Inequality in Britain: an explanation of recent trends Luke Sibieta, November 23rd, 2011 © Institute for Fiscal Studies An economic approach to inequality The gap between “rich” and “poor” But how should we measure it? Why should we care about inequality? Can we explain recent trends? How should we measure it? Inequality of what? – Household income, earnings, wages, consumption, material living standards, utility? Compare different points in the income distribution Summary measures of the entire distribution with desirable properties – E.g. Gini Coefficient, Mean Log Deviation Substantial rise in inequality during the 1980s Gini Coefficient 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 Source: IFS © Institute for Fiscal Studies Top of income distribution races away 6.00 Ratio 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 90/10 Source: IFS © Institute for Fiscal Studies 50/10 99/50 Gini – Mid 80s Gini - Mid 2000s Source: OECD. Figures not directly comparable with those on other slides. Mid 80s Germany refers to West Germany. © Institute for Fiscal Studies OE CD ex ic o M US A Ire la nd tra lia Au s Ita ly UK ad a Ca n Ja pa n an ce Fr Ge rm an y 0.50 0.45 0.40 0.35 0.30 0.25 0.20 0.15 0.10 0.05 0.00 Sw ed en Gini Coefficient The Gini: international comparisons Real earnings growth Sweden (1980-2005) Avg annual earnings growth 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 Source: OECD Notes: Full-time male workers only © Institute for Fiscal Studies 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 USA (1980-2005) France (2000-2005) Avg annual earnings growth Avg annual earnings growth 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 Avg annual earnings growth UK (1980-2005) 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 Why should we care about inequality? Economics largely focuses on ‘Efficiency’ and ‘Pareto optimality’, says very little about ‘Equity’ Efficiency considerations for valuing inequality – Social unrest and crime, trust and social capital, long-term generational consequences – But some benefits as a result of incentive effects Welfare considerations of a social planner – What is the optimal welfare metric? Why has inequality gone up? There are many competing explanations for changes in inequality, including: – – – – Changing industrial structure, etc. Returns to education Regional changes (North/South gap) Demographic Change Statistical decompositions allow us to weigh up some of these competing explanations Results taken from Brewer, Muriel and WrenLewis (2010) Inequality – subgroup decomposition Inequality measures tell us how unequally incomes are distributed Lowest Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition But suppose we divide the population into subgroups (e.g. ethnic groups, or employed vs. unemployed) Lowest Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition We see that some groups have very high inequality (e.g. the self-employed) Lowest Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition And others have low inequality, with low average incomes (etc.) Lowest While others have low inequality, but high average incomes (e.g. the employed) Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition Increasing inequality could be caused by: Inequality increasing within some groups: Lowest = “Within-group inequality” effect Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition Or increasing inequality between groups Lowest Income Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition Or increasing inequality between groups (i) because their average incomes change Lowest Income = “Relative income effect” Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition Or increasing inequality between groups (ii) because more people join a group with high inequality Lowest Income = “Population change (within)” effect Highest Inequality – subgroup decomposition Or increasing inequality between groups (iii) because more people join groups with low (or high) incomes Lowest = “Population change (mean)” effect Income Highest Subgroup decomposition example: by employment status of head of household We divide the population into groups according to the schooling of the head of household: • Left education aged 16 or under • Left education aged 17-19 • Left education aged 20+ • Unknown or still in education Decompose inequality changes into the four effects described earlier Subgroup decomposition – by education level Between-group inequality Period Change in overall inequality (I0) Withingroup inequality 1978 - 84 18 13 1984 – 88 42 34 1988 – 91 18 16 1991 – 95-96 –12 –13 1995-96 – 2000-01 11 10 2000-01 – 04-05 –9 –10 1 1 –2 2004-05 – 06-07 10 10 1 1 –2 Population change (within) Population change (mean) Relative income 0 1 4 0 2 Mostly group 0 within 1 Relative income effect inequality important during 1 1 1980s 1 2 5 1 –2 –2 Subgroup decompositions can be unclear Suppose we have the following change: Lowest Income Highest Subgroup decompositions can be unclear Gender subgroup decomposition.... ... would partly attribute it to decreasing female income Lowest Income Highest Subgroup decompositions can be unclear Colour subgroup decomposition.... ... would partly attribute to decreasing yellow income Lowest Income Highest Subgroup decompositions can be unclear Which factor is more important? Lowest Income Highest Subgroup decompositions can be unclear Which factor is more important? Factor decomposition allows us to consider all factors simultaneously Lowest Income Highest Inequality (log variance x 1000) Income inequality – factor decomposition 350 Employment Status Health 300 Ethnic group 250 Education 200 Age 150 Gender 100 Household type Region 50 Residual 0 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 1988 1992 1996 2000 2004 Source: HBAI Data (FES and FRS) and authors’ analysis What we do not know (and why it matters) There is much we do not understand! But the answer matters. Different explanations for why inequality has increased have different implications for various ideas of ‘fairness’ or ‘justice’ Studies have examined whether increases in income inequality reflect : Higher volatility in people’s incomes from year to year. Or increases in ‘permanent inequality’ between people who are always poor and always rich (i.e. reductions in social mobility). © Institute for Fiscal Studies How much can government affect inequality? Tax and state benefit system clearly makes a difference But can be very costly to just rely on fiscal redistribution. Countries with low inequality (e.g. Scandinavia) tend to have low ‘pre tax and benefit’ inequality; much of recent rise in inequality due to rise in pre-tax earnings inequality. Income distribution shaped by the distribution of private incomes earned in the labour market. © Institute for Fiscal Studies How much can government affect labour market outcomes? Depends what drives it! But ultimately, people can not earn a lot in the labour market unless they have skills that employers value. It is not surprising that the most equal societies are different to the most unequal ones from the bottom up, e.g. early educational achievements, health, etc. It seems very difficult to only target equality in specific things (e.g. ‘income’), because everything is connected! © Institute for Fiscal Studies