are considered, adult literacy campaigns become more attractive, with cost-effectiveness ratios that are 6 – 10 times better than the income intervention, and 1.5 –2.5 times better than building more schools. Even if we assume that half the measured benefit of adult literacy is through unmeasured tastes for, or ability in, acquiring human capital, adult literacy is just as cost-effective as extending coverage through school infrastructure. The detailed analysis of the impact of school characteristics on primary school enrolment in rural Mozambique indicates that dimensions of school quality and access both work to stimulate enrolment, although the effects are small and differ somewhat by gender of child. School quality, measured by the number of trained teachers in the administrative post, has a positive and significant impact on enrolment, but it is the gender composition of the trained teaching staff that is even more important in determining the household decision to send children to school. For example, the share of female teachers who are trained is an important positive determinant of enrolment rates. Raising this ratio from 0.08 to 0.16 in the administrative post will raise enrolment rates by roughly 4 percentage points. School availability also has a significant impact on enrolment rates. Reducing the travel time to the nearest school will increase enrolment rates for both sexes by 17 – 20 percentage points, and the impact of school availability is enhanced for girls if the school is built with cement. Few previous studies have considered the possible interaction between school supply indicators and household characteristics. In Mozambique, these exist particularly for girls. In terms of policy, the most interesting of these is the positive interaction between travel 126 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 time to a school and household income, which implies that the two factors are substitutes—construction of a village school will increase enrolment more among poorer households. Additionally for girls, there is a positive interaction among household income, cement classrooms, and the number of trained teachers in the area. Acknowledgements Thanks to Farizana Omar, Helder Zavale, and Virgolinho Nhate for excellent research assistance, to Manuel Rego of the Mozambique Ministry of Education for supplying and interpreting the data, and Gaurav Datt, Dean Jolliffe, and especially Ken Simler, for helpful comments on earlier drafts. Useful criticism was also provided by an anonymous referee. This paper was written while the author was outposted by IFPRI as Professor of Economics to the Eduardo Mondlane University, Maputo, Mozambique. Appendix A1. Summary statistics for children ages 7 – 11 Girls Boys Mean SD Mean SD Log daily per capita consumption Land holdings (ha) Have irrigation Have agricultural equipment Head literate Adult in household with EP2 Adult female in household with EP2 Head female Head’s age Currently enrolled in school 8.154 2.564 0.046 0.046 0.476 0.078 0.109 0.187 45.508 0.406 0.61 2.41 0.21 0.21 0.50 0.27 0.31 0.39 12.80 0.49 8.143 2.590 0.046 0.042 0.454 0.077 0.109 0.184 45.146 0.498 0.64 2.70 0.21 0.20 0.50 0.27 0.31 0.39 12.71 0.50 School characteristics Pupil – teacher ratio No. of trained teachers Proportion of trained female teachers Proportion of female teachers Pass rate Girls’ pass rate Boys’ pass rate Portuguese subject pass rate Mathematics subject pass rate Log (travel time to nearest school) Number of EP1 schools in administrative post Change in number of EP1 schools Have EP2 in AP Have secondary school in AP Number of observations 65.324 79.654 0.096 0.103 0.644 0.581 0.676 0.663 0.683 1.384 26.118 8.383 0.651 0.272 2293 18.07 66.47 0.10 0.12 0.05 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.05 2.11 21.08 11.35 0.48 0.44 65.157 80.414 0.094 0.102 0.643 0.580 0.676 0.661 0.682 1.317 25.945 8.301 0.657 0.273 2203 17.59 66.90 0.11 0.13 0.05 0.07 0.05 0.05 0.05 2.10 19.78 11.77 0.47 0.45 School characteristics are measured at the administrative post level, except for travel time to school. S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 127 References Alderman, H., Behrman, J., Ross, D., Sabot, R., 1996. Decomposing the gender gap in cognitive achievement in a poor rural economy. Journal of Human Resources 31, 229 – 254. Barrera, A., 1990. The role of maternal schooling and its interactions with public health programs in child health production. Journal of Development Economics 32, 69 – 91. Betts, J., 1995. Does school quality matter? Evidence from the national longitudinal survey of youth. Review of Economics and Statistics 77 (2), 231 – 250 May. Birdsall, N., 1985. Public inputs and child schooling in Brazil. Journal of Development Economics 18, 67 – 86. Card, D., Kruger, A., 1992. Does school quality matter? Returns to education and the characteristics of public schools in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 100 (1), 1 – 40 February. Case, A., Deaton, A., 1999. School inputs and educational outcomes in South Africa. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3), 1047 – 1084 August. Duflo, E., 1999. Schooling and Labor Market Consequences of School Construction in Indonesia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment, mimeo, MIT. Glewwe, P., 1999. Why does mother’s schooling raise child health in developing countries? Evidence from Morocco. Journal of Human Resources 34 (1), 124 – 159 Winter. Glewwe, P., Jacoby, H., 1994. Student achievement and schooling choice in low income countries. Journal of Human Resources 29 (3), 843 – 864. Glewwe, P., Grosh, M., Jacoby, H., Lockheed, M., 1995. An eclectic approach to estimating the determinants of achievement in Jamaican primary education. World Bank Economic Review 9 (2), 231 – 258. Golhaber, D., Brewer, D., 1997. Why don’t schools and teachers seem to matter? Assessing the impact of unobservables on educational productivity. Journal of Human Resources 32 (3), 505 – 523 Summer. Handa, S., 1996. The determinants of teenage schooling in Jamaica: rich vs. poor, females vs. males. Journal of Development Studies 32, 554 – 580. Handa, S., 1999. Maternal education and child height. Economic Development and Cultural Change 47, 421 – 439. Handa, S., 2000. Raising Primary Schooling in a Developing Country, International Food Policy Research Institute Discussion Paper, Washington, DC hwww.ifpri.cgiar.org/divs/fcnd/dp/dp76.htmi. Hanushek, E., 1995. Interpreting recent research on schooling in developing countries. World Bank Research Observer 10 (2), 227 – 246. Hedges, L., Laine, R., Greenwald, R., 1994. Does money matter? A meta-analysis of studies of the effect of differential school inputs on student outcomes. Educational Researcher 23 (3), 5 – 14. Kremer, M., 1995. Research on schooling: what we know and what we don’t. World Bank Research Observer 10 (2), 247 – 254. Lam, D., Duryea, S., 1999. Effects of schooling on fertility, labor supply, and investments in children, with evidence from Brazil. Journal of Human Resources 34 (1), 160 – 192 Winter. Lavy, V., 1996. School supply constraints and children’s educational outcomes in rural Ghana. Journal of Development Economics 51, 291 – 314. Ministry of Finance, 1998. Understanding Poverty and Well Being in Mozambique: The First National Assessment, Maputo, Government of Mozambique. OXFAM, 1999. Access to Basic Education and Health in Mozambique, Oxfam-GB, Maputo, Mozambique. Pradhan, M., 1998. Enrolment and delayed enrolment of secondary school age children in Indonesia. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 60 (4), 413 – 431. Republic of Mozambique, Educational Indicators, Ministry of Education, Planning Directorate, Maputo, Mozambique, various years. Rivers, D., Vuong, Q., 1988. Limited information estimators and exogeneity tests for simultaneous probit models. Journal of Econometrics 39 (3), 347 – 366 November. Rosenzweig, M., Schultz, P., 1983. Estimating a household production function: heterogeneity, the demand for health inputs, and their effects on birth weight. Journal of Political Economy 91 (5), 723 – 746 October. Simmons, J., Alexander, L., 1978. The determinants of school achievement in developing countries: a review of the research. Economic Development and Cultural Change 26 (2), 341 – 357 Jan. Strauss, J., Thomas, D., 1995. Human resources: empirical modeling of household and family decisions. In: 128 S. Handa / Journal of Development Economics 69 (2002) 103–128 Behrman, J., Srinivasan, T.N. (Eds.), Handbook of Development Economics, vol. 3A. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 1883 – 2005. Tan, J.-P., Lane, J., Coustere, P., 1997. Putting inputs to work in elementary schools: what can be done in the Philippines? Economic Development and Cultural Change 45, 857 – 879. Thomas, D., Strauss, J., Henriques, M.-H., 1991. How does mother’s education affect child height? Journal of Human Resources 26, 183 – 211.