Long Run Effects of Colonial Education Policy? Latika Chaudhary Scripps College 1030 Columbia Avenue Claremont, CA 91711 latika.chaudhary@scrippscollege.edu Manuj Garg Stanford University 579 Serra Mall Stanford, CA 94305 manuj@stanford.edu PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE. PLEASE DO NOT CITE. Version: June 2010 Abstract Although marked differences in literacy across different states of India are well documented, the historical persistence of these regional patterns is less well known. This paper examines one potential explanation for this persistence, namely colonial public investments on primary education. Although OLS estimates suggest a strong and persistence effect of colonial spending on educational outcomes across 147 districts of former British India, IV estimates find colonial spending to be a significant determinant of outcomes only until the 1970s. The effects of historical spending are relatively short lived in the Indian context because of an effective government campaign beginning in the 1970s to reduce inequalities in the provision of public services. 1. Introduction Social scientists have long noted the tremendous heterogeneity in educational performance across different states and regions of India.1 As of 2001, Kerala had achieved almost universal literacy as compared to 47 percent in Bihar. Literacy among Scheduled Castes, the traditionally marginalized lower castes, is above average in states such as Gujarat and Maharashtra as compared to Orissa and Uttar Pradesh. Such differences, however, are not just a recent phenomenon—as early as 1911, literacy in Bombay presidency, which roughly corresponds to present-day Gujarat and Maharashtra, was almost twice as high as Bihar and Orissa (6.9 as compared to 3.9 percent). Cochin and Travancore, which represent the contemporary state of Kerala, were leaders in educational attainment with literacy rates of 15 percent as compared to the national average of 5.9 percent.2 Similar patterns are also discernable at the district-level—Ahmedabad district in western India was among the top five literate districts of British India in 1911 and continued to enjoy this position until 1991. Such patterns are quite remarkable given the numerous changes that occurred over the 20th century in the Indian sub-continent for example, Indian independence in 1947, the partition and creation of Pakistan and the relatively large public investments devoted to education in the decades following independence. The role of history is thus critical to understanding why certain states or districts of India have been partially unsuccessful in overcoming poor schooling endowments. Are colonial public investments correlated with contemporary outcomes? If yes, for how long does history continue to influence present day outcomes? Using district-level data for the districts of former British India, this paper examines whether colonial public investments on primary education continue to influence educational 1 Roy and Datta (1993), Drèze and Sen (1998), Probe Team (1999), Drèze and Kingdon (2001), ASER (2005), Kingdon (2007), Pal and Ghosh (2007) among many others have commented on these patterns. 2 Ramachandran (1996) emphasizes the unique historical role of the state in contributing to Kerala’s success story. 1 outcomes between 1961 and 1991. This exercise complements and extends Chaudhary (2010), where we find that colonial public investments had large and significant effects on male literacy in the early 20th century. We focus on a particular measure of public investments, namely rural district board expenditures, which account for the majority of public spending on primary education at the district level. For the empirical exercise, we merged district level information on public spending by colonial district boards in 1911 to literacy and enrollment outcomes reported in the recent censuses. In the cross-sectional OLS analysis, we also controlled for a variety of factors that may bias the coefficients on 1911 public spending such as 1911 income, development and social structure. The OLS coefficients indicate a large and positive effect of colonial investments on rural literacy and primary school graduates. A 10 percent increase in 1911 public spending per rural population is associated with a 3.2 percentage point increase in total rural literacy in 1961, which increases to 4.7 percentage points in 1991. Moreover, we find no significant effects of historical spending on control outcomes such as secondary school and higher graduates. Despite the extensive set of controls, the OLS estimates may still be biased. To address such concerns, we instrument for 1911 public spending using 1911 land revenues. According to historical accounts, subjective forces unrelated to education created quasi-random variation in revenue assessments conditional on observable differences in geography and development across districts (Chaudhary 2010). Moreover, land revenues are statistically unrelated to available measures of agricultural productivity between 1957 and 1987, corroborating the historical accounts and providing some reassurance about the validity of the IV approach. Unlike the OLS estimates, the IV estimates on colonial public spending are positive and significant only for the 1961 and 1971 cross-sections, and in a few marginal cases for the 1981 2 cross-section. Colonial spending is statistically unrelated to 1991 literacy and enrollment outcomes. A remarkable persistence in public investments between the pre- and postindependence period coupled with changing priorities in the 1970s can account for our findings. In the decades immediately following independence, spending allocations were often based on historical patterns perpetuating differences in spending inherited from the colonial era.3 But, beginning in the 1970s, the universal provision of public goods became an important policy objective of the central government following which there were massive increases in the level of public goods in previously underserved areas (Banerjee and Somanathan 2007). Broadly, this paper relates to a large and growing literature on the relationship between history and economic development. Beginning with the seminal work of Engerman and Sokoloff (1997) and Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson (2001), researchers have used colonization as a quasi-natural experiment investigating its impact on institutional development and hence economic growth. While some of the earlier work focused on cross-country comparisons, recent papers focus on within country analyses such as Banerjee and Iyer (2005), Dell (2008) and Huillery (2009) and we share the same within country focus. Our paper is closest in spirit to Huillery (2009) that examines the effects of early colonial investments on contemporary outcomes in education, health and infrastructure in colonial West Africa finding large and persistent effects of colonial investments on current outcomes. Thus, colonial investments and institutions have had long run effects spanning many decades and centuries in some cases. But, in the case of India the persistent effect of the long hand of history was cut short by policy performs in the 1970s. 2. Regional Literacy Patterns This section reviews literacy rates in pre- and post-independence India to illustrate the 3 See Tilak (1989) for details on education financing in the post-1947 era. 3 striking persistence in regional patterns of human capital development. The preindependence series are for the Indian sub-continent including Pakistan and Bangladesh with regional data for the provinces of British India and the princely states that were under indirect colonial control. The latter territories deferred to the British with regard to defense and foreign policy, but were free to manage their internal administration including the provision of education (see Map of British India and Princely States). In comparison, the East India Company and the British Crown introduced a new state system of education in British India in the 19th century and directly controlled education policy from 1858 to 1919. After 1919 education was a transferred subject because of the MontagueChelmsford reforms, which devolved greater powers to elected Indian ministers at the provincelevel. Education became a provincial subject when provincial autonomy was introduced in 1935 and the status quo was maintained through independence with the classification of education as a state subject until 1976 when it was moved to the concurrent list giving the central and state governments joint authority over the provision of schooling. Given the high costs of developing a mass education system, the colonial government relied heavily on private sources of revenues through the grant-in-aid system, which provided partial public subsidies to schools under private management that came to be known as aided schools. In fact, the current set up of the Indian school system is a legacy of the colonial period with privately managed aided and unaided schools functioning side-by-side with publicly funded and managed government schools. Although the school system was kept intact, India progressively targeted larger public resources toward education after Independence. Table 1 shows the composition of education spending over the course of the 20th century for British India and post-independence India. Unfortunately, the pre- and post-independence 4 series do not correspond to the same geographic area since the British India series exclude the former princely states that are included in the post-1951 data, but include present day Pakistan and Bangladesh that are not covered in the post-1951 data. Despite these anomalies, the broad patterns suggest that public expenditures as a share of total educational expenditures increased from 50 percent in 1901 to 85 percent in 1981 with large increases coming from central and state governments. On account of such transfers, nominal per-capita education expenditures that were among the lowest in the world at the turn of the century increased dramatically over this period. Average literacy in the colonial period mirrored the low level of public investments with less than 10 percent of the population recorded as literate in the early 20th century. Literacy was incorrectly enumerated in the earlier colonial censuses but beginning in 1911 a uniform definition of literacy was adopted—an individual was recorded as literate if she could read and write a short letter to a friend in any language and census officials generally believed the enumeration was conducted accurately in subsequent censuses. A similar definition of literacy was adopted for the post-independence censuses and “a person who can both read and write with understanding in any language is taken to be literate” although “a person who can merely read but cannot write is not literate.” In both periods, there were no formal schooling requirements in order to be recorded as literate. Table 2 documents literacy in the colonial period for the provinces of British India and the larger princely states. Average literacy remained fairly stagnant increasing from 6 percent in 1911 to 10 percent in 1931, but there is tremendous heterogeneity by region, gender and caste. For example, 30 percent of the population in Cochin and Travancore states was literate in 1931 as compared to less than 6 percent in Bihar and Orissa. Literacy in Bengal, Bombay and Madras was twice as high as in the Central Provinces and United Provinces. Female literacy was 5 extremely low averaging 3 percent in 1931 and the regional patterns strongly resemble those for overall literacy. In addition to regional and gender variations, there are striking differences across castes. Brahmans, the traditional elite caste of Hindus, were among the most educated group in this period with male literacy rates as high as 80 percent in Madras. In comparison, the extent of education was very low among socially marginalized groups such as the lower castes and aboriginal tribes. Although India made important strides in increasing access to schooling in the postindependence period, regional patterns of inequality continue to persist as seen in table 3. In 1991 overall literacy was just over 50 percent with substantial variation across Indian states that represent the former provinces of British India as well as the princely states incorporated into independent India. Given the numerous changes in boundaries, the states of 1991 do not correspond to the provinces of 1931. Although table 3 lists the historic regions that roughly correspond to the contemporary Indian states, these broad patterns should be viewed as merely illustrative particularly for Punjab and Bengal since Pakistan and Bangladesh were roughly carved from these provinces. With these caveats in mind, table 3 strongly suggests that regions with higher literacy in 1991 had higher literacy in the colonial period as well. The southern state of Kerala, which represents the former states of Cochin and Travancore, is close to achieving universal literacy, while less than 40 percent of the population of Bihar is literate. Schedules castes (former lower castes) of Gujarat and Maharashtra are more literate than the average population of West Bengal and Assam. Literacy in Madhya Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh continues to lag behind the Indian average just as it did 60 years ago. This persistence is quite remarkable given the increase in literacy over this period and the numerous development programs embraced by the Indian 6 government after independence. Since colonial public investments on primary schooling had a significant effect on increasing literacy in the colonial period (Chaudhary 2010), we examine whether colonial investments can explain any of the observed variation in literacy across districts of modern India. 3. Colonial Public Investments on Education Although the Crown via the Government of India directly controlled education policy from 1858 to 1919, the public financing and management of schools was decentralized to provincial governments beginning in the 1870’s. Primary education and other local services such as infrastructure were further decentralized to rural district and urban municipal boards in the 1880s. Due to data constraints, we focus on 1911 public education spending by these rural district boards as our measure of colonial public investments. Data on rural district board spending is available for majority of the districts of British India, while district level data on public spending by provincial governments and urban boards are unreported for many districts. Rural district boards were set up in the early 1880s following the 1882 Resolution of Local Self-Government, which called for the establishment of rural district boards, sub-district boards (where possible), and urban municipalities with up to a two-third majority of non-official members (Indians) that were either elected or nominated by British district officers. The resolution emphasized the importance of elected non-official members and board chairmen where possible, but provincial governments were given substantial leeway in interpreting the resolution and developing district councils to suit local conditions. In practice, British officials were board chairmen assisted by landed Indian elites and other members of the upper castes (Tinker 1968). These rural boards were entrusted with the provision of primary schooling, local 7 infrastructure (civil works), and medical services with 80 percent of expenditures allocated between schooling and infrastructure. With regard to primary schooling, the boards served two key functions. They directly managed a few schools of high quality and provided public subsidies to schools that were privately managed (aided schools). Provincial education departments exercised some control over management, while the boards frequently voted on the necessary funds and decided on the location and general nature of the schools. All the money was distributed in rural areas where almost 90 percent of the population lived. The land cess, an additional levy upon the existing land tax revenue, was the key source of revenue for the colonial boards. Similar to the land revenue, the rate of taxation varied across provinces averaging 6 percent, but was generally uniform across districts within the same province. Provincial governments administered the cess and the boards had no financial autonomy to raise revenues by increasing the rates of taxation. Provincial grants to districts accounted for another 25 percent of board income, while tolls on roads and ferries contributed 10 percent. School fees, income from cattle pounds, and private contributions made up the rest of the revenue sources. To gauge the relative importance of these public investments, table 4 reports district board expenditures as a percentage of total educational spending, primary school spending and public primary school spending in 1912-13 for British India and the larger provinces. On average, district councils accounted for 15 percent of total spending, 49 percent of primary education spending and 65 percent of public spending on primary education. The local boards, thus, represent an important source of rural primary education spending although they do underestimate total public spending on primary education. 8 Average spending by district boards was 3.5 pounds per 1,000 people representing less than 0.5 percent of per-capita GDP in 1912-13. Public spending did increase over time, but always remained under 1 percent of per-capita GDP until Indian independence. Besides the low level, table 1 also highlights the significant heterogeneity within British India with Bombay outspending Bihar and Orissa by a factor of ten. Spending also varied across districts within the same province: for example, spending per-capita ranged from rupees 0.015 to 0.049 in Bihar and Orissa. Differences in land revenues and the Land Settlement system were primarily responsible for differences in spending (Chaudhary 2010). The bottom panel of table 4 documents the relationship between spending and revenues. In the 19th century, the cess represented 60 percent of district board revenues, but provincial governments increased the amount of grants available to the boards in the early 1900s. By 192930 grants contributed to 43 percent of the revenues as compared to 36 percent from the cess. Grants are included under ‘other sources’ in the bottom panel of table 1 and land revenues determined to a large extent the variation in grants across provinces. In Bengal and Bihar, land revenue was fixed in cash for perpetuity because of the Permanent Settlement of 1793. Consequently, these areas were unable to recoup higher revenues as agricultural productivity and prices increased over the next century and lost more public money when land revenues were decentralized to provinces in the late 19th century. Because of their low revenues, they transferred smaller grants to their districts. Land revenues were revised every thirty years in Temporary Settlement areas such as Bombay and Madras. The revenues in this case incorporated changes in agricultural conditions albeit at large intervals. Temporary Settlement areas had larger public funds and hence more money to spend on grants. Provinces allocated grants to districts on a per-capita basis and sometimes favored either 9 poorer (‘needy’) districts or those with larger minority populations. Although land revenues did not influence grants within provinces, they contributed to differences in cess both across and within provinces because the cess was just an additional tax on land revenues. Land revenues and by extension the cess were related to the agricultural potential of a district. But, the whims and idiosyncrasies of individual land settlement officials lead to substantial quasi-random variation in revenues across districts and even within neighboring tracts of the same district. Controlling for observable differences in soil, rainfall and the level of development, Chaudhary (2010) uses land revenues to instrument for public education spending by the rural boards and finds these investments had large and positive effects on the development of male literacy in the colonial period. This paper extends the analysis to assess whether colonial investments influenced educational outcomes such as literacy and enrollment in postindependence India. 4. Data For the empirical analysis, we constructed a new historical dataset of 147 districts of former British India in the current Indian states of Assam, Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Gujarat, Haryana, Himachal Pradesh, Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal (see attached Map of Indian States). The dataset merges information from a variety of different sources including the colonial censuses, historical district gazetteers, post-independence censuses, and the India Agricultural and Climate dataset constructed by the World Bank. Although state and province boundaries have changed substantially over the 20th century, district boundaries have remained relatively stable over this period. For bigger districts that were carved into smaller areas, we aggregated the data to correspond with the boundary of the older 10 district. In a few instances where there was a substantial transfer of territory between two or three neighboring districts, we aggregated the data for the relevant districts to construct a ‘super district’ that does not correspond to a specific administrative unit. Nonetheless, this ensures that we are comparing the same geographic area over time. The primary goal of the empirical exercise is to assess whether historical expenditures continue to influence contemporary outcomes in India. Since district board spending could be correlated with factors such as income and development that may influence both historical and contemporary literacy, we used the 1911 colonial census to construct a historical measure of development (i.e. population density). Moreover, we also constructed measures of the caste and religious breakdown of the district such as the population share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims and lower castes. Since caste and religious heterogeneity is negatively correlated with the supply of private schooling in this period (Chaudhary 2009), the analysis also includes a herfindahl-based measure of caste and religious fragmentation in each district. We used the colonial district gazetteers to construct a measure of income in the form of income tax revenues collected in the district in 1911.4 Income taxes in this period were generally collected from workers participating in the formal economy. The taxes were levied on a small share of the population and capture the higher tail of the formal income distribution. We also used the gazetteers to construct per-capita measures of public education spending by rural district boards. As mentioned earlier, the gazetteers do not report total public education spending for all the districts and hence we focus on rural board spending. Finally, we extracted data on land revenues collected in each district in 1911. These 4 The colonial district gazetteers provide a unique source of data for the colonial period. They report a wealth of information on district economic, demographic and social characteristics. Each district series has two parts, A and B: part A describes the history, geography, culture, administration, and economic situation of the district, while part B provides statistical tables to complement the discussion in part A. 11 revenues were an important determinant of historical public spending and offer a potential instrument for district board spending. For districts in the United Provinces, the gazetteers do not report the exact land revenues collected, but instead give the revenue demand or what districts were expected to collect in specific years between 1905 and 1911. The reported year also varies by district. Since the revenue demand was fixed for 20 to 30 years, the inconsistency in the reporting year should not create any significant problems. There could in principle be differences between revenue demand and revenue collected, but the regressions include geographic and economic controls to address problems arising from such reporting differences. Given the importance of geography to the computation of land revenues and education spending, we used the India Agricultural and Climate Dataset prepared by the World Bank (IACDS) to construct dummy variables for black, red and alluvial soil. We extracted districtlevel data on normal rainfall from the 1911 census and created a dummy for coastal districts based on a visual inspection of historical maps from this period. Contemporary data on literacy and enrollment are reported in the Indian District Database compiled from the 1961 to 1991 censuses. Using these data, we constructed measures of total literacy, rural literacy, rural literacy in the population aged 10 to 19, rural primary school or higher graduates and rural secondary school or higher graduates. I focus on rural outcomes because historical district board spending was only allocated to rural areas of a district. 5. Results 4.1 OLS Results We begin the empirical analysis by estimating the OLS relationship between spending in 1911 and contemporary educational outcomes such as literacy and enrollment in the postindependence period focusing on the census from 1961 to 1991. Omitted factors correlated with 12 both 1911 public spending and subsequent outcomes pose an important problem in this context because1911 public spending was not randomly allocated across districts. If it is correlated with historical levels of development, which in turn influence current levels of development and hence current outcomes, then the coefficient on 1911 public spending will be biased and will pick up the effect of omitted development. To address such concerns, we introduce several control variables that may be correlated with 1911 spending and contemporary outcomes. These variables fall into three categories: geographic, social and development and other historical investments. Geographic controls include dummies for red, black and alluvial soil, the normal rainfall in the district in 1911 and the numbers of years between 1911 and the first year a railway line was constructed through the district. The social and development controls include the 1911 population share of the various caste and religious groups mentioned in the data section and a district-level measure of caste and religious fragmentation, 1911 population density and 1911 income tax revenues per capita. Public spending on primary education is also related to public spending on local infrastructure and medical services incurred by the district boards. Because land revenues were so important to board revenues, districts with higher levels of land revenues may have outspent other districts in all categories of district board spending namely primary education, local infrastructure and medical services. Since the provision of the latter services could independently influence historical outcomes and in turn contemporary outcomes, we also include 1911 public spending on infrastructure and medical services as controls. The public spending variables are standardized per 1911 rural population because district boards focused on rural areas distinct 13 from the urban boards. Finally, all the regressions include state fixed effects to ensure we are identifying variation within states as opposed to across states.5 Table 5a presents the first set of results on 1961 outcomes. Each number in the table is a coefficient from an OLS regression of the log of 1911 public education spending per 1911 rural population plus different controls. Each row focuses on a different dependent variable. Column 1 includes no controls, column 2 adds state fixed effects, column 3 adds geographic controls, column 4 further adds social and development controls, and lastly column 5 adds the other historical investments. Row 1 begins with the total literacy rate in the district and as seen in the table, the coefficient on public spending is positive and statistically significant—a 10 percent increase in 1911 public spending translates into a 4.3 percentage point increase in the 1961 literacy rate. The result is robust to the inclusion of additional controls although the coefficient in only significant at the 10 percent level after adding all the controls in specification 5. In principle, we expect the effects of district board spending to be perhaps more accurately measured for rural educational outcomes given the rural nature of the boards. Hence, row 2 focuses on the rural literacy rate. After including all the controls in specification 5, the effects of district board spending are more precisely estimated for rural literacy and suggest that a 10 percent increase in historic spending translated into a 3.2 percentage point increase in the 1961 rural literacy rate. Row 3 refines the measure of rural literacy to the population aged 10 to 19 in 1961, which are currently in school or recent graduates. The results are even more striking – the magnitude of the coefficient is twice as large and statistically significant at the 1 percent level (specification 5). Row 4 focuses on male rural literacy and the results are essentially unchanged although the coefficient is less precisely estimated once we include all the controls. 5 The results are robust to using province fixed effects, which use the pre-1947 administrative divisions. 14 Rows 6 and 7 focus on enrollment outcomes as opposed to literacy. If the primary channel linking historical investments to contemporary outcomes is via contemporary investments, then we may expect stronger effects on primary school graduates than on literacy. The census does not directly report enrollment, but rather the number of rural primary school graduates and the number of secondary school graduates. In principle, 1911 district board spending should be unrelated to secondary school graduates because these expenditures were targeted to primary education. Hence, secondary school graduates offer a quasi-control outcome. The coefficient on colonial public spending is positive and statistically significant for rural primary school graduates, and the magnitude is comparable to that for rural literacy. While the coefficient on board spending is positive and significant for secondary school graduates in specifications without the social and development controls, the coefficient becomes negative and statistically insignificant once we add those controls. This suggests that historical income, development and social structure are necessary variables to consider in these regressions. It is reassuring that after controlling for them, historical spending is unrelated to secondary school outcomes, as we would expect. Table 5b, 5c and 5d replicate the regressions for outcomes in 1971, 1981 and 1991. The coefficient on board spending is positive and statistically significant for total, rural, 10-19 age specific and male rural literacy in each of the cross sections. The results on primary school graduates are imprecisely estimated for the 1971 cross-section, but are positive and significant for the 1981 and 1991 cross-sections. After adding the necessary controls, historical spending is not significantly correlated with secondary school graduates in any of the cross sections. Broadly, the findings suggest that colonial public spending has had far reaching effects and continues to influence educational outcomes well into the 1990s. 15 4.2 Instrumental Variables Results Despite the controls and state fixed effects, there may be concern that the OLS estimates are picking up unobservable heterogeneity across districts, which is correlated with both historical spending and contemporary outcomes. However, 1911 land revenues offer an instrumental variable for 1911 board spending. Chaudhary (2010) offers a more detailed argument in favor of using land revenues as an instrument for board spending in the colonial period. Land revenues were strongly correlated with board expenditures and were perhaps unlikely to be systematically related to the error term after controlling for observable differences in geography and development across districts. Anecdotal evidence indicates that revenue calculations were plagued with idiosyncrasies creating quasi-random variation in both land revenues and cesses. Land revenues determined cesses and so we expect them to strongly influence board spending. Appendix table 1 examines the determinants of 1911 per-capita board expenditures on education, and land revenues are a key explanatory variable. Although the coefficient is higher in specifications without province fixed effects, almost two-thirds of the land revenue effect is driven by differences within provinces. A 10 percent increase in per-capita revenues leads to a 3 percent increase in average educational expenditures (specification 7) with an F-statistic of 12 on land revenues. The dummy for Temporary Settlement districts is significant in the across province comparisons (specifications 3 and 4), but neither this variable nor the type of land tenure system (proportion of non-landlord tenures) from Banerjee and Iyer (2005) has any statistically significant effect on expenditures controlling for province fixed effects (specification 5). This is because Land Settlements and land tenure systems did not vary within provinces. Land revenues are thus strongly correlated with spending, but a valid instrument also has 16 to be unrelated to unobservable returns to contemporary literacy. In principle, the revenues were supposed to capture a percentage of the rental assets or agricultural surplus of a district. Soil and rainfall were two objective factors that influenced the assessment computation. For example, districts with alluvial soil enjoyed a larger agricultural surplus and probably paid higher land taxes. Nonetheless, discussions on assessment procedures (Baden-Powell 1972, Chand 1931) indicate revenues varied idiosyncratically even after accounting for differences in geography and development. Contemporary measures of agricultural productivity for the post-independence period offer a plausible test to assess the randomness of land revenues to contemporary educational outcomes. The India Agriculture and Climate Data Set (IACDS) reports measures of agricultural for the years 1957 to 1987. Using these data, appendix table 2 explores the correlation between productivity in the post-independence period and colonial land revenues, controlling for differences in geography, rainfall and socio-economic factors (i.e., the same set of controls as in appendix table 2).6 Columns one to four focus on agricultural productivity of the major crops, namely bajra, jowar, maize, rice and wheat, while columns five to eight focus on all crops reported in the IACDS.7 To control for changes in agricultural practices introduced by the Green Revolution, I break the data in 1965 because according to the IACDS high yielding varieties of seeds were first introduced in 1966 and slowly spread over the 1970s and 80s. Consequently, I report the findings separately for the first year of the data (1957), average productivity for the years 1957 to 1965, average for 1966 to 1987 and average for 1957 to 1987. Colonial revenues are statistically 6 Since the IACDS only reports data for contemporary Indian districts, the regressions exclude districts of former British India that are a part of contemporary Pakistan and Bangladesh. 7 This includes the major crops and the following: barley, cotton, groundnut, gram, jute, other pulses, potato, ragi, tur, rapeseed and mustard, sesame, soybean, sugar, sunflower and tobacco. 17 unrelated to agricultural productivity in all the specifications, providing some quantitative evidence of their randomness. Moreover, the findings on other controls such as rainfall and historical development are as expected, with higher rainfall and development both contributing to greater productivity. Table 6 presents the instrumental variable results for each of the cross sections. I only present the fully loaded regressions including all the necessary controls and state fixed effects. The IV results on board spending are very different from the OLS results in table 3. Board spending is not significantly related to total literacy in any year, but is positive and statistically significant for rural literacy. This finding is perhaps not too surprising given the rural nature of the historic boards. In principle, the effects on total literacy would be imprecisely estimated because the spending only influences the rural portion of total literacy. Row 3 focuses on age specific rural literacy and board spending has a precisely estimated positive effect on 1961 and 1971 literacy. The coefficient on 1981 literacy is marginally significant, while the effect on 1991 literacy cannot be statistically distinguished from zero. The effects on male rural literacy in row 4 are positive but imprecisely estimated for 1961 and 1971 cross-sections. They are not significant for the 1981 and 1991 cross-sections. Surprising, the IV estimates are insignificant for 1961 primary school graduates although they are positive and significant for the 1971 and 1981 cross-sections. Finally, historic public investments do not have any effect on secondary school graduates in either of the cross sections. Broadly, the IV results suggest colonial public investments influenced outcomes up to 1971 and marginally up to 1981 (for primary school graduates), but not 1991. Moreover, the effects appear to be most significant for age groups 10 to 19 and primary school graduates. This suggests the underlying mechanism from colonial spending to contemporary outcomes is through 18 the contemporary provision of primary education. But, the link has weakened over time and by 1991 there is no effect of history as such on educational outcomes. In the next section, we discuss potential explanations to account for these findings. 6. Why do colonial investments matter? If higher colonial public investments translate into higher contemporary public investments for education at the district level, then persistence in public spending can account for the findings. Larger public investments in the colonial period perhaps facilitated the expansion of the public primary school system after independence when larger resources became available. Despite the introduction of a new fiscal system in 1950, there does appear to be some persistence in public spending patterns before and after Indian independence. The formulas used to guide public allocation rules were often based on historical expenditure patterns generating remarkable persistence in spending over time. Table 7a presents public expenditures at the province-level from 1901 to 1961 highlighting the persistence in public spending patterns. Provinces and states such as Bombay and Madras had a historical legacy of high spending in the colonial period due to the Temporary Settlement and other idiosyncratic reasons. And, these areas continued to receive above average public funds in the decades immediately after independence. In comparison, Bihar and Orissa had below average spending in the colonial period and consistently lagged behind the national average after independence. Thus, there appears to be a positive relationship between historical and current levels of spending with Maharashtra and Gujarat emerging as high spending areas in the colonial period, and Bihar and Orissa as generally low spending areas. Table 7b documents total expenditures and the provincial patterns are very similar suggesting private expenditures failed to substitute for the low levels of public spending. 19 Moreover, private spending became a smaller share of total spending over the 20th century. In the early 20th century, public and private spending accounted for 50 percent of total spending but by 1981 public spending accounted for 85 percent of total education spending (table 1). Although these statistics are at the province-level, it is quite feasible district-level spending patterns mirror the provincial patterns. At the very least, these patterns indicate the Indian Government did not, at least initially, follow a strong redistributive policy to equalize spending differentials across different parts of the country. This is supported by qualitative evidence in the national five-year plans, which promoted public investments in capital-intensive industries as opposed to providing basic public goods such as primary schools to a larger share of the population. The big increase in public spending on education did not occur till the 1970s. The Government may also have been constrained in the 1950s and 1960s by political constituencies that supported the earlier historical distribution of public funds and benefited from the distortions. Rajan (2009) outlines a theoretical model where historical inequalities in endowments, public investments or opportunities can create political constituencies unwilling to support pro-poor i.e. pro-educational policies. In the context of British India, larger rural public spending in the colonial period perhaps reduced the inequality in access to schooling, which in turn may have created political constituencies willing to support the expansion of primary education in post-independence India. In comparison, lower colonial investments in areas such as Bihar and Orissa perhaps worsened the inequality in access to educational opportunities and these areas in turn were unable to develop constituencies in favor of reform without strong backing from the central government. While these explanations are adequate up to the 1970s, the IV estimates emphasize that something changed between the 1970s and 1990s. Historical investments are not significant 20 determinants of educational performance in 1981 or 1991. Banerjee and Somanathan (2007) offer an explanation in the changing nature of public goods provision between 1971 and 1991. Their main findings highlight a high degree of convergence in the provision of several basic public goods between 1971 and 1991. Areas with lower levels of public goods including schools in 1971 experienced faster growth relative to other areas between 1971 and 1991. Following Indira Gandhi’s ‘garabi hatao’ campaign in the 1970s, the central government made the expanded provision of basic public services a key policy and allocated larger funds to states to achieve these goals. Such policies helped weaken the relationship between colonial investments and contemporary educational outcomes in the 1980s and 1990s. 7. Conclusion This paper explores the relationship between colonial public investments in the early 20th century and contemporary educational outcomes such as literacy using a unique dataset of 147 Indian districts from 1911 to 1991. The main findings suggest colonial public investments had a large and positive influence on rural literacy up to the 1970s. A 10 percent increase in colonial public investments is associated with a 6-percentage point increase in the 1971 rural literacy rate. The most credible mechanism underlying these results is a strong persistence in public spending patterns over time. Unlike other contexts, the effects of colonial education policies in India however are relatively short lived. Colonial spending is influential for at most three decades after independence because the government enacted specific policy reforms in the 1970s to increase the provision of basic public goods. The results suggest these reforms were successful is severing the historical roots of contemporary educational outcomes. 21 References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson, “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation”, American Economic Review 91, no. 5 (2001), 13691401. Baden-Powell, B.H. Land Revenue and Tenure in British India. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1907. Banerjee, Abhijit and Lakshmi Iyer. “History, Institutions and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India,” American Economic Review 95, no. 4 (2005), 1190-1213. Banerjee, Abhijit and Rohini Somanathan. “The Political Economy of Public Goods: Some Evidence from India.” Journal of Development Economics 82, no. 2 (2007): 287-314. Chand, Gyan. Financial System of India. London: Kegan Paul, Trench, Trubner & Co. Ltd., 1926. ___________. Local Finance in India. Allahabad: Kitabistan, 1947. Chaudhary, Latika. “Determinants of Primary Schooling in British India”, Journal of Economic History 69, no. 1(2009): 269-302. Chaudhary, Latika. “Taxation and Educational Development: Evidence from British India”, Explorations in Economic History 47, no. 3(2010), 279-293. Davis, Lance E. and Robert A. Huttenback. Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Political Economy of British Imperialism, 1860-1912. Cambridge University Press, New York, 1986. Drèze, Jean and Amartya Sen. India: Economic Development and Social Opportunity. Clarendon, Oxford, 1998. Drèze, Jean and Geeta Kingdon. “School Participation in Rural India”, Review of Development Economics 5, no. 1 (2001), 1-33. Duflo, Esther and Rema Hanna. “Improving Teacher Attendance”, Poverty Action Laboratory, Unpublished Working Paper (2005). Engerman, Stanley and Kenneth Sokoloff. “Colonialism, Inequality, and Long Run Paths of Development”, NBER Working Paper 11057 (2005). Galor E., O. Moav, and D. Vollrath. “Land Inequality and the Emergence of Human Capital Promoting Institutions”, Brown University working paper (2006). Government of India. Indian Education Commission, Report and Appendices. Calcutta, 1883-84. ___________. Progress of Education in India: Quinquennial Review. Volumes 1886-1937. 22 Govinda Rao, M. and Nirvikar Singh. The Political Economy of Federalism in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2005. Huillery, Elise. “History Matters: The Long Term Impact of Colonial Public Investments in French West Africa”, American Economic Journal – Applied Economics 1, no. 2(2009):176-215. Kremer, Michael, Nazmul Chaudhury, F. Halsey Rogers, Karthik Muralidharan and Jeffrey Hammer. “Teacher Absence in India: A Snapshot”, Journal of the European Economic Association 3, no. 2–3 (2005), 658-667. Kingdon, Geeta G. “The Progress of School Education in India”, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 23, no. 2 (2007), 168-195. Kumar, Dharma, ed. The Cambridge Economic History of India vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982. Mukhopadhyay, Gopal. Mass Education in Bengal (1882-1914). Calcutta: National Publishers, 1984. Nurullah, Syed and J.P. Naik. A History of Education in India (During the British Period). London: Macmillan, 1951. Pal, Sarmistha and Sugata Ghosh. “Elite Dominance and Under-Investment in Mass Education: Disparity in the Social Development of the Indian States, 1960-92”, IZA Discussion Paper Series No. 2852 (2007). Pratham. “ASER 2005—Annual Status of Education Report”, New Delhi, Pratham, 2006. Probe Team. Public Report on Basic Education in India, New Delhi, Oxford University Press, 1999. Rajan, Raghuram, “Rent Preservation and the Persistence of Underdevelopment”, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 1, no. 1(2009): 178-218. Ramachandran, V.K., “Kerala’s Development Achievements”, in Drèze and Sen (edited) Indian Development: Selected Regional Perspectives. Clarendon Press, Oxford, 1996. Roy, Choudhury and Uma Datta, “Inter-state and Intra-state Variations in Economic Development and Standards of Living”, Journal of the Indian School of Political Economy 5, no. 1 (1993). Roy, Tirthankar. The Economic History of India 1857-1947. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2000. 23 Tilak, Jandhyala B. G. “Center-State Relations in Financing Education in India”, Comparative Education Review 33, no. 4. (1989), 450-480. Vithal, B.P.R. and M.L. Sastry. Fiscal Federalism in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 2001. Map of British India and Princely States 24 Map of Indian Union, 2001 25 TABLE 1: COMPOSITION OF EDUCATION SPENDING PUBLIC PRIVATE Govt. District & Municipal Funds TOTAL Fees Other TOTAL Total PerCapita Expenditures British India 1901-02 1911-12 1921-22 1931-32 1941-42 29% 31% 49% 46% 44% 19% 19% 13% 16% 14% 48% 51% 63% 62% 58% 32% 33% 21% 23% 28% 21% 16% 17% 15% 14% 52% 49% 37% 38% 42% 0.17 0.21 0.74 1.02 1.04 Independent India 1951-52 1961-62 1971-72 1981-82 57% 69% 76% 80% 11% 7% 6% 5% 68% 75% 81% 85% 22% 17% 13% 12% 11% 8% 6% 3% 32% 25% 19% 15% 3.5 9.0 23.0 52.6 Source: Data from 1901 to 1941 are from Progress of Education in India, Quinquennial Reviews (1927-32 and 1937-47). The 1951-1981 data are from the Statistical Abstracts of the Indian Union, except for the composition of spending in 1971 and 1981 that are from Tilak (1989), table 1. The pre-1947 data for British India include parts of present day Pakistan and Bangladesh and exclude the princely states, while the post-1947 are for the entire Indian Union excluding Pakistan and Bangladesh. The per-capita figures are nominal. TABLE 2: LITERACY RATES 1931 Overall 1931 1911 1931 HINDU BRAHMAN LOWER CASTES TRIBAL (S.T) Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female Male Female INDIA 9.9 5.9 16.3 2.9 14.4 2.1 56.4 15.1 2.4 0.2 1.3 0.2 Provinces (British India) Bengal Bombay Madras Assam Central Provinces Punjab UP Bihar and Orissa 11.1 10.8 10.8 9.3 6.6 6.3 5.5 5.3 7.7 6.9 7.5 4.7 3.3 3.7 3.4 3.9 18.2 17.6 18.8 15.6 12.0 10.0 9.4 9.8 3.3 3.1 3.0 2.2 1.2 1.7 1.1 0.8 26.3 17.8 18.2 18.6 11.8 16.6 9.1 10.2 5.0 2.6 2.6 2.5 0.1 2.6 0.1 0.7 64.5 78.8 80.0 . 58.1 26.8 29.3 35.6 21.6 23.1 28.6 . 12.2 3.4 2.5 2.8 6.3 4.9 3.2 . 4.5 1.6 0.9 2.1 0.9 0.3 0.3 . 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.1 1.4 1.0 0.6 3.1 1.2 . . 1.3 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.4 0.1 . . 0.1 Princely States and Agencies Cochin State 33.7 Travancore State 28.9 Baroda State 20.9 Mysore State 10.6 Central India Agency 5.2 Hyderabad State 5.0 Kashmir State 4.0 Rajputana Agency 4.3 15.1 15.0 10.1 6.3 2.6 2.8 2.1 3.2 46.0 40.8 33.1 17.4 9.2 8.5 7.0 7.6 22.0 16.8 7.9 3.3 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 42.8 39.9 31.5 16.1 8.3 7.0 18.7 6.2 16.9 14.2 7.2 2.4 0.1 0.1 1.9 0.0 . . 78.0 78.3 26.5 70.1 . 23.7 . . 28.4 34.4 2.7 7.9 . 1.4 . . . . 0.6 1.0 . . . . . . 0.0 0.1 . . . 3.8 3.7 2.2 0.02 1.0 1.6 . . 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 . Source: Census of India 1931, Volume 1, Part 1 - Report, Chapter IX, Subsidiary Tables I, II, III, and V. Individual data are not presented for the smaller provinces and princely states. Detailed data on the different groups is for 1931. Madras includes Cochin and Travancore States for Brahman and lower caste series. All India Brahman and lower caste literacy is just the average across provinces and princely states included in this table. Literacy rates for lower castes are averages for castes that were enumerated as lower castes in the social precedence tables of 1901. The 1931 census reports literacy rates for only a sample of castes enumerated as lower castes and so these numbers are not strictly comparable across provinces. TABLE 3: LITERACY RATES 1991 TOTAL SCHEDULED CASTES Male Female SCHEDULED TRIBES Male Female Overall Male Female INDIA 52.21 64.13 39.29 49.91 23.76 40.65 18.19 Bombay, Baroda State Gujarat Maharashtra 61.29 64.87 73.13 76.56 48.64 52.32 75.47 70.45 45.54 41.59 48.25 49.09 24.20 24.03 Madras, Cochin, Mysore and Travancore States Andhra Pradesh 44.09 55.13 Karnataka 56.04 67.26 Kerala 89.81 93.62 Tamil Nadu 62.66 73.75 32.72 44.34 86.13 51.33 41.88 49.69 85.22 58.36 20.92 25.95 74.31 34.89 25.25 47.95 63.38 35.25 8.68 23.57 51.07 20.23 Punjab Haryana Himachal Pradesh Punjab 55.85 63.86 58.51 69.10 75.36 65.66 40.47 52.13 50.41 52.06 64.98 49.82 24.15 41.02 31.03 0.00 62.74 0.00 0.00 31.18 0.00 Assam, Bengal, Bihar and Orissa Assam 52.89 West Bengal 57.70 Bihar 38.48 Orissa 49.09 61.87 67.81 52.49 63.09 43.03 46.56 22.89 34.68 63.88 54.55 30.64 52.42 42.99 28.87 7.07 20.74 58.93 40.07 38.40 34.44 38.98 14.98 14.75 10.21 Central Provinces & Berar, Central India Agency Madhya Pradesh 44.20 58.42 28.85 50.51 18.11 32.16 10.73 United Provinces Uttar Pradesh 25.31 40.80 10.69 49.95 19.86 41.60 55.73 Source: Census of India, 1991. Individual data are not presented for Rajasthan, the smaller eastern states and union territories. TABLE 4: DISTRICT BOARD EDUCATIONAL EXPENDITURES AND INCOME DB Educational Expenditures in 1912-13 Per 1000 of the population (£) As % of Total Educ. As % of Total As % of Total Public Exp. Primary Educ. Exp Primary Educ. Exp. British India 3.59 15% 49% 65% Assam Bengal Bihar and Orissa Bombay Central Provinces and Berar. Madras Punjab United Provinces 5.60 2.43 1.65 10.27 4.58 3.03 5.12 3.55 30% 8% 13% 20% 25% 12% 18% 21% 84% 40% 34% 42% 61% 34% 85% 93% 87% 80% 61% 59% 66% 38% 93% 100% DB Revenues in 1912-13 Per 1000 of the population(£) Cesses (Additional Other Sources (for taxes on land e.g. Provincial revenues) grants) Total Income % of Cesses and Other Sources to Total Income British India 6.53 5.96 16.65 75% Assam Bengal Bihar and Orissa Bombay Central Provinces and Berar Madras Punjab United Provinces 7.40 4.28 4.56 10.84 4.99 10.80 10.05 5.20 7.02 4.35 3.08 10.23 9.34 10.13 6.75 4.26 23.11 10.51 9.66 25.78 16.07 31.85 22.92 11.53 62% 82% 79% 82% 89% 66% 73% 82% Source: Statistical Abstracts of India and Progress of Education in India, Eighth Quinquennial Review (1917-1922). The statistical abstracts separate educational expenditures into direct expenditures on different levels of education and indirect expenditures on buildings, etc. I constructed total primary education expenditure as the sum of direct expenditures on primary schools and a proportion of indirect expenditures on buildings with the proportion equal to the direct primary school expenditures relative to total direct expenditures on education. Information on public primary education expenditures is from 1916-17 and was obtained from the Quinquennial Review, Volume II, Supplemental Tables, page 125. In the bottom panel, provincial contributions or grants to district boards are included under "other sources" along with school fees and miscellaneous income sources. The omitted category of income is tolls. TABLE 5a: OLS Effects of Colonial Public Investments on 1961 Educational Outcomes (1) (2) (3) (4) DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0429*** [0.0079] 0.0743*** [0.0137] Total Literacy Rate 0.0729*** [0.0128] (5) 0.0319** [0.0130] 0.0276* [0.0166] 0.0371*** [0.0104] 0.0320** [0.0137] Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0293*** [0.0070] 0.0565*** [0.0101] 0.0568*** [0.0098] Rural Literacy Rate for the Population Aged 10 to 19 DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0700*** [0.0113] 0.0996*** [0.0178] 0.1010*** [0.0170] 0.0715*** [0.0184] 0.0739*** [0.0230] 0.0354** [0.0162] 0.0315 [0.0196] Male Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0304*** [0.0093] 0.0656*** [0.0146] 0.0646*** [0.0145] Primary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0331*** [0.0069] 0.0318*** [0.0059] 0.0314*** [0.0057] 0.0235*** [0.0063] 0.0224*** [0.0071] Secondary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 State FE Geographic Controls Social & Devel. Controls Other Historical Investment Controls 0.0078*** [0.0024] 0.0156*** [0.0058] 0.0144*** [0.0054] -0.0008 [0.0053] -0.0013 [0.0056] No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. Other Historical Investments include district board spending on medical and infrastructure services. All controls are for 1911. TABLE 5b: OLS Effects of Colonial Public Investments on 1971 Educational Outcomes (1) (2) (3) (4) DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0591*** [0.0093] 0.0794*** [0.0146] Total Literacy Rate 0.0784*** [0.0141] (5) 0.0323** [0.0144] 0.0293 [0.0179] 0.0381*** [0.0116] 0.0357** [0.0147] Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0470*** [0.0079] 0.0629*** [0.0112] 0.0638*** [0.0113] Rural Literacy Rate for the Population Aged 10 to 19 DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0914*** [0.0137] 0.0962*** [0.0202] 0.0972*** [0.0203] 0.0614*** [0.0207] 0.0656*** [0.0244] 0.0362** [0.0166] 0.0361* [0.0199] Male Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0501*** [0.0096] 0.0681*** [0.0145] 0.0684*** [0.0151] Primary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0269*** [0.0074] 0.0446*** [0.0117] 0.0450*** [0.0124] 0.0297* [0.0153] 0.0291 [0.0198] Secondary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 State FE Geographic Controls Social & Devel. Controls Other Historical Investment Controls 0.0179*** [0.0062] 0.0298** [0.0115] 0.0278*** [0.0105] -0.003 [0.0114] -0.0057 [0.0120] No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. Other Historical Investments include district board spending on medical and infrastructure services. All controls are for 1911. TABLE 5c: OLS Effects of Colonial Public Investments on 1981 Educational Outcomes (1) (2) (3) (4) DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0661*** [0.0102] 0.0945*** [0.0170] Total Literacy Rate 0.0928*** [0.0163] (5) 0.0417** [0.0163] 0.0385** [0.0188] 0.0497*** [0.0140] 0.0483*** [0.0161] Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0574*** [0.0092] 0.0816*** [0.0143] 0.0820*** [0.0139] Rural Literacy Rate for the Population Aged 10 to 19 DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0981*** [0.0137] 0.1119*** [0.0226] 0.1120*** [0.0219] 0.0684*** [0.0235] 0.0758*** [0.0253] 0.0478*** [0.0179] 0.0493** [0.0197] Male Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0588*** [0.0102] 0.0847*** [0.0167] 0.0857*** [0.0172] Primary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0340*** [0.0067] 0.0585*** [0.0100] 0.0589*** [0.0097] 0.0364*** [0.0091] 0.0346*** [0.0107] Secondary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 State FE Geographic Controls Social & Devel. Controls Other Historical Investment Controls 0.0377*** [0.0111] 0.0579*** [0.0187] 0.0544*** [0.0175] 0.0021 [0.0190] -0.0026 [0.0201] No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. Other Historical Investments include district board spending on medical and infrastructure services. All controls are for 1911. TABLE 5d: OLS Effects of Colonial Public Investments on 1991 Educational Outcomes (1) (2) (3) (4) DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0735*** [0.0110] 0.0894*** [0.0187] Total Literacy Rate 0.0860*** [0.0181] (5) 0.0358* [0.0185] 0.0347* [0.0209] 0.0445** [0.0175] 0.0470** [0.0192] Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0664*** [0.0105] 0.0800*** [0.0175] 0.0784*** [0.0168] Rural Literacy Rate for the Population Aged 10 to 19 DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.1103*** [0.0138] 0.1099*** [0.0250] 0.1015*** [0.0254] 0.0560** [0.0275] 0.0705** [0.0295] 0.0398* [0.0208] 0.0476** [0.0224] Male Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0627*** [0.0112] 0.0988*** [0.0220] 0.0807*** [0.0198] Primary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 0.0537*** [0.0087] 0.0664*** [0.0141] 0.0652*** [0.0138] 0.0335** [0.0134] 0.0350** [0.0143] Secondary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. per- rural pop 1911 State FE Geographic Controls Social & Devel. Controls Other Historical Investment Controls 0.0602*** [0.0167] 0.0783*** [0.0286] 0.0699** [0.0280] -0.0145 [0.0325] -0.0223 [0.0354] No No No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. Other Historical Investments include district board spending on medical and infrastructure services. All controls are for 1911. TABLE 6: IV Effects of Colonial Public Investments on post-1961 Educational Outcomes 1961 1971 1981 1991 DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 Total Literacy Rate 0.0351 0.034 [0.0389] [0.0472] 0.0417 [0.0336] 0.0249 [0.0534] Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 0.0610** [0.0278] 0.0607* [0.0321] 0.0641* [0.0385] 0.0478 [0.0471] Rural Literacy Rate for the Population Aged 10 to 19 DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 0.1336*** [0.0483] 0.1230** [0.0589] 0.0942 [0.0592] 0.044 [0.0685] Male Rural Literacy Rate DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 0.0625 [0.0394] 0.0663 [0.0427] 0.0645 [0.0477] 0.0368 [0.0561] Primary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 0.0158 [0.0169] 0.0854** [0.0332] 0.0548** [0.0261] 0.0308 [0.0372] Secondary School Graduates per rural population DB Educational Exp. perrural pop 1911 State FE Geographic Controls Social & Devel. Controls Other Historical Investment Controls -0.0109 [0.0126] -0.0283 [0.0285] -0.0272 [0.0474] -0.0314 [0.0780] Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. Other Historical Investments include district board spending on medical and infrastructure services. All controls are for 1911. TABLE 7A: EXPENDITURES FROM PUBLIC REVENUES PER CAPITA 1901-02 1911-12 1921-22 1931-32 1941-42 1951-52 1961-62 Bombay Punjab Madras Assam Central Provinces United Provinces Bengal Bihar and Orissa 0.19 0.09 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.06 0.05 0.25 0.12 0.10 0.06 0.12 0.09 0.07 1.12 0.59 0.46 0.34 0.48 0.44 0.33 0.22 1.23 0.87 0.74 0.41 0.49 0.56 0.35 0.28 . . . . . . . . 3.56 2.42 2.77 2.03 2.07 1.67 2.79 1.18 8.91 7.65 8.63 6.78 6.73 4.03 7.25 3.74 INDIA 0.08 0.11 0.47 0.63 . 2.36 6.79 TABLE 7B: TOTAL EDUCATIONAL EXPENDITURES PER CAPITA 1901-02 1911-12 1921-22 1931-32 1941-42 1951-52 1961-62 Bombay Madras Punjab Bengal Assam Central Provinces United Provinces Bihar and Orissa 0.31 0.21 0.16 0.16 0.13 0.11 0.10 0.40 0.23 0.21 0.21 0.15 0.15 0.14 1.53 0.80 0.92 0.71 0.46 0.58 0.66 0.34 1.83 1.21 1.31 0.84 0.58 0.67 0.80 0.46 2.21 1.25 1.25 0.91 0.72 0.72 0.84 0.51 5.62 3.94 4.36 5.03 2.98 2.65 2.87 1.70 12.29 10.70 10.60 10.92 8.76 7.69 6.09 4.98 INDIA 0.17 0.21 0.74 1.02 1.04 3.49 9.02 * Data from 1901 to 1941 are from Progress of Education in India, Quinquennial Reviews (various volumes). Assam includes Eastern Bengal and Assam in 1911-12. The 1951-1961 data are from the Statistical Abstracts of the Indian Union. The pre-1947 data for British India include parts of present day Pakistan and Bangladesh and exclude the princely states, while the post-1947 are for the entire Indian Union excluding Pakistan and Bangladesh. Madras in 1961 is the average for Madras, Andhra Pradesh and Kerala, while Bombay in 1961 is the average for Gujarat and Maharashtra. Bengal post-1947 refers to West Bengal. All figures are nominal. APPENDIX TABLE 1: DETERMINANTS OF 1911 DISTRICT BOARD EDUCATIONAL EXPENDITURES (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Land Tax Revenues per-capita 0.0289*** [0.0046] 0.0161*** [0.0055] Temporary Settlement 0.0267*** [0.0050] 0.0287*** [0.0074] 0.0214*** [0.0071] 0.0169*** [0.0043] 0.0138*** [0.0042] -0.0034 [0.0071] 0.0146* [0.0076] 0.002 [0.0087] Proportion of Non-Landlord (Banerjee and Iyer 2005) Province Fixed Effects Geographic Controls Social and Economic Controls Constant Observations Adjusted R-squared F-test: Land Tax Revenues = 0 Prob > F (7) 0.0173*** [0.0055] 0.0178*** [0.0051] No No No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes 0.0218*** [0.0060] 0.0519*** [0.0119] 0.0114*** [0.0043] 0.003 [0.0069] 0.0455*** [0.0159] 0.0294 [0.0199] 0.0667* [0.0392] 197 0.51 38.97 0.0000 197 0.72 8.66 0.0037 197 0.53 27.92 0.0000 153 0.58 15.14 0.0002 153 0.79 9.13 0.003 197 0.72 9.82 0.0020 197 0.80 12.33 0.0006 Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil, and normal rainfall. Social and economic controls include population share supported by industry, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by professionals, population density, number of years since first railway line, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation. APPENDIX TABLE 2: RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY AND COLONIAL LAND REVENUES 1957 Ag. Productivity for Major Crops 1957-65 Avg. 1966-87 Avg. 1957-87 Avg. 1957 Ag. Productivity for All Crops 1957-65 Avg. 1966-87 Avg. 1957-87 Avg. (in 1911) Land Tax Revenues per-capita 0.0339 [0.0228] 0.0177 [0.0154] 0.0282 [0.0278] 0.0249 [0.0235] 0.0081 [0.0204] 0.0171 [0.0158] 0.0246 [0.0285] 0.0223 [0.0240] Population Density 0.2272** [0.0979] 0.2242*** [0.0721] 0.4116** [0.1634] 0.3563*** [0.1355] 0.3490*** [0.1101] 0.2340*** [0.0779] 0.4250** [0.1649] 0.3654*** [0.1373] Number of years since railways 0.0030** [0.0014] 0.0022*** [0.0007] 0.0035** [0.0014] 0.0031*** [0.0012] 0.0032** [0.0013] 0.0022*** [0.0008] 0.0034** [0.0014] 0.0031** [0.0012] Rainfall 0.0067*** [0.0019] 0.0050*** [0.0013] 0.0059*** [0.0021] 0.0056*** [0.0019] 0.0077*** [0.0020] 0.0051*** [0.0013] 0.0059*** [0.0022] 0.0056*** [0.0019] Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 0.1462 [0.2836] 0.1323 [0.1498] 0.1409 [0.2536] 0.1359 [0.2141] 0.111 [0.2251] 0.1279 [0.1493] 0.1821 [0.2633] 0.1704 [0.2209] 150 0.575 150 0.598 150 0.621 150 0.613 150 0.613 150 0.596 150 0.619 150 0.613 Province Fixed Effects Geographic Controls Social and Economic Controls Constant Observations Adjusted R-squared Notes: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. Geographic controls include dummies for coastal districts, black, red and alluvial soil. Social and economic controls include population share supported by industry, population share supported by commerce, population share supported by professionals, income tax revenues per-capita, share of Brahmans, Christians, Buddhists, Muslims, Tribes, low castes and a measure of caste and religious fragmentation.