JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC ISSUES Vol. XLVIII No. 3 September 2014 DOI 10.2753/JEI0021-3624480305 Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti Abstract: Since 2008, the U.S. economy has been mired in the second worst economic crisis in its history. Conceivably, massive government spending could bring the economy out of this slump as massive war spending ultimately ended the Great Depression of the 1930s. However, a far superior strategy exists: guaranteeing employment accompanied by retraining to enable all unemployed workers to become absorbed into the regular work force. Beyond ending the crisis, the superiority of this strategy is that it would institutionalize a procedure for insuring that, in an increasingly technologically dynamic and open economy, workers would possess the necessary skills for available jobs. Guaranteeing employment would also eliminate the ecological costs associated with the need to seek growth to generate employment at practically any cost. Finally, it would establish a new moral social contract, whereby everyone is granted the dignity that accompanies being a productive member of society. Welfare for those able to work could disappear, along with the degradation and humiliation accompanying it. Keywords: employer of last resort, inadequate demand, inequality, unemployment JEL Classification Codes: E24, H10, J38 [No] country however rich, can afford the waste of its human resources. Demoralization caused by mass unemployment is our greatest extravagance. Morally, it is the greatest menace to our social order. -- Franklin D. Roosevelt (1934) The real problem, fundamental yet essentially simple [is] to provide employment for everyone. -- John Maynard Keynes (1980, 267) The voices which, in such a conjuncture, tell us that the path of escape is to be found in strict economy and in refraining, Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti are professor of economics at American University and assistant professor of economics at Siena College, respectively. Helpful comments by Chris Brown and two anonymous referees are gratefully acknowledged. 679 ©2014, Journal of Economic Issues / Association for Evolutionary Economics Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti 680 wherever possible, from utilizing the world’s potential production, are the voices of fools and madmen. -- John Maynard Keynes ([1933] 1982, XXI, 61) Eleven percent of the U.S. workforce — 6.2 million workers — remained unemployed in 1939, ten years after the onset of the Great Depression. Two years later, as the US entered WWII, unemployment was halved, and by 1944, the unemployment rate fell to an unprecedented 1.0 percent. What happened? The U.S. government began massive deficit spending and — far less noted — became a de facto employer of last resort when it placed over ten million Americans in uniform, and added another two million to the Department of Defense and other agencies. War-stimulated demand employed an additional five million Americans. In all, employment increased by seventeen million (Vatter 1985, 16-17), increasing the total labor force by 18 percent.1 In doing so, it drew minorities and women into the active workforce, breaking through barriers that had traditionally excluded them. Currently, the U.S. economy is trapped in the second worst economic crisis in its history. Although less severe, it shares common roots in the dramatic rise in inequality preceding both of these crises, resulting in inadequate aggregate demand, consumption externalities, and distortions that fueled massive indebtedness, and speculative frenzy — conditions consequent to the dominance of laissez faire ideology. Many workers have become so discouraged that they have left the workforce entirely, as can be seen by the sharp fall in the employment-population ratio in Figure 1: Figure 1. Civilian Employment-Population Ratio (Percent), 2007–2013 64.0 63.0 62.0 61.0 60.0 59.0 58.0 Sep-13 Jan-13 May-13 Sep-12 Jan-12 May-12 Sep-11 Jan-11 May-11 Sep-10 Jan-10 May-10 Sep-09 Jan-09 May-09 Sep-08 Jan-08 May-08 Sep-07 Jan-07 May-07 57.0 Employment-Population Ratio Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics (2007–2013). 1 As of May 2014, employing an additional 17 million workers, and assuming the unemployment rate fell from 6.3 to 1.0 percent, would require approximately 8.5 million new or re-entering labor-market participants. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 681 The employment-population ratio declined from 63.3 in January 2007 to 58.7 percent in June 2013. Although the recession formally ended in June 2009, and the share of the population with a job reached a low of 58.2 percent in November 2010, it has flat lined since, indicating that the economy remains in what many call the “Great Recession.” What is clear is that the continuingly weak economy is a major tragedy for all who remain involuntarily unemployed. Massive government spending brought the U.S. economy out of the Great Depression, and — pace the mistaken budget hawks — it could end the current crisis.2 This article claims that there is a far superior solution. It is one that not only would end the crisis, but also address serious social problems, prepare the workforce for an increasingly technologically dynamic and open economy, and better enable the country to address the worsening ecological crisis. It would also establish a new moral social contract which provides everyone with the dignity that accompanies being a productive member of society. Welfare for the work-able could end, along with the degradation and humiliation accompanying it. That superior solution is government guaranteed employment and the requisite retraining to enable all workers to successfully enter and remain in the regular workforce. A rich literature has evolved over the past several decades (discussed below) providing detail as to how a program of guaranteed employment would work. This article advances this discourse by examining why the ongoing unemployment crisis especially mandates that serious consideration be given to such a program, and why it is critical that it be supplemented by a retraining component. Current conditions that especially justify a skilling program include ever-increasing inequality, accompanied by lessened social mobility, the slowing pace of recovery from recessions (Olney and Pacitti 2013), rising concern that the current crisis may be harbinger of a sustained period of economic stagnation (Colander 2013; Gordon 2012; Krugman 2013; Summers 2013; Wray 2013), and that we may be nearing a point of no return if remedial environmental actions are not undertaken. The next section of this article addresses the causes that brought on the current crisis and underlie its intractability. Attention then turns to why a program of guaranteed employment and retraining would be superior to conventional deficit spending for ending the crisis, followed by a summary of how such a program might work, and then a discussion of its costs. The following section identifies additional benefits of guaranteed employment with a retraining program. The article concludes with reflections on the political conditions confronting the implementation of a program of guaranteed employment and reskilling. Inequality, Inadequate Demand, and Crises Wage stagnation and rising inequality were core causes of the financial crisis of 2008, as had been the case in 1929. As Stiglitz notes, “[i]n the wake of the 2008 global financial crisis, there is now an increasing global consensus that inequality leads to 2 As Keynes put it, “[l]ook after the unemployed, and the budget will look after itself” ([1933] 1982, CW XXI, 150). 682 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti instability and that instability contributes to inequality” (2012, 91). Over the three decades preceding 2008, and the decade leading up to 1929, wages practically stagnated, lagging far behind productivity gains. The extreme degree of inequality accompanying wage stagnation is captured by the fact that, on the eve of both crises, the top 1.0 percent received historically high shares — just under 25 percent — of total income (Alvaredo et al. 2013). Wage stagnation and exploding inequality generated three dynamics that made the economy vulnerable to systemic dysfunction in the runups to both 1929 and 2008 (Wisman 2013b, 2014; Wisman and Baker 2010). The first is that they constrained consumption, reducing profitable investment potential in the real economy, and thereby encouraging an ever wealthier elite to flood financial markets with credit. This credit helped keep interest rates low, and encouraged the creation of new financial instruments and greater indebtedness as some of the excess income and wealth of the rich was recycled as debt to those below. In both instances rising inequality fueled speculation in financial and real estate markets, resulting in macroeconomic instability (Galbraith 2012; Kumhof and Rancière 2010). The second dynamic is that consumption externalities were generated, forcing individuals to struggle harder to find ways to maintain the welfare of their families and their relative social status. The consequence was that, by the eve of the 2008 crisis, the personal saving rate had fallen from 10.4 percent in the early 1980s to negative in 2006. Between the periods 1898–1916 and 1922–1929, personal saving as a percent of disposable income declined by 42 percent — from 6.4 to 3.8 percent (Olney 1991, 48-49). Part of the excess income of the rich was recycled into debt to families below, as total household debt as a percent of disposable income doubled — from about 62 percent in 1974 to 129 percent in late 2007. From 1919 to 1929, debt as a percent of income almost doubled, increasing from 4.64 to 9.34 percent (Olney 1991, 88-89). And by 2007, the average married household worked 19 percent more hours than they did in 1979 — the equivalent of over one extra work day per week. Although work hours are unavailable, in the 1920s, with female participation rates increasing from 24.3 to 25.1 percent, household workweeks may have increased (Smiley 2010, 4). The third dynamic is that, as the rich took larger shares of income and wealth, they gained more command over ideology, and hence politics (Hacker and Pierson 2010; Wisman 2013c). Reducing the size of government, abandoning full employment policies, undermining unions, cutting taxes for the wealthy, reducing welfare for the poor, deregulating the economy, and failing to regulate newly evolving credit instruments, flowed out of this ideology, causing policy-induced increases in inequality (Schmitt 2009). The rise in inequality that brought on these crises now impedes recovery. Inequality reduces aggregate demand by negatively affecting consumption, investment, and government spending (Rohit 2011). The consumption propensity of upper-income groups is substantially lower than that of lower-income groups, so an upward redistribution of income will lower aggregate demand. On average, the wealthiest 1.0 percent of income earners spend 49 percent of their income, the richest 20 percent spend 76 percent, and the bottom 80 percent spend 90 percent (Dynan, Skinner and Zeldes 2004). Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 683 Since the start of the recovery from the Great Recession, productivity has risen at an annual average of 1.9 percent, while real wage compensation has grown by a paltry 0.2 percent per year. Practically all gains from economic growth have accrued to the owners of capital.3 Labor’s share of national income has fallen by 3.8 percent since the official end of the Great Recession (June 2009), while after-tax corporate profits have increased by 24 percent. Labor’s share of GDP is at a post-WWII low (55 percent), while the profit share is at a post-WWII high (11 percent). Given the caution and deleveraging provoked by the crisis, consumption cannot readily be pumped up by households saving less and taking on higher debt. And given the dearth of investment spending, and thus weak demand for labor, longer work weeks cannot be counted on to fuel additional consumption. Although profits have been robust, net investment that might generate employment has been weak due to anemic consumer demand. Since 1994, net investment as a share of GDP increased by 2.9 percent per year, but has only increased by 0.9 percent per year since the start of the recovery. Over the same period, total foreign direct investment by U.S. firms increased by 1.6 percent, but rose to 2.2 percent during the recovery. From 2007 to 2012, profits for domestic corporations grew by 35 percent, but their investment in plants and equipment grew by only 2.6 percent (Samuelson 2013, A17). What then, aside from investing abroad, has been done with these profits? Fueled by the Fed’s quantitative easing policies, funds have been flowing into asset markets and cash reserves. Dividend payments as a share of GDP have increased by 25 percent since the start of the recovery, and the number of share buybacks by firms, which increases stock prices, has tripled (Amenta 2013). Additionally, firms are opting to hoard cash as opposed to making new investments. U.S. firms have increased their cash reserves by approximately 25 percent since the start of the recovery, while the ratio of cash to net assets has increased by approximately 20 percent (Sánchez and Yurdagul 2013). While the economy was saved from more severely crashing during the first two years of the crisis by highly stimulative fiscal policy, once this threat dissipated, a loud chorus has successfully insisted on budget austerity, causing government spending to decline. Total federal expenditures as a share of GDP had risen by 27.4 percent during the recession, but have fallen by 10.1 percent since the start of the recovery. Since the official end of the recession in June 2009, the three main sources of economic growth — consumption, investment, and government spending — have been too weak to enable a recovery as robust as those following earlier recessions. The redistribution of income away from labor and toward the wealthy has, as noted earlier, dampened consumer demand. This, in turn, has reduced the incentive of firms to invest in real capital. Fiscal austerity means that government spending has been inadequate to counter the low levels of consumption and investment. Constrained private and public sector consumption has reduced net investment and increased cash hoarding by U.S. firms. Not only did an explosion in inequality set the 3 Capital is overwhelmingly owned by the rich. In 2007, the wealthiest 1.0 percent of Americans owned 49.3 percent of stocks and mutual funds, the richest 10 percent had 89.4 percent, leaving the bottom 90 percent with only 10.6 percent (Wolff 2010, 52, Table 9). 684 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti stage for the crisis of 2008, but that explosion continues unabated. Since the start of the recovery, Emmanuel Saez (2012) estimates that the top 1.0 percent of the income distribution captured 93 percent of all of the income gains during the first year of recovery from the Great Recession. The distribution of wealth, which accounts for assets and debt as well as income, has followed a similar trend between 2009 and 2011. The bottom 93 percent of households has seen its net wealth fall by 4.0 percent, while the top 7.0 percent of households have seen their net wealth rise by 28 percent (Fry and Taylor 2013). By constraining consumption, inequality and its continued rise handicap the recovery. The plight of the economy can be seen in the following: Since the start of the recovery, the economy has added an average of 117,000 jobs per month. At this pace, all the jobs lost during the recession will not be recovered until October 2014 — nearly seven years since the start of the Great Recession. Even if all nonfarm job vacancies were immediately filled by unemployed workers, it would still leave approximately eight million workers without a job. Such depressed conditions have unsurprisingly led to a vast pool of missing workers: Approximately 4.0 percent of the labor force has stopped looking for work due to weak job opportunities (Economic Policy Institute 2103). But the slow pace of recovery and massive scale of unemployment and shrinking labor force is only part of the story. Since the onset of the Great Recession, the labor market has dealt a series of harsh blows to the unemployed. Figure 2 shows the near tripling of the post-WWII average duration of unemployment. The share of unemployed workers who have been jobless for more than half a year, shown in Figure 3, has also tripled. This has led to record high levels of the cost of job loss, as workers can now expect to lose over 40 percent of their income during the year following job loss — approximately twice the historic average (Pacitti 2011). The tragedy of lost income is compounded by the fact that the longer workers are unemployed, the more their skills or human capital atrophy — a loss of a critically important store of personal wealth. Consequently, when they eventually find employment, they will be less skilled, and thus command lower salaries. Moreover, the current economic crisis is not just impacting unemployed workers, but also underemployed workers, or those with inadequate employment. According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics U-6 measure of labor underutilization, one out of every seven workers is underemployed as of December 2013. This measure includes unemployed and discouraged workers, but also involuntary part-time employees — those who wish to work full-time, but can only find part-time work. The number of involuntary part-time employees has nearly tripled since the beginning of the recession. However, these measures fail to capture one more form of underemployment: “mal-employment,” where employees are employed in positions that do not significantly make use of their skills. Neeta P. Fogg and Paul E. Harrington (2011) estimate that mal-employment rose from 25 percent in 2000 to 28 percent in 2010, with much of the gain affecting workers between the age of 20 and 24, whose malemployment rate was 39 percent. Surveys of workers, who graduated college during the Great Recession, show that only 40 percent have jobs that require a four-year Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 685 degree, and that 23 percent have jobs outside of their education specialty (Stone, van Horn and Zukin 2012). Moreover, underemployment is highly regressive in that it most affects marginalized populations: young workers, the least educated, and low income and minority groups (Sum and Khatiwada 2009, 2010, 2012). Figure 2. Average Unemployment Duration in Weeks, 1948–2013 Jan-12 Jan-08 Jan-04 Jan-00 Jan-96 Jan-92 Jan-88 Jan-84 Jan-80 Jan-76 Jan-72 Jan-68 Jan-64 Jan-60 Jan-56 Jan-52 Jan-48 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 Unemployment Duration Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics (1948–2013). Figure 3. Percent of Unemployed Workers Jobless for 27 Weeks or More, 1948–2013 50.0 45.0 40.0 35.0 30.0 25.0 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 Unemployed >27 weeks Source: Authors’ calculations from the Bureau of Labor Statistics (1948–2013). Jan-11 Jan-08 Jan-05 Jan-02 Jan-99 Jan-96 Jan-93 Jan-90 Jan-87 Jan-84 Jan-81 Jan-78 Jan-75 Jan-72 Jan-69 Jan-66 Jan-63 Jan-60 Jan-57 Jan-54 Jan-51 Jan-48 0.0 686 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti This massive underutilization of labor will depress rates of growth in human capital formation and incomes for the groups who need upward economic mobility the most. In addition to the economic costs, the social costs to the underemployed include insecurity, stress, lower self-esteem, alcohol abuse, and depression (Dooley and Prause 2004). It is not only workers that have been impacted by the Great Recession and slow recovery. Due to the severity of the current crisis, a large number of firms have been forced into bankruptcy. Between March 2008 and March 2010, corporate bankruptcies doubled, and have yet to return to their pre-recession levels (U.S. Federal Courts 2013). Emerging firms will generally deploy the most recent technological advances, often meaning that workers released by the defunct firms will not possess the skill mix needed by the new ones. Not only does this prolong their unemployment, but the enhanced demand for more highly skilled workers augments the polarization of the workforce, and generates greater long-term structural unemployment. Per-Anders Edin and Magnus Gustavsson (2008) estimate that each year of unemployment causes a five percentile move down the skill distribution. Henry Farber (2011) finds that workers who lost their jobs during the Great Recession and were reemployed received a real weekly wage in their subsequent job that was on average 17.5 percent lower than their pre-displacement earnings.4 This analysis includes all durations of unemployment, so the earnings losses for the long-term unemployed are probably much greater than Farber’s final estimate. The Superiority of Guaranteed Employment and Retraining Over Massive Government Spending Although massive government spending could conceivably bring the economy fully out of the Great Recession, it is far inferior to instituting a comprehensive program guaranteeing employment and the retraining necessary to enable workers to find employment in the regular economy for three principal reasons. First, as Hyman P. Minsky (1973) argued, full employment has historically been achieved through accelerated private investment, which is unsustainable because it creates financial instability, provoking recessions and mass unemployment. To engender full employment by stimulating investment, the government often gives preferential treatment to capital income, such as reduced capital gains taxes and accelerated depreciation allowances. This widens income distribution and the role of speculative finance, thereby increasing macroeconomic instability over time. A system of guaranteed employment, by contrast, would be able to sustain full employment, because speculative finance is not required to create the investment that traditionally generates full employment. The government directly creates jobs, hence 4 The difference between a five percentile fall in the skill distribution and a 17.5 percent decline in earnings can be accounted for due to the different scales, but also because the decline in earnings is due to both skill decay and shorter hours when reemployed (Farber 2011). Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 687 macroeconomic stability, thereby eliminating the need for preferential treatment of capital income and enabling a compression of income distribution. Second, government spending could only reduce unemployment to its so-called natural rate, or the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), below which inflation is believed to become a problem. At that point, monetary authorities can be expected to “take away the punchbowl,” ending the economic expansion that pulls workers into the active workforce.5 Thus, although government spending could substantially reduce unemployment, it could not eliminate it. The Congressional Budget Office (2013) estimates that the 2013 value of the NAIRU has temporarily risen from its long-term value of 5.5 to 6.0 percent, while Justin Weidner and John C. Williams (2011) estimate a rise to 6.7 percent. Thus, according to these estimates, to avoid inflationary pressures, 8.6 to 10.4 million workers must remain unemployed, sacrificed for the presumed good of everyone else. But, in fact, society would suffer the loss of their potential output, and the social wealth loss as skills or human capital depreciate, not to mention welfare costs and the severe social consequences of unemployment. A guaranteed employment program would make these sacrifices unnecessary since all willing workers would always be employed, and therefore all contributing to society’s wellbeing. Third, government spending alone would not address the increasingly severe problem of workers not being adequately prepared for an ever more technologically dynamic economy. As Frank Levy and Richard J. Murnane claim in a recent study prepared for the think tank Third Way, “[f]or the foreseeable future, the challenge of ‘cybernation’ is not mass unemployment but the need to educate many more young people for the jobs computers cannot do” (cited in Tankersley 2013, A9). A program to guarantee employment and any necessary training would eliminate — or at least greatly mitigate — long-term structural unemployment, the problem of the skills firms demand not being matched by the skills workers can supply.6 Since the industrial revolution, as production processes became increasingly sophisticated, government-provided public education prepared workers for more complex workplaces.7 However, since the 1970s, education — especially for the less 5 As Rudi Dornbusch (2002) famously put it, “[n]one of the postwar expansions died of old age, they were all murdered by the Fed” (cited in “Of Shocks and Horrors”). However, the 2001 and 2007 recessions were not caused by Fed tightening, but rather by the popping of asset bubbles. 6 There is considerable debate surrounding the role of structural unemployment in the current crisis. Some argue that the unemployment problem is largely structural, and therefore that fiscal and monetary policies are incapable of addressing it in the short run (Brooks 2010; Kocherlakota 2010; Rajan 2010). Others appeal to evidence suggesting that the current elevated unemployment rate is almost entirely cyclical, and thus could be reduced using traditional expansionary policy (Chinn, Ferrara and Mignon 2013; Lazear and Spletzer 2012; Valletta and Kuang 2010). The argument we set forth in this article is that an ELR program with a training component could alleviate short-term unemployment problems, whether they be cyclical or structural. Moreover, from a long-term perspective, it will mitigate the effects of rapid technological change, human capital depreciation, and an inadequate educational system that creates the conditions for structural unemployment. 7 As Joel Mokyr notes, “the Industrial Revolution and the subsequent technological developments after 1760 led to many production processes that required a level of competence that was beyond the capability of the household” (2002, 140). 688 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti privileged — has not kept pace with the more sophisticated needs of the economy.8 The plight of the less privileged can be seen in the fact that the educational achievement gap between children from rich and poor families is roughly 30 to 40 percent greater for those born in 2001 than those born in the mid-1970s, and is now more than twice as large as the black-white achievement gap (Reardon 2011). The Education Trust reports that 23 percent of high school graduates do not score high enough on the enlistment test to be accepted by any branch of the military (Washington Post 2010, A2). This strongly suggests that the formal education which society provides to many of its future workers is not adequate for the job demands created by more rapid technological change. Further, in an ever-more-complex economy, the training most receive when young is not adequate for their full work lives. More and more will need continual retraining. While much of this training is on-the-job, some workers will lose their jobs and, for lack of necessary skills, not find comparable new ones. Although publicly provided formal schooling might provide some of the necessary reskilling, some workers who perform poorly in school settings learn well when training is part of their jobs.9 The traditional model — that future workers receive their education when young and that any future reskilling occurs on the job — no longer suffices in a work world where skills are continually becoming antiquated. To maintain skills and full employment in increasingly sophisticated workplaces, a new model is needed. This model should provide those who do poorly in school with needed skills, while continually retraining those who become and remain unemployed because of obsolete skills. Thus, it is in the best interest not only of workers, but of society generally, that a critical component of a new model be a government-employer-of-last-resort program. The program will not only insure continuous employment, but also the necessary skills, so that all workers may successfully enter and re-enter the regular labor market. 8 In spite of an economy that has become enormously more complex over the past four decades, Michael Alison Chandler points out that, “[n]ationally, the [SAT] reading score for the Class of 2011, including public- and private-school students, was 997, down … 33 points from 1972, [while] the average math score was 514, … up five from 1972” (2011, A1). International comparisons confirm this educational failure. Among 25 to 34 year-olds with university degrees, the US had sunk to 12th place in 2010. The World Economic Forum ranked the US 52nd among 139 nations in the quality of its university math and science instruction in 2010. Almost half of all science graduates in the US are foreigners. Further evidence of the failure of the American educational system to adequately produce the skills necessary for the more dynamic economy is the pressure employers are putting on Congress to exceptionally permit more highly skilled workers into the US. To the extent their petition is successful, demands for strengthening education in the US will be attenuated. 9 This is well supported by the success of the apprentice programs of Germany, Austria, and Switzerland, which provide workers, who accept lower wages, two to three years of firm-funded on-the-job training, in addition to education provided by the state (Dustman and Sconberg 2012). These programs have been successful at smoothing the transition between apprenticeships and employment by equilibrating the skills demanded to the skills being supplied (Parey 2009; Ryan 2001). Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 689 How Government Guaranteed Employment and Retraining Would Work Under such a program, employment could be guaranteed to everyone willing and able to work (zero involuntary unemployment) by making government the employer of last resort (ELR). In recent years, a number of economists have advocated just this (Attali and Champain 2005; Forstater 1998, 2006; Harvey 1989; Kaboub 2012; Mitchell and Wray 2005; Wisman 2010, 2013a; Wisman and Reksten 2013; Wray 1998a, 1998b, 1999, 2007). An ELR program might work as follows: Federal funds would be given to local governments which would then distribute resources as needed to community employment centers, so that employment opportunities could be tailored to meet local needs (Kaboub 2012). Employment is then offered to anyone who seeks work, but would otherwise be without a job.10 Workers are “[hired] off the bottom” (Mitchell and Wray 2005, 236), and the offered wage serves as a price floor — a living minimum wage.11 Upon losing a job, unemployment insurance could cover a set number of weeks for the individual’s job search, at the end of which the individual may join the ELR program should a job not have been located. This program could also be crafted to provide part-time work for those only able to find part-time work in the private sector, or who can only work part time due to family responsibilities. No other form of public support need be available to unemployed, but able-bodied workers. Thus, those choosing to not accept such employment would be voluntarily unemployed, and welfare could be restricted to those physically or mentally unable to work. Entering into the ELR program would entail working in a government-created or approved job, and/or receiving training. The goal would be to keep the entire workforce at work, or in training, and to move workers into the regular economy as quickly as possible. A job placement component, working in conjunction with private employers, could facilitate re-entry into the regular labor market. The goal would be that government employment would only be temporary, lasting until workers become capable of rejoining the regular labor force. The government catches them as they lose jobs and releases them as soon as possible. An ELR program would face the challenge of employing workers in domains that do not directly compete with private or current public sector jobs. Domains might include programs for assisting the elderly population, tutoring less-privileged children, daycare, and improving the quality of the public space by providing flowers, benches, statuary, and fountains along streets and in parks.12 The American Society of 10 Or, in technical terms, the program would operate so as to provide an infinitely wage-elastic demand for labor. The price of labor in the program would be set independently of market conditions, absorbing all redundant labor at that price. That is, the market sets the quantity, but not the price. 11 An ELR could end-run the claim that the minimum wage cannot be raised without causing further unemployment. Those losing jobs as the living wage is slowly lifted would fall back into the ELR sector where training would raise their skill level and productivity, making the higher wages profitable for their future employers. 12 Wray offers an extensive list of potential ELR jobs (1997, 15-16). He also suggests that an ELR program might fund “qualifying non-governmental non-profit organizations, such as Americorps, VISTA, 690 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti Civil Engineers (2013) gave the United States a D+ grade for the current state of its infrastructure. Thus, major projects — such as burying utility cables; creating seawalls in flood-prone areas; providing public broadband internet access to all areas of the country, including rural ones; road and bridge repairs; improved public transportation; and high-speed rail in population-dense areas — offer productive and socially useful avenues for employment. But one of the most promising uses of ELR workers would be to employ them in “green jobs,” such as alternative energy manufacturing, which provide the tools and incentives to reduce the likelihood that the human species commits ecocide (Forstater 2006). Although at the outset such a program might be inefficient due to frictional adjustments and the time needed for skill acquisition, its efficiency should improve in the nature and quality of work performed, in its training component, the management of resources, and in its ability to help participants locate employment.13 An ELR program might come to be seen as is the public school system — a necessary social institution for economic dynamism and fairness. An ELR program would be countercyclical because it absorbs into a buffer stock those who are laid off from the private sector during a downturn, and would serve as the ultimate automatic stabilizer. The government would buy excess labor supply as a buffer stock and release it as the demand for labor in the private sector increases. Unemployment insurance currently provides this sort of buffer stock of workers, but with the disadvantages of incentive problems, lower incomes, and eroding human capital. Moreover, when the private sector expands, it can hire from the buffer stock of workers with greater confidence that they possess the appropriate work habits and skills. The reserve army of the unemployed is replaced by a disciplined and better skilled reserve army of ELR employees. An ELR approach differs radically from the strategy of stimulating aggregate demand to create jobs. In an aggregate demand approach, reaching full employment is sought indirectly through stimulative fiscal and monetary policy, although, as noted earlier, monetary authorities bring expansions to an end well before actual full employment is achieved in order to avoid excess inflationary pressures. A guaranteed employment program, by contrast, would go directly to the problem by providing all willing and able unemployed workers with a job. Whereas managing aggregate demand to increase employment is a “trickle-down” approach, an ELR is a “bubbleup” approach, with jobs created for workers at the bottom (Wray 2007, 17). Full employment would exist regardless of the level of aggregate demand, although with full employment aggregate demand would remain robust. It is a supply-side as opposed to a demand-side solution to the problem of unemployment. the Student Community Service Program, the National Senior Service Corps, the Peace Corps, the National Health Service Corps, school districts, and Meals on Wheels” (2007, 11). 13 Although job retraining programs in developed economies have produced mixed results, none have been as comprehensive as what we advocate here. Studies reveal that how retraining programs are structured is critical in determining effectiveness (Heckman, LaLonde and Smith 1999). Furthermore, training is only effective when there are existing jobs that require workers. An ELR would provide both the training and the jobs. Moreover, a better trained workforce would facilitate the generation of firms that could thrive were the properly skilled workers available. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 691 Finally, an ELR program could be decentralized, so as to better meet local needs. For instance, states could receive ELR budgets from the federal government proportional to their rates of unemployment (Wray 1999, 485). If the program were to be administered by states, or smaller political jurisdictions, then the ELR wage could be set in terms of the local cost of living, and/or it could be set lower the higher the percent of the local labor force absorbed into the program, so as to preserve incentives for mobility. The Cost of Government Guaranteed Employment and Retraining, and the Cost of Unemployment Several economists have estimated the likely cost of an ELR program (Attali and Champain 2005; Darity 2010; Gordon 1997; Kaboub 2012; Wray 1997, 1998, 2011). Fadhel Kaboub’s (2012, 109) extensive study estimates that a comprehensive and very generous ELR program, with a three-tier skill-based wage scale, “could employ 23.4 million people for less than $600 billion annually, or less than 4% of GDP, with the added benefit of increasing GDP by nearly one trillion dollars per year.”14 Kaboub’s estimates correspond to the costs estimated by Jacques Attali and Vincent Champain for France (2005, 6-7). William Darity, Jr., estimates that to employ fifteen million unemployed workers at a mean salary of $40,000 plus $10,000 in benefits would cost $750 billion, thus less “than the $1.3 trillion handout initially given to the investment banking community” at the outset of the current crisis (2010, 180). Michael Murray (2012) estimates that, using a standard macroeconomic model, an ELR implemented today could be budget neutral — neither increasing nor decreasing the deficit — because the growth-inducing effects and tax increases would offset the operating costs. Although a training component for such a program would considerably increase costs in the short run, it would more than pay for itself with large, lasting benefits such as those listed above. Although the estimates given above provide a rough sense of an ELR’s cost, forecasting the full long run costs and benefits of an ELR program, especially one with a sophisticated reskilling component, would be difficult and lies beyond the scope of this paper. It would entail estimating the value produced by ELR workers, the enhanced productivity of ELR-trained workers when they enter the regular labor force, the resulting increase in tax revenues, and the decrease in social costs currently resulting from unemployment. Unemployment benefits, beyond a brief few weeks following job loss to enable a new job search, would disappear and other incomesupport program costs would dramatically decline. Unemployment-generated health costs borne by Medicaid would be practically eliminated. For the unemployed, who are absorbed into an ELR, there are significant nonpecuniary costs that would be eliminated. It has been estimated that these costs drastically outweigh the monetary and consumption costs of not having a job 14 Kaboub’s (2012) hourly wage scale would be $21 for skilled-, $18 for semi-skilled-, and $15 for unskilled workers, all with a $10,000 annual benefits package. These figures could be adjusted to suit local costs of living and community needs. 692 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti (Winkelmann and Winkelmann 1998, 1). Daniel Sullivan and Till von Wachter (2009) find evidence of higher mortality rates for workers who experience job loss, and estimate that for workers displaced at age forty, life expectancy falls by 1-1.5 years. Job loss also results in poorer health outcomes: elevated stress and anxiety, such as heart attacks and strokes (Burgard, Brand and House 2007); higher divorce rates (Charles and Stephens 2004); loss of social standing, self-esteem, and contact with friends and family (Taylor et al. 2010); and lower levels of emotional wellbeing, such as worry, sadness, and stress (Krueger and Mueller 2011; Marlar 2010).15 Many of the personal costs of unemployment also have a public dimension. Studies have found a correlation between increased unemployment and increased criminal activity. Jeff Grogger (1998) as well as Eric D. Gould, Bruce Weinberg, and David B. Mustard (2002) find that youth criminal activity positively correlates with the unemployment rate. Unemployment fuels prejudice against minorities and immigrants (Sen 1997). Adolescents with unemployed parents do less well in school, and those who attempt suicide are more likely to have an unemployed father (Storm 2003, 401). There is the possibility that an ELR program would initially be inflationary, especially with ELR wages set above minimum wages. However, William Mitchell and L. Randall Wray (2005) and L. Randall Wray (1998) conclude that after its introduction, it would be anti-inflationary, or at worst, non-inflationary. But would not guaranteed employment embolden workers to demand higher wages? Wray (2007, 18) counters this possibility by noting that, while workers have the alternative of ELR jobs, employers have the opportunity of hiring from the ELR pool. Thus if the wage demands of workers in the private sector exceed by too great a margin the employer’s calculation of their productivity, the alternative is to obtain ELR workers at a mark-up over the ELR wage. This will help to offset any wage pressures caused by elimination of the fear of unemployment. Moreover, workers within the program would presumably come to possess the skills needed in the private sector, boosting productivity, and thus applying downward pressure on prices. Worker productivity might also be enhanced if increased job turnover improved job fit. Upward wage pressures might be lessened in an inflationary period as employers could readily hire workers from the buffer stock, who are willing to work, disciplined, and well-trained, hence causing a race to the top in 15 In a description of European males during the 1930s, Peter Temin (2008, 681) has vividly captured the debilitation of unemployment: Unemployed men in the European Great Depression were exceedingly idle; an increase of apathy reduced all forms of recreational activity. Men passed their time doing essentially nothing; when asked, they could not even recall what they had done during the day. They sat around the house, went for walks, or played cards and chess. Most men went to bed early; there simply was no reason to stay awake. They contributed less to the running of the household than before, sometimes not even turning up on time for meals. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 693 recruitment and providing incentives for workers to supply high levels of on-the-job effort. In an expansion, as workers are pulled from the buffer stock into regular employment, ELR spending would decrease, countering some of the inflationary pressures of the expansion. That is, even in an expansion, labor markets would be relatively loose. Wray (1998, 544) notes that “[f]urther, reduction or elimination of employment taxes related to the unemployment insurance program will also attenuate pressure on prices, as will reduction of private and social costs of unemployment (e.g., reduction of crime will lower business costs).” Mitchell and Wray (2005, 4) also speculate that the anti-inflationary character of ELR might end the need for restrictive monetary policy to address inflationary pressures. After its introduction, no further inflationary pressure should result, and the natural rate of unemployment, or NAIRU, would become zero. Further Benefits of Guaranteed Employment There are significant benefits, in addition to full employment, that would result from an ELR program. First, guaranteed employment would enhance productivity by providing not only jobs, but also training to match the skills needed by employers. It would reduce structural unemployment resulting from the skills of unemployed workers not matching those needed by employers. This skill mismatch is likely to become a growing problem as the pace of technological change quickens and globalization expands (Wisman and Reksten 2013). Also, by removing the threat of unemployment, workers might be less reluctant to leave jobs, for which their skill mix is ill-suited to search for a better fit. Although this could increase turnover rates, and thus short-run adjustment costs, it would provide productivity gains in the long run as job fit would improve. Second, guaranteed employment and retraining would eliminate bias associated with hiring the long-term unemployed, ending the problem of “duration dependence,” which appears when rising periods of unemployment beget further increases in unemployment duration due to negative signals and depreciated human capital (Kroft, Lange and Notowidigo 2012). William Dickens and Rand Ghayad (2013) have hypothesized that the shifting outward since 2008 of the Beveridge curve — the empirical relationship between unemployment and vacancies — may be due to the fact that the long-term unemployed are viewed by employers as damaged goods. Third, the training component of an ELR would especially improve the productivity and wages of workers at the lower end of the job spectrum who — although employed most of the time — suffer from involuntary part-time employment, unstable and insecure jobs, frequent interludes of unemployment, underemployment, little or no skill accumulation, and lasting earnings losses (Couch and Placzek 2010; Farber 2008, 2011; Stevens 1997). Fourth, an ELR would ultimately eliminate the need for minimum wage legislation. To attract workers, private employers would have to pay a wage equal to or higher than that paid by the government program. Additionally, an ELR would eliminate the need for unemployment insurance, and for the work-able, nutrition assistance, and other stigma-inducing and degrading income-support programs. 694 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti Fifth, it would guarantee full employment, with the least disruption to markets and macroeconomic stability (Minsky 1973; Wray 2007). The need for speculative financial markets to provide capital for private investment to generate full employment would be sharply reduced, attenuating swings in the business cycle. Rather than fighting the intractable and contrary twin curses of unemployment and inflation, the focus of economic policy would be maintaining price stability. Sixth, an ELR would provide a socially fair mechanism to offset the costs imposed by the secular shift toward deindustrialization and service production: namely, longer recovery times from recessions and the slow employment growth which accompanies it (Olney and Pacitti 2013), in addition to mitigating the damaging economic effects of a possible stationary state (Durand and Lege 2012, 2013). Seventh, as William S. Vickrey (1992, 342) points out, “[u]nder conditions of full employment, trade-balance deficits become not a matter of exporting jobs, but of importing capital.” Thus, domestic demand would be stimulated through open economy channels. Eighth, guaranteeing employment to all able-bodied workers would significantly reduce inequality, especially if its pay were set to provide a living wage and if the preferential treatment of capital income were eliminated, making the tax and transfer payment system more progressive (Minsky 1973).16 The long-sought goal of eliminating poverty within a capitalist system for those able and willing to work would at last be realized. An ELR would also reduce inequality by augmenting the human capital of the least privileged — those whom current social conditions and the education system cheat out of an adequate preparation for work life. Guaranteeing employment and adequate skills to enter the regular labor market could be expected to provide cumulative benefits as poverty and dysfunctional neighborhoods disappear. Children would grow up in families where parental employment offers social and personal respect, and in neighborhoods where the able are gainfully employed. Additionally, ELR jobs that provide needed resources to underserved communities could revitalize previously neglected areas and increase economic mobility. Forty percent of individuals born into the bottom quintile of the income distribution remain there as adults, and 70 percent remain below the middle quintile, with African Americans in particular less likely to surpass their parents’ income (Urhan et al. 2012). This constraint in opportunity results from a lack of access to the educational, economic, social, and cultural resources needed for upward mobility. Attempts to improve schools for the less privileged have met with limited success, due in large part to the high unemployment and social dysfunction in the neighborhoods in which these schools are located.17 Guaranteeing employment would promise to 16 Robert Gordon has identified six “headwinds” that he believes will slow or even end U.S. economic growth. Inadequate education is one, but “the most important quantitatively in holding down the growth of our future income is rising inequality” (2012, 17). 17 Rising inequality has also played a critical role in its influence on public expenditures for public goods, such as schools, a dynamic addressed by Christopher Lasch in his last major work, The Revolt of the Elites (1996). He noted that as economic elites take an ever-greater share of income and wealth, they tend to Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 695 dramatically improve the quality of these neighborhoods and their schools. The training component of an ELR would catch those whom schools fail, providing them with the human capital necessary for employment, and enable the social and selfrespect that accompanies having a job. Until recent decades, the United States was widely known as the land of exceptional opportunity, holding out the potential for anyone to rise to the very top. Among the factors underlying this social mobility were the lack of defined classes, less inequality, abundant land in the nation’s early history, and the world’s best education system between the 1830s and 1970s. Rising inequality has eroded that legacy, and the potential for vertical mobility is now greater in many other wealthy societies. A number of studies have found upward mobility between generations to be lower in the US than in other countries, such as Canada, Sweden, Germany, Spain, Denmark, Austria, Norway, Finland, and France (D’Addio 2007; Hertz 2007; Mazumder 2005; Mishel, Bernstein and Allegretto 2007; Solon 1992). An ELR with a training component would insure that everyone can accumulate the human capital with which to have a fair chance of advancing. Reduced inequality would lower the likelihood of economic crises and accelerate recoveries from downturns, as discussed above, and more generally would provide a strong base for adequate aggregate demand and robust economic performance.18 Having assessed a massive number of studies, Richard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett (2009) find that more unequal societies score lower on practically every measure of quality of life. A ninth benefit is that guaranteeing employment would eliminate the pressure for economic growth at practically any cost, which has severely handicapped the struggle to avoid ecological catastrophe. There is a growing consensus among scientists that human activity is dramatically changing the environment, with severe future consequences if appropriate action is not taken. And the urgency of such action is becoming increasingly apparent. As reported by Frances Kissling and Peter Singer (2012, B3), “many climate experts suggest that we have less than two decades before we reach a point of no return — after that, nothing we can do will prevent climate changes from spiraling into disaster.” This threat is made more acute by the fact that the current crisis has decreased the focus on environment issues, as politicians seek growth at practically any cost to lower unemployment (Eilperin and Craighill 2012, A3). isolate themselves in social enclaves, such as gated communities, exclusive clubs, and private schools. They tend to work in jobs, live in neighborhoods, and move in circles where they literally do not see those struggling to stay on their feet. Because of elites’ disproportionate political power, this withdrawal from the wider society and from direct contact with the concerns of other citizens erodes support for public services on which those further down the economic ladder depend — public schools, parks, transportation, public safety, and a clean environment. As Secretary of Labor during the Clinton Administration, Robert Reich, has put it, “members see no reason why they should pay to support families outside the gates when members are getting everything they need inside” (2001, 199). 18 The so-called “Golden Age of American Capitalism” — the thirty years following WWII — came with what Arthur Burns termed a “revolutionary leveling” (cited in Williamson 1991, 11), and what Claudia Goldin and Robert Margo (1992) dubbed the “Great Compression” in the wage distribution. Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti 696 The output of today’s world economy is valued at $65 trillion, and over the next two decades, it is expected to double. Joel E. Cohen (2012. 47) reports that, whereas global electricity consumption has doubled since 1980, it is expected to double again by 2030, placing additional enormous strains on the environment. The oceans — the “lungs of the earth” — are 30 percent more acidic today than the preindustrial level, and their acidity is projected to double by the end of the century, posing a severe threat to the sea food web. Furthermore, “the OECD projected that, by 2050, without more effective energy policies fossil fuels will supply 85 percent of energy demand, thus implying a 50 percent increase in greenhouse gas emissions and worsening urban air pollution “(2012, 47). It was inevitable that humanity would reach a point where its continued activities would pose a severe challenge to the earth’s environment. Until recent centuries, the human population was small enough and its technology not sufficiently developed that collective human activity could upset global equilibria. It is true that earlier human societies created local ecological devastation, such as deforestation, severe soil erosion, and polluted waterways. They even did so to the point of causing their civilizations to collapse (Diamond 2005). However, their ecologically harmful actions were never before on a sufficient scale to threaten the ecology of the whole earth, and thus threaten humanity’s very future. But this threat’s inevitability is shown by the numbers. Cohen reveals that “since 1700 human numbers have grown elevenfold, soon to be twelvefold, while economic activity per person has grown twelvefold” (2012, 49). The cumulative impact on the environment of this exploded population in possession of ever more powerful technologies has been such that, today, the threat of ecological devastation is no longer in question among the overwhelming majority of scientists in all fields of ecology. This challenge is compounded by the fact that in democracies political parties across the spectrum, striving to hold onto or acquire office, struggle to convince the electorate that their advocated policies hold the greatest promise of stimulating economic growth and reducing unemployment. The continuing contemporary crisis has heightened the pressure to be convincing, and when in power, to show results.19 However, this pursuit of employment creation through growth at practically any cost means that the struggle to successfully address what arguably is humanity’s greatest struggle — avoiding ecological devastation — is seriously compromised. Guaranteeing employment and, where necessary, reskilling all capable of work, would sidestep this problem. Economic growth would no longer be necessary to generate employment. This does not mean that growth would cease. Indeed, productively employing all able workers and providing them with appropriate skills would promise 19 The belief that economic growth can decrease unemployment is, of course, true in the short run. However, although more robust growth typically lowers unemployment, it is never a permanent decline. Thus, in spite of decades of growth, unemployment levels have not trended downward. For instance, in spite of a more than doubling of economic output in the post-WWII US, between 1948 and 1976, the average unemployment rate was 5.0 percent, and between 1977 and 2013, it averaged 6.5 percent. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 697 to enhance the potential for growth. But society would be free to pursue “smart” growth — an ecologically benign growth that reverses ecological damage.20 The tenth benefit of guaranteeing employment and retraining is that it could serve as the foundation of a new moral social contract. Despite theoretical discord among economists on the macroeconomic policy front, a short-run tradeoff between unemployment and inflation is generally assumed. Whatever the measures taken to stimulate growth, and thereby generate employment, there is an underlying assumption that at some point — the natural rate of unemployment, “one of the most vicious euphemisms ever coined” (Vickrey 1992, 341) — lower unemployment threatens rising inflation. As William S. Vickrey notes, “under current practices the only way in which fiscal and monetary authorities can restrain inflation is by creating unemployment” (1992, 341), and it should be added, by increasing employment insecurity through the use of part-time workers (Pacitti 2014). Stock prices also tend to fall when unemployment dips dangerously low, presumably due to expectations that very low unemployment may provoke wage inflation, generalized price inflation, and higher interest rates (Roubini 2013). Thus, some level of unemployment appears necessary for the wellbeing of capital markets. Unemployed and part-time workers who desire full-time positions — generally society’s least privileged (Darity 1999) — are held hostage to the inflation monster. As Wray and Forstater (2004) put it, “the job of fighting inflation through unemployment is horribly disproportionately shared and is mostly put on the backs of those who have no market power to cause wage inflation in the first place” (262). For most of society to profit from price stability, a minority — the least privileged — are condemned to be unemployed, thus sacrificed for the good of the whole.21 Guaranteeing employment, and providing the training necessary for all workers to participate in the economy, would end this unfair treatment of society’s least privileged by establishing a new social contract. Yet, it would not be a radically new one. Government has participated in opening opportunity throughout U.S. history, especially by providing access to land and the education necessary for economic success. Final Reflections If guaranteeing employment and reskilling are such good ideas, why have they not always been more central to politicians whose success in gaining office and holding 20 There is a further dynamic by which guaranteed employment and retraining would make the environmental challenge less intractable. By reducing inequality, it would reduce the intense status competition in consumption that higher inequality fuels (Wisman 2011). 21 The social conditions and social choice that condemn some to unemployment has a parallel in Shirley Jackson’s classic and macabre short story, “The Lottery.” It is the story of an annual ceremony at which a town’s citizens draw lots, and then the “winner” is stoned to death. Presumably this is natural and good, in the interest of the broader community. As old man Warner puts it: “Lottery in June, corn be heavy soon.” The difference is that in Shirley Jackson’s town lottery, all citizens had equal chances of winning, whereas in the job lottery the chances — as determined by social background, race, and gender — vary greatly. 698 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti onto it has depended upon offering a convincing program to reduce unemployment? One possibility is that in earlier instances in which governments provided jobs for the destitute, it occurred too frequently in “the jail-like workhouse, [that] forcibly separated husbands, wives and children in order to punish the poor for their destitution, and discourage them from the dangerous temptation of procreating further paupers” (Hobsbawm 1968, 69-70). Moreover, given the lamentable character of so much work during earlier capitalism, perhaps it was not readily conceivable that the state could guarantee work which was anything but dehumanizing. An alternative explanation is that an ELR would increase the bargaining power of labor at the expense of capital, reducing the ability of employers to discipline their labor force, with the threat of unemployment (Kalecki 1943). A small elite that overwhelmingly owns capital exerts enormous political power, and thus the ability to steer ideology away from a comprehensive employment guarantee. Nevertheless, there was a push for guaranteed employment in the US during the trying period of the 1930s which resulted in three job creation programs employing 1.4-4.4 million people each month (Rose 2013, 155). There was also an unsuccessful attempt to make “Employment Assurance” a part of the Social Security Act. What is seldom realized is that during WWII the U.S. government instituted an ELR, albeit without this intention, when twelve million men and women — approximately 18 percent of the labor force — were directly employed. In 1943, a “New Bill of Rights” was proposed, but not adopted, that would have entailed the “formal acceptance by the Federal Government of responsibility for insuring jobs at decent pay to all those able to work regardless of whether or not they can pass a means test” (cited in Rose 2013, 170, emphasis in original). In his 1944 State of the Union address, President Roosevelt advocated an “economic bill of rights” that would include the “right to a useful and remunerative job” and the “right to earn enough to provide adequate food and clothing, and recreation” (cited in Rose 2013, 170). The original draft of the Full Employment bill of 1945 affirmed that “all Americans able to work and seeking work have the right to useful, remunerative, regular, and full-time employment” (cited in Rose 2013, 170), which — had it been retained — would have obliged the federal government to guarantee employment. The Humphrey-Hawkins Full Employment Act of 1978 was the last attempt to strengthen the government’s commitment to full employment, but it came forth in a political climate that was rapidly turning against labor’s interests. It came at the closure of the “Great Compression” (Goldin and Margo 1992), during which labor had made historically unprecedented gains as inequality decreased. Stagflation in the 1970s delegitimized Keynesian economics. Chicago School economist John Cochrane claimed that, “[w]hen inflation came in the nineteenseventies, that was a major failure of Keynesian economics” (cited in Cassidy 2010, 31). As early as 1980, Robert E. Lucas (1980, 19) wrote that, “[a]t research seminars, people don’t take Keynesian theorizing seriously anymore; the audience starts to whisper and giggle to one another.” This set the stage for a strong rejection of government intervention in the economy, motivated by a strong backlash to the liberal agenda. As Michael Perelman (2007, 32) notes, “the political climate during Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 699 the Nixon administration terrified many conservatives, who worried about the prospect of a radical takeover of the state and the end of capitalism, as they knew it.” Attention shifted, as illustrated by the Laffer curve, to the alleged growthdepressing high taxes, especially on the rich, that were claimed to reduce entrepreneurial energies and incentives to save and invest, resulting in stagnation and anemic tax revenues. Welfare, union power, and labor legislation were claimed to have sapped work incentives. As this understanding of the economy became more entrenched, the push for directly assuring workers jobs was abandoned and forgotten not only by policymakers, but also by almost all modern macroeconomists. An elite had recaptured the political ideology and the political process (Hacker and Pierson 2010; Wisman 2013c).22 Milton Friedman claimed that “only a crisis — actual or perceived — produces real change” (1982, ix). In keeping with Friedman’s hypothesis, the reversal of the gains labor had made since the 1930s came during a period of crisis — the stagflation of the 1970s. Today, the U.S. economy again finds itself in a prolonged crisis. Might the times again be ripe for “real change”: change that brings this crisis to an end, prepares the workforce for an ever more technologically dynamic future, makes the ecological challenge less intractable, ends poverty and welfare, and restores a high level of social mobility to America? Moreover, an ELR with a training component might find wide support across the political spectrum23 since it would privilege work — the ever-present ethic in the American experience that everyone should contribute productively to society — while ending welfare for those able to work. If implemented, such a program would not only dynamize, but also humanize American capitalism. A final reflection is that there is something morally amiss in a rich economy which leaves a portion of its workforce unemployed and without adequate skills to find employment. Unemployment is both the largest market and political failure. And, no matter the unemployment rate, it is morally wrong for an overwhelming majority of the population to condemn a portion of society — the least privileged — to a life of unemployment and underemployment. Economic, social, and emotional wellbeing is tied to having a job (Wisman 2010). The personal costs that these unfortunates must suffer are far too high. Avner Offer (2007, 7) reports that “[t]he strongest determinant of low life satisfaction is absence of social connection, particularly unemployment and separation.” Professor of psychiatry James Gilligan (2011) claims that the inability to find a job is the foremost driver of shame and worthlessness. To condemn a portion of the population — even if only a small 22 The political victory of the elite was abetted by the rapid rise of the importance of money in political campaigns. For instance, the number of firms with registered lobbyists increased from 175 in 1971 to almost 15,000 in 2007 — an increase of over 8,000 percent. Between 1974 and 2009, the total number of corporate political action committees increased sixteen-fold, from 89 to 1,598 (Wisman and Pacitti 2012). Research reveals that expenditures on creating and disseminating ideology yield high returns (Glaeser 2006). 23 In the US, job training has bipartisan support. Retraining programs were supported by Republican Presidential candidates, Mitt Romney and Newt Gingrich. Even the ultra-conservative Paul Ryan has claimed that “equipping workers with the skills and tools they need is a proper role for the federal government to assist with” (reported by Goldstein 2012, B3). 700 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti percentage — to remain unemployed is morally wrong. It sacrifices those who are generally the poorest to what is perceived, mistakenly, to be in the best interests of society. Equality of opportunity, just outcomes, and ecological survival constitute a moral, social, and economic imperative to guarantee employment and retraining for the full workforce. References Alvaredo, Facundo, Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez. “The Top 1 Percent in International and Historical Perspective.” Working Paper No. 19075. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2013. Amenta, Michael. “Buyback Quarterly.” Factset, June 19, 2013. Available at www. factset.com/websitefiles/ PDFs/buyback/buyback_6.19.13. Accessed July 8, 2013. American Society of Civil Engineers. “2013 Report Card for America’s Infrastructure.” 2013. Available at www.infrastructurereportcard.org/. Accessed April 11, 2014. Attali, Jacques and Vincent Champain. Changer le paradigme pour supprimer le chômage. Paris: Foundation Jean-Juares, November, 2005. Available at www.metiseurope.eu/content/pdf/n9/6_attali.pdf. Accessed April 11, 2014. Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1948–2013. Available at www.bls.gov/home.htm. Accessed April 11, 2014. ———. 2007–2013. Available at www.bls.gov/home.htm. Accessed April 11, 2014. Brooks, David. “The Genteel Nation.” New York Times, September 9, 2010. Available at www.nytimes.com/2010/09/10/opinion/10brooks.html?_r=0. Accessed April 11, 2014. Burgard, Sarah A., Jennie E. Brand and James S. House. “Toward a Better Estimation of the Effect of Job Loss on Health.” Journal of Health and Social Behavior 48, 4 (2007): 369-384. Cassidy, John. “Letter from Chicago: After the Blowup.” The New Yorker, January 11, 2010, pp. 28-33. Chandler, Michael Alison. “SAT Reading Scores Hit Lowest Point in Decades.” Washington Post, September 11, 2011, p. A1. Charles, Kerwin Kofi and Melvin Stephens. “Disability, Job Displacement and Divorce.” Journal of Labor Economics 22, 2 (2004): 489-522. Chinn, Menzie D., Laurent Ferrara and Valérie Mignon. “Post-Recession U.S. Employment Through the Lens of a Non-Linear Okun’s Law.” Working Paper 19047. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2013. Cohen, Joel E. “What Will It Take to Save the Earth?” The New York Review, April 26, 2012, pp. 47-49. Colander, David. “A Summary of the Structural Stagnation Hypothesis.” Modern Economics Blog, April 29, 2013. Available at http://modernecon.org/ structuralstagnationsummary/. Accessed April 11, 2014. Congressional Budget Office. “Estimates of Potential GDP and the Related Unemployment Rate, January 1991 to February 2013.” 2013. Available at www.cbo.gov/ sites/default/files/cbofiles/attachments/ EstimatesPotentiaGDPunemployment_0.xls Accessed July 10, 2013. Couch, K.A. and D.W. Placzek. “Earnings Losses of Displaced Workers Revisited.” American Economic Review 100, 1 (2010): 572-589. D’Addio, Anna Cristina. “International Transmission of Disadvantage: Mobility or Immobility across Generations? A Review of the Evidence for OECD Countries.” OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Paper No. 52. Paris, 2007. Darity, William, Jr. “Who Loses from Unemployment.” Journal of Economic Issues 33, 2 (1999): 491-496. ———. “A Direct Route to Full Employment.” Review of Black Political Economy 37 (2010): 179-181. Darity, William, Jr. and Arthur Goldsmith. “Unemployment, Social Psychology, and Unemployment Hysteresis.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 16 (Fall 1993): 55-73. Diamond, Jared. Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Succeed. New York: Viking, 2005. Dickens, William and Rand Ghayad. “It’s Not a Skill Mismatch: Disaggregate Evidence on the US Unemployment-Vacancy Relationship.” Economists’ View, January 5, 2013. Available at http:// economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2013/01/its-not-a-skill-mismatch-disaggregateevidence-on-the-us-unemployment-vacancy-relationship.html. Accessed July 1, 2013. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 701 Dooley, David and JoAnn Prause. The Social Costs of Underemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004. Durand, Cedric and Phillipe Lege. “Regulation Beyond Growth.” Capital & Class 37, 1 (2012): 111-126. ———. “Over-Accumulation, Rising Costs, and ‘Unproductive’ Labor: The Relevance of the Classic Stationary State Issue for Developed Countries.” Review of Radical Political Economics 20, 10 (2013): 119. Dustman, Christian and Uta Schonberg. “What Makes Firm-Based Vocational Training Schemes Successful? The Role of Commitment.” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4, 2 (2012): 3661. Dynan, Karen, Jonathan Skinner and Stephen P. Zeldes. “Do the Rich Save More?” Journal of Political Economy 112, 2 (2004): 397-444. Economic Policy Institute. “Missing Workers.” Washington, D.C., 2013. Available at www.epi.org/ publication/missing-workers/. Accessed January 6, 2014. Economist. “Of Shocks and Horrors.” The Economist, September 26, 2002. Available at www.economist.com/ node/1336182. Accessed July 29, 2013. Edin, Per-Anders and Magnus Gustavsson. “Time Out of Work and Skill Depreciation.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 61, 2 (2008): 163-180. Farber, Henry. “Employment Insecurity: The Decline in Worker-Firm Attachment in the United States.” Working Paper No. 530. Princeton: Princeton University, 2008. ———. “Job Loss in the Great Recession: Historical Perspective from the Displaced Workers Survey, 1984– 2010.” Working Paper No. 564. Princeton: Princeton University, 2011. Fogg, Neeta P. and Paul E. Harrington. “Rising Mal-Employment and the Great Recession: The Growing Disconnect Between Recent College Graduates and the College Labor Market.” Continuing Higher Education Review 75 (2011): 51-65. Forstater, Mathew. “Flexible Full Employment: Structural Implications of Discretionary Public Sector Employment.” Journal of Economic Issues 32, 2 (1998): 557-563. ———. “Green Jobs: Public Service Employment and Environmental Sustainability.” Challenge 49, 4 (2006): 58-72. Friedman, Milton. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962. Fry, Richard and Paul Taylor. “An Uneven Recovery, 2009-2011: A Rise in Wealth for the Wealthy; Declines for the Lower 93%.” Washington, D.C.: Pew Research Center, 2013. Available at www.pewsocialtrends.org/files/2013/04/wealth_recovery_final.pdf. Accessed January 6, 2014. Galbraith, James K. Inequality and Instability: A Study of the World Economy Just Before the Great Crisis. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012. Gilligan, James. Why Some Politicians Are More Dangerous Than Others. New York: Polity, 2011. Glaeser, Edward L. “Corruption in America.” Journal of Public Economics 90, 6-7 (2006): 1053-1072. Goldin, Claudia, and Robert Margo. “The Great Compression: The Wage Structure in the United States at Mid-Century.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 1 (1992): 1-34. Goldstein, Amy. “Job Retraining Is a Popular Fix That May Not Work.” Washington Post, February 19, 2012, p. B3. Gordon, Robert J. “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds.” Working Paper No. 18315. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 2012. Gordon, Wendell. “Job Assurance — The Job Guarantee Revisited.” Journal of Economic Issues 31, 3 (1997): 826-834 Gould, Eric D., Bruce Weinberg and David B. Mustard. “Crime Rates and Local Labor Market Opportunities in the United States: 1979–1997.” Review of Economics and Statistics 84, 1 (2002): 4561. Grogger, Jeff. “Market Wages and Youth Crime.” Journal of Labor Economics 16, 4 (1998): 756-791. Hacker, Jacob and Paul Pierson. Winner Take All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer — and Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon and Schuster, 2010. Harvey, Philip. Securing the Right to Employment. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989. Heckman, James J., Robert J. Lalonde and Jeffrey A. Smith. The Economics and Econometrics of Active Labor Market Programs. Volume 3A. In Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and David Card, pp. 1865-2095. New York: Elsevier, 2009. 702 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti Hertz, Tom. “Trends in the Intergenerational Elasticity of Family Income in the United States.” Industrial Relations 46, 1 (2007): 22-50. Hobsbawn, E.J. Industry and Empire: An Economic History of Britain Since 1750. London: Weidenfield and Nicholson, 1968. Kaboub, Fadhel. “The Low Cost of Full Employment in the United States.” In The Job Guarantee: Toward True Full Employment, edited by Matthew Forstater and Michael Murray, pp. 59-72. New York: Palgrave, 2012. Kalecki, Michal. “Political Aspects of Full Employment.” Political Quarterly 14, 4 (1943): 322-331. Keynes, John Maynard. Activities 1940–46. Shaping the Post-War World: Employment and Commodities. Vol. XXVII of Collected Works. London: Macmillan, 1980. ———. Activities 1931–39. World Crises and Policies in Britain and America. Vol. XXI of Collected Works. London: Macmillan, [1933] 1982. Kissling, Frances and Peter Singer. “To Fix the Climate, Take Meat off the Menu.” Washington Post, June 17, 2012, p. B3. Kocherlakota, Naryana. “Inside the FOMC.” Speech delivered on August 17, 2010, in Marquette, MI. Available at www.minneapolisfed.org/news_events/pres/speech_display.cfm?id=4525. Accessed April 11, 2014. Kroft, Kory, Fabian Lange and Matthew J. Notowidigdo. “Duration Dependence and Labor Market Conditions: Theory and Evidence from a Field Experiment.” Working Paper No. 18387. National Bureau of Economic Research, 2012. Krueger, Alan B. and Andreas Mueller. “Job Search, Emotional Well-Being and Job Finding in a Period of Mass Unemployment: Evidence from High-Frequency Longitudinal Data.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring 2011. Krugman, Paul. “Secular Stagnation Arithmetic.” The Conscience of a Liberal Blog, December 7, 2013. Available at http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/12/07/secular-stagnation-arithmetic/. Accessed April 11, 2014. Kumhof, Michael and Romain Rancière. “Inequality, Leverage and Crises.” IMF Working Paper 10/268, November, 2010. Lasch, Christopher. The Revolt of the Elites: and the Betrayal of Democracy. New York: W.W. Norton, 1995. Lazear, Edward P. and James R. Spletzer. “The United States Labor Market: Status Quo or a New Normal?” Working Paper 18386. National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, 2012. Lucas, Robert E., Jr. “The Death of Keynesian Economics.” Issues and Ideas (Winter 1980): 18-19. Marlar, Jenny. “Worry, Sadness, Stress Increase with Length of Unemployment.” Gallup Wellbeing, June, 2010. Available at www.gallup.com/poll/139604/worry-sadness-stress-increase-lengthunemployment.aspx. Accessed April 11, 2014. Mazumder, Bhashkar. “Fortunate Sons: New Estimates of Intergenerational Mobility in the United States Using Social Security Earnings Data.” Review of Economics and Statistics 82, 2 (2005): 235-255. Minsky, Hyman P. “The Strategy of Economic Policy and Income Distribution.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 409 (September 1973): 92-101. Mishel, Lawrence, Jared Bernstein and Sylvia Allegretto. The State of Working America. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2007. Mitchell, William and L. Randall Wray. “In Defense of Employer of Last Resort: A Response to Malcolm Sawyer.” Journal of Economic Issues 39, 1 (2005): 235-243. Mokyr, Joel. The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2002. Murray, Michael. “Employer of Last Resort under the ‘Pay As You Go’ Legislation: A Fair-Model Simulation.” Working Paper. Bemidji State University, 2012. Offer, Avner. “The Challenge of Affluence.” Interview. Challenge 50, 2 (2007): 6-19. Olney, Martha L. Buy Now, Pay Later. Chapel Hill, NC: University of North Carolina, 1991. Olney, Martha L. and Aaron Pacitti. “Goods, Services, and the Pace of Economic Recovery.” Working Paper No. 2013-04. Berkeley Economic History Lab, University of California Berkeley, 2013. Available at http:// behl.berkeley.edu/files/2013/02/BEHLWP2013-04_ olneypacitti_2-26-13.pdf. Accessed April 11, 2014. Pacitti, Aaron. “The Cost of Job Loss and the Great Recession.” Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 33, 4 (2011): 597-620. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 703 ———. “Bargaining Power, Labor Market Institutions, and the Great Moderation.” Eastern Economic Journal (2014): doi:10.1057/eej.2014.3. Parey, Matthais. “Vocational Schooling Versus Apprenticeship Training — Evidence from Vacancy Data.” Working Paper. University of Essex and Institute for Fiscal Studies, 2009. Perelman, Michael. The Confiscation of American Prosperity: From Right-Wing Extremism and Economic Ideology to the Next Great Depression. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007. Rajan, Raghuram. “Bernanke Must End Era of Ultra-Low Rates.” Financial Times, July 29, 2010. Reardon, Sean F. “The Widening Socioeconomic Status Achievement Gap: New Evidence and Possible Explanations.” In Whither Opportunity? Rising Inequality and the Uncertain Life Chances of Low-Income Children, edited by Richard Murnane and Greg Duncan, pp. 91-116. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2011. Reich, Robert B. The Future of Success. New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 2001. Rohit. “Income Distribution, Irrational Exuberance, and Growth: A Theoretical Model of the U.S. Economy.” Review of Radical Political Economics 43, 4 (2011): 449-466. Roosevelt, Franklin D. “168 — Fireside Chat.” Speech, Washington, D.C. September 30, 1934. Available at www.presidency.ucsb.edu/ws/index.php?pid=14759. Accessed April 11, 2014. Rose, Nancy E. “Bring Back the WPA: Lessons from the Job Creation Programs of the 1930s.” In Employment Guarantee Schemes: Job Creation and Policy in Developing Countries and Emerging Markets, edited by Michael J. Murray and Matthew Forstater, pp. 155-180. New York: Palgrave, 2013. Roubini, Nouriel. Business Cycle Indicators: Unemployment Rate. Available at http:// pages.stern.nyu.edu/ ~nroubini/bci/Unemploymentrate.htm. Accessed on July 10, 2013. Ryan, Paul. “The School-to-Work Transition: A Cross-National Perspective.” Journal of Economic Literature 39, 1 (2001): 34-92. Saez, Emmanuel. “Striking It Richer: The Evolution of Top Incomes in the United States.” Working Paper. University of California-Berkeley, 2012. Available at http://elsa. Bekeley.edu/~saez/saezUStopincomes-2012.pdf. Accessed July 8, 2013. Samuelson, Robert J. “Cautious Capitalists.” Washington Post, September 9, 2013, p. A17. Sánchez, Juan M. and Emircan Yurdagul. “Why Are Corporations Holding So Much Cash?” Regional Economist, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, January 2013. Available at www.stlouisfed.org/ publications/re/articles/?id=2314. Accessed July 8, 2013. Schmitt, John. “Inequality as Policy.” Real Word Economics Review 51, 1 (2009): 2-9. Sen, Amartya. “Inequality, Unemployment and Contemporary Europe.” International Labor Review 136, 2 (1997): 155-172. Smiley, Gene. “The U.S. Economy in the 1920s.” EH.Net Encyclopedia. Available at http://eh.net/ encyclopedia/article/Smiley.1920s.final. Accessed February 12, 2013). Solon, Gary. “Intergenerational Income Mobility in the United States.” American Economic Review, 82, 3 (1992): 393-408. Stevens, Ann Huff. “Persistent Effects of Job Displacement: The Importance of Multiple Job Losses.” Journal of Labor Economics 15, 1 (1997): 165-188. Stiglitz, Joseph E. The Price of Inequality. New York: W.W. Norton, 2012. Stone, Charley, Carl Van Horn and Cliff Zukin. “Chasing the American Dream: Recent College Graduates and the Great Recession.” Rutgers University: John J. Heldrich Center for Workforce Development, May 2012. Storm, Sara. “Unemployment and Families: A Review of Research.” Social Science Review 77 (2003): 399401. Sullivan, Daniel and Till von Wachter. “Job Displacement and Mortality: An Analysis Using Administrative Data.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 124, 3 (2009): 1265-1306. Sum, Andrew and Ishwar Khatiwada. “The Great Recession of 2007–2009: Its Post-World War II Record Impacts on Rising Unemployment and Underutilization Problems Among U.S. Workers.” Paper No. 22. Center for Labor Market Studies, 2009. ———. “Labor Underutilization Problems of U.S. Workers Across Household Income Groups at the End of the Great Recession.” Paper No. 26. Center for Labor Market Studies, 2010. ———. “Ignoring Those Left Behind.” Challenge 55, 2 (2012): 5-20. Summers, Lawrence. “Preempting Economic Stagnation.” Washington Post, December 20, 2013, p. A27. Tankersley, Jim. “The Rise of Robots Favors the Rich.” Washington Post, July 13, 2013, p. A9. 704 Jon D. Wisman and Aaron Pacitti Taylor, Paul et al. “The Impact of Long-Term Unemployment: Lost Income, Lost Friends—and Loss of SelfRespect.” Pew Research Center, 2010. Available at http:// pewsocialtrends.org/assets/pdf/760recession.pdf. Accessed July 8. 2013. Temin, Peter. “Real Business Cycle Views of the Great Depression and Recent Events: A Review of Timothy J. Kehoe and Edward C. Prescott’s Great Depressions of the Twentieth Century.” Journal of Economic Literature 46, 3 (2008): 669-684. United States Federal Courts. Bankruptcy. Available at www.uscourts.gov/ Statistics/ BankruptcyStatistics/12-month-period-ending-march.aspx. Accessed July 15, 2013. Urhan, Susan K. et al. “Pursing the American Dream: Economic Mobility Across Generations.” The Pew Charitable Trusts: State and Consumer Initiatives, 2013. Available at www.pewtrusts.org/ our_work_report_detail.aspx?id=85899403846. Accessed July 8, 2013. Valletta, Robert G. and Katherine Kuang. “Is Structural Unemployment on the Rise?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter 2010-34, 2010. Vatter, Harold G. The U.S. Economy in Work War II. New York: Columbia University Press, 1985. Vickrey, William S. “Chock-Full Employment Without Increased Inflation.” American Economic Review 82, 2 (1992): 341-345. Washington Post. “Military: Many Recruits Failing Army Entrance Exam.” Washington Post, December 22, 2010, p. A2. Weidner, Justin and John C. Williams. “What Is the New Normal Unemployment Rate?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, Economic Letter 2011-05, 2011. Wilkinson, Richard and Kate Pickett. The Spirit Level: Why More Equal Societies Almost Always Do Better. London: Allen Lane, 2009. Williamson, Jeffrey G. Inequality, Poverty and History: The Kuznets Memorial Lectures. Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1991. Winkelman, Liliana and Rainer Winkelman. “Why Are the Unemployed So Unhappy? Evidence from Panel Data.” Economica 65, 257 (1998): 1-15. Wisman, Jon D. “The Moral Imperative and Social Rationality of Government-Guaranteed Employment and Reskilling.” Review of Social Economy 68, 1 (2010): 35-67. ———. “Inequality, Social Respectability, Political Power, and Environmental Devastation.” Journal of Economic Issues 45, 4 (2011): 877-900. ———. “The Growth Trap, Ecological Devastation, and the Promise of Guaranteed Employment.” Challenge 56, 2 (2013a): 53-78. ———. “Wage Stagnation, Rising Inequality, and the Financial Crisis of 2008.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 37, 4 (2013b): 921-945. ———. “Government Is Whose Problem.” Journal of Economic Issues 47, 4 (2013c): 911-937. ———. “The Financial Crisis of 1929 Reexamined: The Role of Soaring Inequality” Journal of Political Economy (2014): 372-391. Wisman, Jon D. and Bart Baker. “Rising Inequality and the Financial Crises of 1929 and 2008.” In Consequences of Economic Downturn, edited by Martha Starr, pp. 63-82. New York: Palgrave, 2010. Wisman, Jon D. and Aaron Pacitti. “What Could the Wealth Gained By the Richest Americans Since 1979 Have Paid For?” Think Progress, September 14, 2012, http:// thinkprogress.org/ economy/2012/09/14/852061/wealth-gained-pays-for/. Accessed July 8, 2013. Wisman, Jon D. and Nicholas Reksten. “Rising Job Complexity and the Need for Government Guaranteed Work and Training.” In The Job Guarantee: Toward True Full Employment, edited by Matthew Forstater and Michael Murray, pp. 5-38. New York: Palgrave, 2013. Wolff, Edward N. “Recent Trends in Household Wealth in the United States: Rising Debt and the MiddleClass Squeeze — An Update to 2007.” Working Paper No. 589. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, 2010. Wray, L. Randall. Understanding Modern Money: The Key to Full Employment and Price Stability. Northampton, MA: Elgar, 1998a. ———. “Zero Unemployment and Stable Prices.” Journal of Economic Issues 32, 2 (1998b): 535-545. ———. “Public Service Employment-Assured Jobs Programs: Further Considerations.” Journal of Economic Issues 22, 2 (1999): 483-491. ———. “The Employer of Last Resort Program: Could It Work for Developing Countries?” Working Paper 2007/5. International Labor Office, 2007. Ending the Unemployment Crisis with Guaranteed Employment and Retraining 705 ———. “When Robots Make Drones: The Brave New World of Secular Stagnation.” Economonitor Blog, December 9, 2013. Available at www.economonitor. com/lrwray/2013/12/09/when-robots-makedrones-the-brave-new-world-of-secular-stagnation-2/. Accessed December 9, 2013. Wray, Randall L. and Mathew Forstater. “Full Employment and Social Justice.” In The Institutionalist Tradition in Labor Economics, edited by Dell P. Champlin and Janet T. Knoedler, pp. 253-272. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe, 2004.