The Effect of Mergers, Divestitures, and Board Composition on CEO Compensation before and after the Financial Crisis Ralph Sonenshine, Nathan Larson, and Michael Cauvel ABSTRACT This paper revisits the determinants of CEO compensation using recent data (covering 125 firms from 2003 to 2012) spanning the 2008 financial crisis. Overall, consistent with earlier studies, we find firm size and board composition to be the most consistent indicators of CEO pay. However, pay becomes more performance-oriented in the years after the financial crisis, which may reflect tighter governance. We give particular attention to the role played by changes in the CEO’s scope due to mergers and divestitures – the latter has seldom been considered before. We also investigate how these factors differ by industry. JEL Codes: G34, G3, M12, M41 Key words: mergers and divestitures, CEO compensation, board composition, stock market performance I. Introduction Over the past twenty-five years CEO compensation of the top 350 firms in the U.S. has grown 875%, or more than twice the 354% growth in wages of the average worker.1 This rapid increase appears even more dramatic when option and stock awards to CEOs are considered, and it outstrips the growth in pay of other highly paid workers. This trend has sparked renewed interest in understanding the factors that determine CEO compensation and whether changes in these factors impact the recent surge in pay. Much of the debate centers on whether CEO pay is earned (for good performance and productivity) or captured (by extracting rents from a weak board). The first view predicts that pay should be linked to observable measures of firm performance, such as stock price and earnings, in order to provide CEOs with incentives; the latter suggests that pay depends on the availability of rents and the bargaining power of the CEO vis-à-vis the board and shareholders. At the same time, it is a well-established, empirical fact that size matters: all else equal, CEOs of larger firms are paid more. Both schools of thought on pay can reconcile this fact, but with different explanations. If one believes in pay for performance, then one argues that larger firms attract more talented chiefs. Pay for performance amplifies a CEO’s productivity by scaling up the resources under his control, or demand stronger incentives to keep leadership on the straight and narrow. Under the rent-seeking view, larger firms are harder for the board to monitor and offer more opportunities for the CEO to skim. Therefore, as Core et. al. (1999) note CEO compensation may be expected to be a function of firm size, complexity, growth opportunities, and board structure, as well as firm performance and stock market volatility. One highly visible way for a CEO to influence his firm’s size (and so perhaps his pay) is with 1 See http://www.epi.org/publication/ceo-pay-2012-extraordinarily-high/. 1 mergers and divestitures. Ideally, any link between an acquisition or divestiture and CEO pay should be related to whether the deal improves shareholder value. However, because mergers grow a firm and divestitures shrink it, the strong link between size and pay may play a role as well. Furthermore, the fact that mergers and divestitures are large, concrete changes for which the CEO can credibly and publicly take responsibility may prompt CEOs to pursue potentially questionable acquisitions rather than more incremental changes in a firm’s size. This paper studies how mergers and divestitures affect executive compensation over a tenyear period. The sample straddles the financial crisis of 2008, so we can test whether compensation changes before and after the crisis, and if so, whether changes in the impact of mergers and divestitures are partially responsible. Furthermore, by gathering data on board composition, we can examine how changes in CEO pay are mediated by stronger corporate governance, both generally and in relationship to mergers and divestitures. Our results confirm the strong link between firm size and executive compensation. Similarly to other studies, we find an elasticity from size to pay of roughly 0.25; however, the elasticity appears to be lower after the financial crisis than it was in 2008 and the five years prior. After controlling for firm size, we find that merger announcements have a positive effect on certain measures of CEO compensation, yet merger size actually has a small, negative effect. Our findings on divestitures, in contrast, are inconclusive. The layout of the paper is as follows. Section II reviews the relevant literature. Section III discusses our data and empirical strategy. Section IV presents our regression results, and Section V provides some concluding remarks. II. Literature Review 2 There are two prevailing schools of thought on what determines CEO pay. The principalagent view (as articulated by Core et. al. 2003, among many others) suggests that boards design CEO compensation contracts so as to provide incentives for CEOs to work hard and maximize shareholder value. Alternatively, the managerial power view (Bebchuk and Fried 2003) asserts that CEOs exert influence over their boards that effectively allows them to participate in setting their own pay. The two approaches suggest different explanations for large pay packages; under the principal-agent approach, high average levels of pay may be necessary to compensate the CEO for the risk he bears by having his compensation tied to firm performance (via stock and options), whereas under the managerial power approach high pay might indicate weak corporate governance – specifically, a high degree of leverage for the CEO over the board and compensation committee. Crystal (1991) argues that boards of directors over-compensate senior executives because outside directors are hired by the CEO and can be removed by the CEO. Likewise, Lambert et al. (1993) and Boyd (1994) find a positive relation between CEO compensation and the percentage of the board composed of outside directors. However, Finkelstein and Hambrick (1989) conclude that compensation is unrelated to the percentage of outside directors on the board. Conyon (2006) provides a survey of the evidence supporting these alternative perspectives. Empirical evidence for the managerial power argument has focused on linking CEO pay to measures of board capture or weak corporate governance. Chhaochharia and Grinstein (2009) show that when new standards for board independence were introduced in the wake of corporate scandals in the early 2000s, CEO pay declined disproportionately at firms most affected by the new rules. In a sample of IPO firms, Conyon and He (2004) find that CEOs with large stakeholders on the board (who are presumably stronger monitors) get pay packages tied more closely to firm performance (less 3 cash and more equity). However, the evidence is not uniform; for example, Boyle and Roberts (2013) find that CEOs of New Zealand firms who sit on the board compensation committee are paid less than those who do not. Meanwhile, there is a substantial body of empirical evidence that CEO pay is increasing in firm size (Kostiuk 1989, Murphy 1985); typical estimates put the elasticity of pay with respect to size at 0.25 (so a 10% increase in size is associated with a 2.5% increase in pay). Under the principalagent perspective, this relationship can be seen as reflecting the need to give the CEOs of larger firms incentives commensurate with the larger economic impact of their actions (Gayle and Miller 2009). In contrast, the more cynical view of the managerial power approach would be that larger firms present CEOs with more opportunities to carve out rents (Bebchuk and Fried 2003). This empirical relationship adds nuance to a concern with older roots: namely that CEOs are interested in empire-building for its own sake. Writers, such as Marris (1964) and Aoki (1984) argued that, unencumbered by external constraints, executives are more interested in increasing firm size than maximizing shareholder value. Tosi et al. (2000) attributes this in part to the idea that CEOs can exert more complete control over firm size than performance. In light of this empirical evidence, a growing theoretical literature has attempted to elaborate on the reasons that firm size and CEO pay might be linked. Rosen (1992) suggests that the marginal productivity of a CEO may scale up with firm size because his decisions affect how a larger pool of employees and resources are deployed. When this is so, competitive labor markets will tend to match more talented CEOs with larger firms where they are paid according to their productivity, establishing a positive association between size, CEO ability, and pay. Baker and Hall (2004) extend 4 this theory and take it to the data, finding support for the conjecture that CEO productivity rises with firm size. Building on these results, Gabaix and Landier (2008) develop a competitive equilibrium assignment model of the market for CEO talent and show that calibrated predictions of pay can help to explain not only the size-pay correlation but also time series and cross-country patterns in pay. Tosi et al. (2000) concur that reasons for the size-pay correlation include greater complexity, more stratification, and greater human capital at larger firms. Given the association between firm size and CEO compensation, it is not surprising that actions that change a firm’s size appear to have consequences for pay. Mergers and divestitures are highly visible actions that a CEO can take to grow or shrink his firm, respectively; if he expects these actions to be rewarded or punished in future compensation, there may be a temptation to make decisions that are not aligned with maximizing firm value. On the question of mergers, it has long been suspected that CEOs may be prone to empire-building at the expense of shareholder value. This view is bolstered by considerable empirical evidence that stock markets treat merger announcements as negative news for the acquiring firm and that acquirers tend to overpay for their acquisitions (Moeller et al. 2004). A number of studies have found that CEOs tend to be rewarded for mergers with higher pay (Hartford and Li 2007, Grinstein and Hribar 2004, Yim 2013). Harford and Li (2007) find that growth via internal capital investments is not similarly rewarded and suggest that, for some reason, mergers give CEOs particular leverage in bargaining with boards for better pay. Yim (2013) shows that the pay increase in the year after an acquisition is retained in subsequent years (thus strengthening the incentives of all CEOs to complete mergers, but particularly younger ones who will enjoy these gains over a longer career horizon). If CEOs pursued only mergers that were in their shareholders’ interest, 5 then rewarding them for mergers might be appropriate. Harford and Li (2007) address this by examining the relationship between CEO pay and his firm’s post-merger performance. They find that the overall pay gain from mergers conceals an asymmetry: CEOs are rewarded for mergers that turn out well but are not punished for mergers that turn out poorly. One conceivable explanation is that captured, or partially captured boards, tend to insulate CEOs from the downside consequences of their mistakes. In fact, there is a body of evidence indicating that unwarranted generosity after mergers is exacerbated by weak corporate governance (Harford and Li 2007, Grinstein and Hribar 2004). Grinstein and Hribar (2004) find that weaker boards tend to grant larger bonuses for mergers. Harford and Li (2007) show that CEOs are punished for poor post-merger performance when the board is strong. Furthermore, CEOs with weaker boards tend to make deals that are larger and less profitable (as judged by market reaction) (Harford and Li 2007), suggesting that they may not anticipate consequences for failure. In contrast with the healthy literature on mergers, there is relatively little evidence on how divestitures and other decisions to shrink the firm affect CEO pay. In principle, divestitures should be rewarded or punished, just as with mergers, on the basis of their effect on shareholder value. Bebchuk and Grinstein (2005) find the asymmetric result that increases in firm size lead to higher pay, but decreases in size (measured either by sales or market capitalization) do not cause pay to fall. In one of the few studies to focus explicitly on divestitures, Haynes, Thompson, and Wright (2007) examine panel data from British firms. They find that in general, CEOs are punished for divestitures via the robust link between firm size and pay, suggesting that CEOs will have little incentive to downsize even when it is the right thing to do. However, firms with strong boards are an exception to this rule: they tend to reward CEOs for divestitures. 6 This paper then examines the influence of mergers and divestitures on CEO pay. As part of the analysis, we also assess the influence of board composition and the way these factors have been changing over time, particularly pre and post financial crisis. III. Data and Empirical Methodology This paper analyzes CEO compensation for a set of 123 U.S. companies over a ten-year time period between Jan 1, 2003 and December 31, 2012. In order to assess the effect of large mergers and divestitures, the sample was restricted to companies that engaged in a merger or a divestiture with a transaction value of $1 billion or more. Data on merger and divestiture values and announcement dates were found using the SDC Thomson database. The data set includes 97 companies that engaged in a merger or divestiture and 26 other companies that did not engage in a large merger (>$1 million) during the ten-year time span. Each of the 26 companies was selected because it is a leading competitor for one of the 97 merging companies2. CEO compensation was measured in four ways: salary, total current compensation (salary plus bonus), TDC 1 (Total Direct Compensation 1), and TDC 2 (Total Direct Compensation 2). Compensation data was taken from the Compustat database. TDC 1 estimates the value of total compensation realized by the executive in a given year. This is the sum of salary, bonus, the value of restricted stock granted, the total value of stock options exercised, and the value of long-term incentive payouts. Thus TDC 1 comprises the value of total compensation awarded (but not necessarily realized) to the executive that year. TDC 2 estimates 2 For many of the 97 companies, we could not find a key publicly-held competitor that did not engage in a large merger during the ten-year time span. 7 the value of total compensation using the same method except it replaces the value of restricted stock granted with the net value of stock options exercised. As Kaplan and Rauh (2010) explain: “. . . TDC 2 will be closer to an executive’s true adjusted gross income while TDC 1 will more closely approximate the compensation a company’s board expected to pay the executive”. Firm size was measured using the firm’s sales. We also estimated the effect using firm market capitalization and found similar (unreported) results. We chose firm sales because the Rsquared regression results were higher when using firm sales versus market capitalization. We also investigated the effect of profitability on CEO pay to explore whether the link between pay and performance. Profitability measures along with firm sales were taken from the Compustat database. We used earnings per share from operations. We expect earnings per share to have a positive effect on incentive compensation. We also used the firm’s annual stock market performance as an independent variable. We tried both total and net stock market performance (subtracting out the benchmark index annual performance), but did not find differences in significance between the variables. In addition, we used dummy variables to identify the year that the CEO was hired and whether the CEO was hired from inside the firm or the outside. The hypothesis is that incentive compensation will be lower if the CEO is a new hire, as incentives may be built in over time. Also, we hypothesize that CEOs hired from the outside may receive higher salary or incentive compensation than inside hires, based on the theory that the firm faces more competition for outside hires (both from the CEOs’ current employers and from other firms trying to hire them). Finally, we examined board composition using the Risk Metrics database. Each board 8 member is categorized in this database as being an employee, linked (affiliated3), or independent. It has been assumed that the higher the percentage of affiliated board members the higher the CEO compensation, though statistical studies have not completely borne this out. (See Hallock 1997; Core et. al. 1999, and Fich and White 2003.) If there is no registered linkage, then the board member is either classified as an outside member, independent, or an employee member. III.a. Summary statistics Table 1 shows company sales and compensation by industry. From the table we see that the sample is fairly well dispersed between industries. The consumer products, technology, industrial, and healthcare sectors each accounted for 15% to 17% of the sample. The oil and gas and financial segments were 12% and 11% of the total, while the utility, retail, and transportation sectors were 6%, 5%, and 2% of the total. From Table 1 we see the highest average salaries among sampled firms are paid in the consumer packaged goods industry, followed by the retail industry. One of the commonalities between these two industries is that they are relatively non-cyclical. The cyclical industries, such as oil and gas, industrial, and technology industries each pay lower salaries but higher stock and option compensation, as shown in TDC 1 and TDC 2. Companies in the financial sector are the largest as measured by market capitalization, while companies in the utility and transport sectors maintained the lowest market capitalization. The retail sector had the highest compensation using TDC 1 and TDC 2, as well as total current compensation. 3 Refers to a board of director’s member, who may be either a retired employee or one who does business with the organization on which he/she serves as a member of the board. (See Economic Research web site http://www.erieri.com/glossary/term/affiliated%20director/45) 9 Figure 1 shows annual pay by compensation category. Here we see increasing compensation for all categories over the first three (2003-2005) or six years (2003-2008) of the sample. A sharp decline in the compensation level in each of the categories, except salaries, then occurs around 2009. The compensation categories that include stock and option grants (TDC 1 and TDC 2) show a time trend similar to overall stock market performance over the period: rising through the first half of the decade and then declining in the years leading up to and including the recession of 2008/2009, before recovering around 2010. TDC 2 declined particularly sharply since this compensation category includes stock options exercised, and is therefore closely tied to contemporaneous market performance. TDC 1 declined more gradually, as TDC 1 includes stock options awarded. We also see in Figure 1 that average salary increased slightly (from $1.0 million to $1.3 million), while total current compensation (salary plus bonus) actually fell between 2003 and 2012. In contrast with the decline in TDC 2, which is sharpest in 2008, the declines in total current compensation and TDC 1 begin in 2006, preceding the recession. Figure 2 shows the annual number of merger announcements and divestitures, while Figure 3 shows the average transaction value of merger announcements and divestitures. We see from Figure 2 that merger announcements increased for the first three years of the sample period and then declined over the last four years of the sample (2009-2012) to the 2003/2004 level. Divestiture announcements remained steady between two and five for the first six years of the sample and, like merger announcements, declined significantly in 2009. There were then a large number of divestitures that occurred in 2011. Table 2 shows the total number of mergers and divestitures by industry as well as the 10 average and relative merger value by industry. Here we see that the largest number of mergers occurred in the technology industry, while the highest merger values occurred in the financial industry. Also, we observe that the high relative merger value (merger value / market capitalization) occurred in the utility sector. Regarding divestitures, we see that the consumer sector accounted for the largest number and largest value of divestitures. From Figure 3 we see that, in addition to the growing number of mergers between 2003 and 2005, the average merger value was also growing larger. Merger value then declined but rose sharply in 2008 and 2009, suggesting a few large mergers were announced in the recession years. Figure 4 shows CEO board composition by year. There is a gradual but sustained trend toward more independent board membership over the period, as the average fraction of independent members rises from 70% to 85%. This rise is made possible by a steady decline in both employee and affiliated board members over the ten years. Table 3 presents summary statistics for the board composition, stock market, and control variables used in the regression equation. We see in Table 3 that the firms in this sample on average had a 7.0% higher stock market return than the S&P 500. This result could suggest a selection bias in that successful firms are making acquisitions or divestitures. We also see that outside hires accounted for 23% of the CEOs in our sample; in addition, 13% of CEOs were new hires (in their first year with the company). Finally, note that 79% of the directors were classified by Risk Metrics as independent directors, 13.5% were employee directors, and 6.5% were affiliated directors. 11 III.b Empirical strategy We estimated several models of the determinants of CEO compensation following the basic template below for firm j in year t: (1) Compensationjt = β0+ β1lag firm salesjt-1 + β2Merge/Divestjt + β3Merger valuejt + β4 Divest. value jt + β5lag EPSjt-1 + β6lag stock market returnjt-1 + β7lagS&P returnjt-1+ β8EmployeePercentjt + β9AffiliatedPercentjt + β10Insidejt + β11NewHirejt + β12financial crisist + β13Industryj+ + εjt Separate regressions were run on each of the four executive compensation measures. These variables were logged as were the continuous independent variables shown. Merge/Divest is a dummy variable that distinguishes between companies that engaged in a merger or divestiture with a transaction value of greater than $1 billion during sample period. Merger and divestiture announcements are dummy variable with one (1) used to indicate the year of a merger of divestiture announcement, and zero (0) the year when no merger/announcement merger was made. The merger value and divestiture values refer to the transaction value as reported at the time of the merger or divestiture announcement. Market capitalization refers to the market value of the firm at the year-end. EPS refers to earnings per share from operations. EPS and stock market return were used to examine how CEO compensation is tied to firm profitability. Net stock margin return is the annual stock market return, including dividends, subtracting out the return on the benchmark index (S&P 500).4 Employee percentage and affiliated percentage represent the fraction of employees and affiliates respectively on the firm’s board; these variables are intended to assess the effect that board composition has on CEO compensation. The coefficients for these two variables should 4 We tried both net and absolute stock market return but did not find a difference in the findings. 12 be interpreted relative to the omitted category, the percentage of board members who are independent. Following the literature on corporate governance, we hypothesize that boards with more affiliated members will be more vulnerable to CEO influence, and thus will dole out higher pay. In contrast, we expect employee board membership to result in lower compensation, as independent directors may be seeking higher pay to influence the pay at their own companies. Finally, financial crisis is a dummy variable indicating whether compensation was awarded before or after the onset of the financial crisis. It is equal to 0 for years up to 2007, and switches to 1 for 2008 and subsequent years. Control variables include two dummy variables that indicate if the CEO was a new hire in the particular year and if the CEO is hired from outside the firm. We would expect that CEOs hired from outside the firm would command a higher payout than CEOs hired internally. Also, we expect new hires to receive lower compensation, partly because of lags in awarding and exercising incentive pay, and partly because they tend to be younger and pay trends upward over the lifecycle. Finally, we include industry and year fixed effects. We also estimated a separate regression that included interactive terms between financial crisis and lag EPS, merger value, log firm sales, stock market returns, and S&P returns regressed against the four compensation variables. The intent of these regressions is to examine the joint effect between the financial crisis and merger value, as well as other covariates of interest. Finally, in a fifth regression we created interaction variables between merger value and five of the industry terms (the industries with the largest frequency in the sample). We did this to assess differences in the merger effect on CEO compensation by industry. Also, we wanted to assess whether potential findings regarding the impact of merger value on CEO compensation 13 are driven by one or two industries. IV. Results Table 5 shows the results from the regression equation for the four dependent variables (salary, total current compensation, TDC 1, and TDC 2). All continuous variables except for employee and affiliated percentage and stock market returns5 are measured in logs, and therefore, the parameter estimates can be interpreted as elasticities. We see in this table that the coefficient for firm size6 (lag firm sales) is positive and significant to the one percent level for each of the dependent variables for CEO compensation. This finding, as expected, suggests that firm size influences CEO compensation. The coefficient for lag sales of .15 to .26 is similar to the .25 coefficient found in other studies7. We also see the coefficient for the firm merge/divest variable, which indicates whether the firm completed a merger or divestiture in the ten-year time period, is positive and significant when regressed against salary and total compensation. This may be explained by the notion that simply announcing a merger or divestiture indicates to the board that the CEO is making positive change in the company or has the skill sets to make major changes. From Table 5, we also see the coefficient for merger value is positive and significant when regressed against TDC 1 and TDC 2 (but not for salary or total compensation). This finding is consistent with other studies8, suggesting that CEOs are rewarded for larger mergers, over and beyond the increase one would expect simply because the merged firm has grown larger. Note that 5 Many of the stock market returns were negative, so we did not log this variable. The results were similar when firm market capitalization (logged) was used instead of firm sales; we chose to use firm sales because the R-squared was higher when this variable was used. 7 See Kostiuk 1989, Murphy 1985. 8 See Hartford and Li 2007, Grinstein and Hribar 2004, Yim 2013. 6 14 there is a substantial body of evidence indicating that merger announcements tend to depress the stock price of the acquiring firm; this would tend to generate a negative relationship between mergers and TDC1 and TDC2. Taking this effect into account, it is possible that boards intend to reward CEOs more generously for mergers than indicated by our coefficients. The effect of mergers and divestitures is asymmetric, as divestitures have no significant effect on any form of CEO compensation. This may reflect competing effects: while divestitures are often regarded positively by the market, with a corresponding gain in share price, they reduce the size of the firm and the scope of the CEO, for which he may be (unfairly) punished. The results from Table 5 also indicate that the fraction of employees on the board is negatively related to salary and TDC 1 (with significance at the 10% and 1% levels). We also see the coefficient for affiliated board percentage is negative and significant to the 1% in its effect on TDC 1 and TDC 2. The coefficient for affiliated percentage is also fairly large (-.79 and -1.03); implying that a 1% increase in affiliated percentage relative to independent percentage would cause a .79% and 1.03% decrease in TDC 1 and TDC 2. In other words adding one additional affiliated member to the board reduces CEO pay by 7.9% to 10.3%. This result is counter-intuitive since affiliated board members are closely associated with the CEO. One possible explanation is that affiliated board members may be less inclined to pay large salaries due to concerns of conflict of interest or being too close to the CEO. We find that TDC 1 and TDC 2 are linked to firm performance, but salary and total compensation generally are not. Specifically, TDC 1 and TDC 2 receive positive, significant effects from lagged earnings per share and from lagged stock market performance. While lagged stock market performance also has a significant positive effect on total compensation, the effect of EPS is 15 peculiarly negative and significant (albeit small). While this provides some evidence of pay for performance, the conclusion is somewhat undone by the large positive and significant effects of the S&P return on TDC 1 and TDC 2, which indicates that CEOs are being rewarded for individual firm returns on top of a reward for the rising tide of the overall market. Controlling for other factors, total compensation fell significantly after the financial crisis. In contrast, salaries rose significantly (but by a much smaller amount), indicating a shift away from bonuses (and perhaps a desire to smooth out pay). However, neither TDC 1 nor TDC 29 changes significantly post-crisis. This is a bit surprising, as one might have expected both to fall simply because stock prices were lower, reducing the value of stock and option grants. One possible explanation would be a countervailing increase in the volume of such grants post-crisis, perhaps with the intention of keeping CEOs more accountable for performance. Finally, we see that being a new hire has a negative effect on all four forms of CEO compensation, suggesting that compensation may accumulate over time of service, with the first year having the lowest pay. Also, we see that the coefficient for the outside hire variable is positive and significant when regressed against TDC 1. This finding suggests that firms provide higher incentive compensation packages in the form of stock payouts and options to CEOs that are hired from the outside, relative to those promoted from within the firm. Table 6 shows the regression results with merger value and other covariates interacted with the financial crisis dummy.10 The most salient result relates to firm sales. Pre-crisis, the elasticity of pay with respect to firm sales is positive and significant for all four measures of pay, with elasticities 9 TDC 2 declined significantly in the years leading up to the financial crisis, but then returned to a growth trajectory post crisis. 10 There is not enough variation in the board composition variables to estimate their pre- and post-crisis effects separately. 16 ranging from 0.12 to 0.33. After the crisis these elasticities drop significantly in all four cases. For salaries and total compensation, the effect of this drop is to essentially wipe out any link between size and pay. The decline is less dramatic for TDC 1 and TDC 2, but the elasticity with respect to size still falls by roughly 40% in both cases. An optimistic interpretation would be that the crisis had a sobering effect on boards, making them more reluctant to reward CEOs for outcomes unrelated to shareholder value. A more cynical possibility is that CEOs were rewarded for sales growth in the boom years but were not punished when sales dropped after the crisis. If compensation shifted away from factors unrelated to shareholder value after the crisis, does that mean that it became more closely tied to a CEO’s performance? The evidence suggests a weak and qualified yes. Pre-crisis, lagged earnings per share have a negligible (often negative) and insignificant effect on all forms of pay except TDC 1. However, their effect rises post-crisis for all four measures of pay, significantly so for total compensation and TDC 2. Similarly, before the crisis, lagged stock market returns have no significant effect on pay except for TDC 2. Afterwards though, their effect rises (except for TDC 2, which remains level), with a significant increase in the effect on salary. Thus we have qualified evidence that compensation became more responsive to firm performance in the wake of the financial crisis. Furthermore, there appears to be some shift away from rewarding CEO’s simply for a rising tide in the overall market. Pre-crisis, there is some evidence that bonuses are benchmarked against market performance (the negative coefficient on the S&P return for total compensation), but this is belied by the large and significant positive effect of S&P returns on TDC 1 and TDC 2. Presumably any benchmarking of bonuses is more than undone by generous (or no) benchmarking of stock and option grants. The main change post-crisis is that this positive effect of S&P returns on TDC 1 and 17 TDC 2 is completely wiped out (although a new positive effect on salaries does emerge). This could reflect a new emphasis on tying stock and option incentives to relative performance in the wake of the financial crisis (among other possible explanations). We also see in the results from Table 6 that the coefficient for the interactive term between merger value and financial crisis is insignificant in all four regressions. This finding would indicate that the effect of mergers did not change in the post financial crisis period. Finally, Table 6 examines the influence of industry interacted with merger value percentage. From these results we see that the coefficients for merger value interacted with the technology sector had a positive effect on CEO salary, TDC 1 and TDC 2. This result would suggest that CEOs in the technology industries receive a higher salary and stock and option-based compensation, the larger the merger value. This finding would also indicate that the principal-agent concern relating to mergers may be industry specific. It is also possible that higher CEO salaries and total compensation due to mergers are warranted in the rapidly evolving technology industry, where mergers are necessary to innovate and redefine the company. We also find that merger value percentage interacted with the oil and gas industry has a positive effect on CEO total compensation. It is unclear why the effect in the oil and gas industry would only show up with total compensation. We do not find any of the other interactive terms formed between merger value and the industry to be significant in their effect on any of the four CEO compensation variables. V. Conclusions We examine the determinants of CEO compensation over a ten-year period spanning the 2008 financial crisis, focusing on the effect of mergers and divestitures. After accounting for a pre-crisis 18 rise in pay followed by a crash when the crisis hit, average pay is flat over this period. This marks a break with the twenty years prior during which CEO pay saw a rapid expansion. Consistent with other studies, we find an elasticity of compensation with respect to firm size of roughly 0.15 to 0.26, with a greater effect found pre-financial crisis than post-crisis. After accounting for firm size, merger value was associated with CEO variable compensation, as measured by TDC 1 and TDC 2. In contrast, divestiture values have no measurable effect on pay after controlling for firm size. Board composition also appears to influence CEO compensation with higher employee percentage associated with lower CEO compensation, measured by salary and total compensation. In contrast, higher employee or affiliated board membership appears associated with lower CEO compensation, measured by TDC 1 and TDC 2. For employee board membership the result was limited to the post financial crisis period. Also, the results indicate that stock market returns and profitability measured by EPS may have a greater effect on CEO compensation in the post financial crisis period, while the effect of firm size and overall market returns diminishes. This finding suggests that CEO compensation was influenced to a greater extent by pay for performance criteria in the post financial crisis period. Finally, we find that the merger effect on CEO compensation may be industry-specific given the positive effect that merger value percentage interacted with select industries (technology and oil and gas) had on CEO salary and total compensation. In summary, while firm size appears to have the largest effect on CEO compensation, there are other strong influences to include merger value, board composition, industry, and short term financial performance (measured by earning per share and stock market performance) that also appear to influence CEO pay. It is left to other studies to 19 disentangle these effects further. 20 References Aoki M. 1984. The Co-operative Game Theory of the Firm. Oxford University Press: Oxford. Baker, G. and Hall, B., 2004. CEO Incentives and Firm Size. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(4): 767-798. Bebchuk, L. and Fried, J. 2003. Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3): 71-92 Bebchuk, L. and Grinstein, Y., 2005. Firm Expansion and CEO Pay. NBER Working Paper 11886, http://www.nber.org/papers/w11886.pdf. Boyd, B.K. 1994. Board control and CEO compensation Strategic Management Journal, 15 335– 344. Boyle, G. and Roberts, H. 2013. CEO Presence on the Compensation Committee: A Puzzle. Journal of Economics and Business. 70: 16-26. Becher, D. and Juergens, J. Do Acquirer CEO http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2117397 Incentives impact Mergers, Chhaochharia, V. and Grinstein, Y. 2009. CEO Compensation and Board Structure. Journal of Finance, 64(1): 231-260. Conyon, M. J., 2006. Executive Compensation and Incentives, Academy of Management Perspectives, 20(1), 25-44 Conyon, M. J. and L. H. 2004. Compensation Committees and CEO Compensation Incentives in U.S. Entrepreneurial Firms. Journal of Management Accounting Research: December 2004, 16(1), 35-56. Core, J., Guay, W., and Larcker, D. 2003. Executive equity compensation and incentives: a survey. FRBNY Economic Policy Review, April: 27-50. Core, J., Holthausen, R., and Larcker, D., 1999. Corporate governance, chief executive officer compensation and firm performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 51: 371-406. Crystal, G. 1991. In Search of Excess: The Overcompensation of American Executives W.W. Norton and Company, New York. Fich, E.M. and White, L.J. 2003. CEO Compensation and Turnover: The Effects of Mutually Interlocked Boards. Wake Forest Law Review, 38(3). 21 Finkelstein, S. Hambrick, D. 1989. Chief executive compensation: a study of the intersection of markets and political processes. Strategic Management Journal, 10 1989, 121-134. Gabaix, X. and Landier, A., 2008. Why Has CEO Pay Increased So Much? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1): 49-100. Gayle, G., and Miller, R. 2009. Has moral hazard become a more important factor in managerial compensation? American Economic Review, 99, 1740-1769. Grinstein, Y., and Hribar, P., 2004. CEO Compensation and Incentives: Evidence from M&A Bonuses. Journal of Financial Economics, 73: 119-143. Hallock, K.F. 1997. Reciprocally interlocking boards of directors and executive compensation [Electronic version]. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 32(3), 331-343. Harford, J. and Li, K., 2007. Decoupling CEO Wealth and Firm Performance: The Case of Acquiring CEOs. Journal of Finance, 62(2): 917-949. Haynes, M., Thompson, S., and Wright, M., 2007. Executive Remuneration and Corporate Divestment: Motivating Managers to Make Unpalatable Decisions. Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 34(5): 792-818. Kaplan, Steven N., and Joshua Rauh. 2010. “Wall Street and Main Street: What Contributes to the Rise in the Highest Incomes?” Review of Financial Studies 23(3): 1004-1050. Kostiuk, P. F., 1989. Firm Size and Executive Compensation, The Journal of Human Resources, 25(1), 90-105. Lambert, R. Larcker, D. Weigelt, K. 1993. The Structure of Organizational Incentives, Administrative Science Quarterly, 38, 438–461 Marris,R. 1964. The Economic Theory of Managerial Capitalism, Macmillan, London. Moeller, S., Schlingemann, F., and Stulz, R., 2004. Firm Size and the Gains from Acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics, 73, 201-228. Murphy, K. J., 1985. Corporate Performance and Managerial Remuneration, Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7 (2), 11-42. Rosen, S.. 1992. Contracts and the market for executives. In Contract Economics, ed. Lars Werin and Hans Wijkander, pp. 181–211. Cambridge, MA: Blackwell. Tosi, H., Werner, S, Katz, J., Gomez, L. 2000. How Much Does Performance Matter. A MetaAnalysis of CEO Pay Studies. Journal of Management 26(2), 301-339. 22 Yim, S., 2013. The Acquisitiveness of Youth: CEO Age and Acquisition Behavior. Journal of Financial Economics, 108: 250-273. 23 Figure 1: Annual Executive Compensation by Type (in $1,000) 24 Table 1: CEO Compensation by Industry Industry Frequency Size (Market Cap in Billions) Size (sales in Billions) Salary (in 000s) Total Current Compensation (in 000s) TDC 1 (in 000s) TDC 2 (in 000s) Consumer 20 $44,629 $27,417 $1,742 $4,176 $14,599 $16,988 Technology 19 $59,263 $33,698 $982 $1,786 $14,439 $19,463 Industrial 20 $36,796 $33,764 $1,278 $2,275 $10,926 $11,361 Financial 14 $76,588 $57,089 $1,144 $4,017 $17,262 $21,201 Healthcare 21 $46,417 $26,607 $1,195 $1,881 $11,200 $13,585 Oil and gas 15 $58,857 $66,217 $1,341 $2,487 $13,944 $21,825 Retail 6 $33,901 $67,533 $1,263 $2,323 $20,516 $26,128 Transport 3 $13,858 $22,485 $749 $1,221 $6,569 $9,416 Utility 7 $16,130 $10,529 $843 $1,136 $6,554 $7,865 $47,233 $36,490 $1,227 $2,480 $13,067 $16,235 Average 25 Figure 2: Annual Merger and Divestiture Announcements Industry Number of Mergers Table 2: Merger Summary Statistics Average Relative Merger Number Average Merger Merger Size of Divestiture Size (In Size Stand. Divest. Size (In millions) Dev. millions) Relative Divest. Size Divest. size stand. dev. Consumer 22 $9,132 20% $1,801 13 $18,544 9% $8,345 Technology 40 $6,722 11% $2,948 3 $8,949 $2,277 Industrial 22 $3,453 9% $742 7 $8,948 3% 6% Financial 18 $15,086 20% $4,562 8 $2,392 5% $494 Healthcare 32 $8,231 18% $2,432 11 $11,054 4% $7,460 Oil and gas 14 $10,147 17% $3,340 6 $7,998 4% $3,498 Retail 8 $8,367 25% $4,266 2 $3,412 7% $1,262 Transport 3 $1,858 13% $570 1 $2,400 9% - Utility 3 $14,092 87% $5,872 2 $10,131 7% $7,831 162 $8,268 18% $1,008 49 $10,249 5% $2,480 Average 26 $,594 Figure 3: Merger and Divestiture Value by Year 27 Figure 4: Board Composition Percentage by Year 28 Table 3: Summary Statistics Variable Mean Earnings Per Share 3.06 Net Stock Market Return 0.07 New Hire Standard Deviation 0.09 Min Max 2.87 3.25 0.008 0.06 0.09 0.13 0.014 0.102 0.159 Outside Hire 0.23 0.018 0.19 0.27 Employee Percentage 0.135 0.003 0.13 0.14 Independent Percentage 0.792 0.006 0.78 0.80 Affiliated Percentage 0.07 0.004 0.06 0.08 . Table 4: Summary Statistics – Merging/Divesting versus Non-Merging/Divesting Firms Merging/Divesting Companies Non merging/divesting companies Size (Market Cap, millions) $55,255 $16,791 Size (Sales) $42,293 $16,017 Salary (thousands) $1,246 $1,198 Total Compensation $2,629 $1,908 TDC1 TDC2 $14,091 $17,553 $9,135 $11,171 3.15 3.32 5.8% 11.1% 79% 14% 7% 81% 15% 4% Category EPS Net stock market return IP EP LP 29 Table 5: Regression Results Merge/Non merge firms Lag Firm sales (logged) Merger value (in logs) Divestiture value (in logs) Lag EPS (logged) Financial crisis Lag Stock market return Lag S&P Return Employee Percent Affiliated Percent Outside New Hire Industry Dummies No. of Observations R2 (1) Salary 0.08*** (0.03) 0.15*** (0.01) 0.03 (0.02) -0.02 (0.02) (2) Total Current Compensation 0.11** (0.05) 0.21*** (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) 0.02 (0.02) -0.06 (0.06) 0.05** (0.02) 0.04 (0.03) -0.05 (0.25) -0.28* (0.16) -0.11 (0.13) -0.02 (0.03) -0.16*** (0.03) Yes 887 0.45 -0.02** (0.01) -0.38*** (0.04) 0.15*** (0.06) 0.03 (0.11) 0.38 (0.28) 0.33 (0.25) 0.01 (0.02) -0.11* (0.05) Yes 862 0.34 (3) TDC 1 -0.03 (0.07) 0.26*** (0.03) 0.02*** (0.001) 0.01 (0.01) (4) TDC 2 0.01 (0.07) 0.25*** (0.04) 0.014** (0.006) 0.01 (0.01) 0.04*** (0.01) 0.03 (0.06) 0.33*** (0.08) 0.34*** (0.14) -0.89*** (0.38) -0.79*** (0.34) 0.20*** (0.07) -0.26*** (0.08) Yes 919 0.30 0.06*** (0.01) 0.01 (0.07) 0.59*** (0.10) 0.44*** (0.17) -0.40 (0.45) -1.03*** (0.40) 0.09 (0.09) -0.48*** (0.10) Yes 918 0.25 Notes: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. MSE denotes means square error. 30 Table 6: Regression Results – Financial Crisis Effect Merge/Non merge firms Lag Firm sales (logged) Lag Firm sales * Crisis (logged) Merger value (in logs) Merger value * Crisis (in logs) Lag EPS (in logs) Lag EPS * Crisis (in logs) Lag Stock market return Lag stock market * Crisis S&P Return S&P return * Crisis Employee Percentage Affiliated Percentage Outside New Hire Industry Dummies No of Observations R-squared (1) Salary 0.09 (0.07) 0.12*** (0.04) -0.13** (0.06) 0.01 (0.11) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.02) 0.10 (0.06) -0.26 (0.34) (2) Total Current Compensation 0.13* (0.07) 0.26*** (0.03) -0.24*** (0.06) 0.01 (0.01) 0.01 (0.01) -0.04 (0.02) 0.13** (0.06) 0.24 (0.16) 1.01** (0.52) (0.56) (0.63 2.16*** (0.95) -3.11*** (1.21) 0.39 (0.38) -0.06 (0.08) -0.34** (0.17) Yes 894 0.16 0.55 (0.44) -2.35*** (0.86) 0.30 (0.88) -2.15** (1.10) 0.42 (0.36) 0.15 (0.13) -0.35** (0.18) Yes 894 0.23 31 (3) TDC 1 0.08 (0.10) 0.33*** (0.04) -0.14*** (0.05) 0.08 (0.08) -0.04 (0.03) 0.05** (0.025) 0.01 (0.01) 0.17 (0.19) (4) TDC 2 0.06 (0.14) 0.33*** (0.04) -0.13** (0.05) 0.01 (0.01) -0.01 (0.01) 0.02 (0.03) 0.05* (0.03) 0.64*** (0.26) 0.31 (0.25) 3.45*** (1.15) -4.12*** (1.19) -1.01** (0.51) -0.78** (0.38) 0.15** (0.06) 0.28*** (0.08) Yes 919 0.32 -0.03 (0.30) 4.00*** (1.48) -5.16*** (1.92) -0.47 (0.63) -0.98** (0.44) 0.03 (0.08) -0.53*** (0.08) Yes 918 0.26 Notes: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. MSE denotes means square error. 32 Table 7: Regression Results – Industries Interacted with Merger Value (2) Total Current (1) Salary Compensation (3) TDC 1 Merge/Non merge -0.05 0.12** 0.01 Firms (0.05) (0.05) (0.07) Lag Firm sales 0.14*** 0.12*** 0.26*** (logged) (0.01) (0.04) (0.03) Lag EPS (logged) Financial crisis Lag Stock market Return S&P Return Employee Percentage Affiliated Percentage Outside New Hire MergerVal*Technology MergerVal*oil and gas Industry Dummies No. of Observations Adjusted R2 (4) TDC 2 -0.04 (0.09) 0.25*** (0.04) 0.02 (0.014) -0.53* (0.27) -0.01 (0.05) 0.01 (0.10) -0.53* (0.27) 0.10 (0.24) 0.17** (0.06) -0.39*** (0.04) -0.02** (0.01) 0.05 (0.10) 0.51* (0.28) 0.31 (0.24) 0.04*** (0.01) 0.01 (0.06) 0.44*** (0.08) 0.33 (0.13) -0.82*** (0.39) -0.80*** (0.35) 0.26 (0.16) 0.01 (0.07) 0.60** (0.10) 0.42*** (0.17) -0.42 (0.46) -1.06*** (0.41) 0.16 (0.13) -0.13* (0.05) 0.002* (0.001) 0.01 (0.01) 0.23* (0.14) -0.20* (0.11) 0.01 (0.01) 0.002* (0.001) 0.16* (0.09) -0.29*** (0.11) 0.002** (0.001) 0.01 (0.01) 0.226 (0.226) -0.51*** (0.12) 0.002** (0.001) 0.01 (0.01) Yes 919 0.30 Yes 408 0.25 Yes 888 0.22 Yes 888 0.31 Notes: Robust standard errors are in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote statistical significance levels of 1%, 5%, and 10% respectively. MSE denotes means square error. 33