Means-testing and tax rates on earnings: a contribution to the Mirrlees Review Mike Brewer (IFS) Emmanuel Saez (UC, Berkeley) Andrew Shephard (IFS & UCL) © Institute for Fiscal Studies “The Mirrlees review: Reforming the Tax System for the 21st Century” • Independent review, run by Mirrlees, with Besley, Blundell, Gammie and Poterba – Commissioned 13 studies, plus discussants. All available on-line. – Editorial volume will distil, and make own recommendations. Published late 2009 (?) • Objectives – To bring together international experts in public economics, tax law, political science and tax practice – To identify the characteristics of a good tax system for any open developed economy in the 21st century – To assess how well UK tax system conforms to these ideals – To recommend how it might realistically be reformed in that direction • Inspired by the 30th anniversary of the ‘Meade Report’, The Structure and Reform of Direct Taxation (1978) © Institute for Fiscal Studies Means-testing and tax rates on earnings • Aim – to review developments in optimal income tax, and make recommendations for UK personal tax, tax credits and benefits • Outline – Optimal tax theory • Top rates of tax & all rates of tax • Extensive and intensive responses – Other issues • Family vs individual • Administering transfers for low-income families – Lessons for the UK – Reform proposals for the UK Reflections • Optimal income tax still not that useful when designing income tax and cash transfers • Saez (2002) was key advance by integrating extensive and intensive responses, and making problem tractable (see also Immervol et al (2007), Blundell et al (2009)) • But we found ourselves unable to ignore – Dynamic issues (eg response of high-salaried workers to higher METRs) – Family formation (not just “how to tax couples” (Kleven et al, 2009) but also tax and welfare (dis)incentives to be (or to admit to being) in a couple (Anderberg, 2008; Hoynes, 2008) – Fertility responses to child-conditional transfers (Brewer et al, 2008; Laroque and Salanie, 2008; Milligan, 2005) – Administrative/operational issues • So we learned lessons from optimal tax theory and positive economic analysis, then imposed our own value judgements to suggest reforms. We mostly ignored the UK political context. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Optimal income tax: intensive responses fraction with higher earnings social value of tax rate consumption above z • Use Saez (2001, 2002) T ' ( z) 1 1 H ( z) • Intensive-only model: (1 G( z)) 1 T ' ( z) e elasticity to net-oftax rate zh( z) density of earners Optimal income tax: intensive responses, simple simulation for UK METR 100% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% V=log(u), e=0.50 V=log(u), e=0.25 £50 £500 £5,000 Annual income £50,000 Earnings estimated from FRS and SPI; METRs estimated from TAXBEN © Institute for Fiscal Studies £500,000 Optimal income tax : intensive responses • Use Saez (2001, 2002) T ' ( z) 1 1 H ( z) • Intensive-only model: (1 G( z)) 1 T ' ( z) e zh( z) • Revenue-maximising top rate of tax: T ' ( z | z z) E( z | z z) 1 ;a 1 a e E( z | z z) z – If z is Pareto distributed above zbar, then a is constant – BSS estimated a =1.6; Brewer and Browne (2009) estimated a=1.8 Estimating the Pareto parameter (a) for top incomes in UK a=E(z|z>zbar)/(z-E(z|z>zbar)) 2.20 a 2.10 E ( z | z z) E ( z | z z) z 2.00 1.90 1.80 1.70 1.60 1.50 £0 £100,000 £200,000 £300,000 zbar £400,000 Source: Brewer and Browne, 2009 based on Survey of Personal Incomes 2005-6 © Institute for Fiscal Studies £500,000 Optimal income tax : intensive responses • Use Saez (2001, 2002) T ' ( z) 1 1 H ( z) • Intensive-only model: (1 G( z)) 1 T ' ( z) e zh( z) • Revenue-maximising top rate of tax: T ' ( z | z z) E( z | z z) 1 ;a 1 a e E( z | z z) z – If z is Pareto distributed above zbar, then a is constant – BSS estimated a =1.6; Brewer and Browne (2009) estimated a=1.8 – What about e ? No evidence from UK, so did naïve analysis based on income shares, and changes in average METRs… Income shares and top rates in UK, 1962-2003 100% 16% 90% 14% 80% Income share 12% 70% 10% 50% 8% 40% 6% METR 60% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1962 METR, top 1% METR, top 5-1% 4% Share, top 1% Share, top 5-1% 2% 0% 1972 1982 Source: BSS (2008) based on income shares from Atkinson (2008). METRs estimated from TAXBEN © Institute for Fiscal Studies 1992 2002 Optimal income tax : intensive responses • Use Saez (2001, 2002) T ' ( z) 1 1 H ( z) • Intensive-only model: (1 G( z)) 1 T ' ( z) e zh( z) • Revenue-maximising top rate of tax: T ' ( z | z z) E( z | z z) 1 ;a 1 a e E( z | z z) z – If z is Pareto distributed above zbar, then a is constant – BSS estimated a =1.6; Brewer and Browne (2009) estimated a=1.8 – What about e ? No evidence from UK, so did naïve analysis based on income shares, and changes in average METRs… giving e=0.46 (0.13) Optimal income tax : intensive responses • Use Saez (2001, 2002) T ' ( z) 1 1 H ( z) • Intensive-only model: (1 G( z)) 1 T ' ( z) e zh( z) • Revenue-maximising top rate of tax: T ' ( z | z z) E( z | z z) 1 ;a 1 a e E( z | z z) z – If z is Pareto distributed above zbar, then a is constant – BSS estimated a =1.6; Brewer and Browne (2009) estimated a=1.8 – What about e ? No evidence from UK, so did naïve analysis based on income shares, and changes in average METRs… giving e=0.46 (0.13) – Overall, BSS suggested revenue-maximising rate of 56.6%, and BB suggested 54.7% – At time of writing BSS, top income tax rate was 40% (47.7% on earned), but UK government has just proposed new top rate of 50% and rise in payroll tax! – All depends on e; Government argues has closed Revenue raised by different income tax rates above £150,000 (includes effect on NI and indirect taxes) Change in tax revenues, £ million £4,000 BSS behavioural response £3,000 No behavioural response £2,000 HMT behavioural response £1,000 £0 35% 40% 45% 50% -£1,000 -£2,000 -£3,000 -£4,000 Source: Brewer and Browne, 2009 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Income tax rate above £150,000 55% 60% Optimal income tax: extensive responses • But we can’t ignore extensive responses, especially for lone parents and mothers in couples • Evidence – Reviewed in Meghir and Phillips, (2008) – Saez (2002): The more important are extensive elasticities, the lower should marginal rates be for low earners – Adam (2005): METRs for low-earning lone parents in UK above Laffer bound – IKKS (2008): earned income tax credits (negative marginal rates for low earners) more likely to be optimal for countries with dispersed wage distribution, like UK • Participation responses can include migration, participation in (in)formal economy The family and the tax system • Individual or joint? – Efficiency: individual-level tax (or, even, lower METRs for second earners/women) – Equity: family-level tax if partners share resources – Couple penalties? (Anderberg, 2008) – Hard to say much in optimal income tax model • Kleven et al (2008): optimal to have higher tax rates on second earners with poor partners than those with rich partners, like UK. Leads to “Couple penalties” • But assumes everyone lives in a couple forever • Many transfers conditional on children (“tagging”) – Equity: higher transfers for families with children – Efficiency: lower MTRs for (some?) parents – Fertility response ?? How many lone parents in the UK? Number (millions) 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 Lone parents receiving income-related child support 0.5 All lone parent families 0.0 10/1995 07/1998 04/2001 01/2004 Source: Brewer et al (2009) based on official estimates and admin data © Institute for Fiscal Studies 10/2006 07/2009 Administering transfers for low-income households • BSS argued that – Transfers should be predictable, impose low compliance costs on recipients and have high take-up – Little point designing transfer system for poor that does not reflect current circumstances • UK system fails here (tax credits, Housing Benefit), but recent UK experience and international examples suggest no easy solutions The tax and transfer system and work incentives in the UK • Rest of the paper assesses the UK tax and transfer system and its impact on incentives • Will show some pictures, then outline our proposals • Will not discuss “conditionality” (ie what people have to do in order to receive welfare benefits) © Institute for Fiscal Studies Annual net income Budget constraint, lone parent, 2008-9 £50,000 £45,000 £40,000 £35,000 £30,000 £25,000 £20,000 £15,000 £10,000 £5,000 £0 Welfare benefits have 100% METR Rent subsidy makes huge difference… At 16 hours/wk, lose entitlement to welfare but gain entitlement to tax credits £0 £10,000 £20,000 £30,000 £40,000 £50,000 £60,000 £70,000 Annual earnings including employer cost Source: BSS 2008 based on TAXBEN. 2008-9 tax system. © Institute for Fiscal Studies End of tax credit withdrawal METRs, lone parents, 2008-9 Welfare benefits have 100% METR Rent subsidy makes huge difference… £50,000 £45,000 End of tax credit withdrawal Annual net income £40,000 £35,000 120% 100% 80% £30,000 £25,000 60% £20,000 40% £15,000 METR, HB £10,000 At 16 hours/wk, lose entitlement to welfare but gain entitlement to tax credits £5,000 £0 £0 20% 0% £10,000 £20,000 £30,000 £40,000 £50,000 £60,000 £70,000 Annual earnings including employer cost Source: BSS 2008 based on TAXBEN. 2008-9 tax system. © Institute for Fiscal Studies METR, no HB Participation tax rates, lone parents, 2008-9 Welfare benefits have 100% METR Rent subsidy makes huge difference… £50,000 £45,000 End of tax credit withdrawal Annual net income £40,000 100% 80% £35,000 60% £30,000 40% £25,000 20% £20,000 £15,000 PTR, no HB £10,000 PTR, HB £5,000 £0 £0 At 16 hours/wk, lose entitlement to welfare but gain £20,000 £30,000 £40,000 entitlement to tax credits -20% -40% £10,000 £50,000 £60,000 £70,000 Annual earnings including employer cost Source: BSS 2008 based on TAXBEN. 2008-9 tax system. © Institute for Fiscal Studies 0% METRs, couples, 2008-9 100% 100% 90% 80% With kids, partner not working With kids, partner working Without kids, partner not working Without kids, partner working 70% METRs higher for 1st earners if have children 60% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 50% 40% 40% 30% 30% 20% 10% From tax credit taper 0% £0 20% 10% 0% £10,000 £20,000 £30,000 £40,000 £50,000 £60,000 £70,000 Annual earnings including employer cost Source: BSS 2008 based on TAXBEN. 2008-9 tax system. © Institute for Fiscal Studies METRs higher for 2nd earners if have children PTRs, couples, 2008-9 100% 100% 90% 80% With kids, partner not working With kids, partner working Without kids, partner not working Without kids, partner working PTRs higher for 1st earners if have children 70% 60% 90% 80% 70% 60% 50% 50% 40% 40% 30% 30% 20% PTRs higher for 2nd earners if 10% have children 0% £0 10% 0% £10,000 £20,000 £30,000 £40,000 £50,000 £60,000 £70,000 Annual earnings including employer cost Source: BSS 2008 based on TAXBEN. 2008-9 tax system. © Institute for Fiscal Studies 20% Main defects in the UK tax-transfer system… • Participation tax rates at the bottom very high: – • If on welfare, METR is 100% below 16 hours METR over 80% for low-income working families because of phasingout of WTC, IT, NI, employer NI, VAT (70% if ignore employer taxes and VAT) – • High METRs/PTRs focused on those with high responsiveness! Housing benefit has very steep withdrawal, and big administrative problems Tax credit administration less efficient than PAYE • – – • Tax credits adjust slowly and unpredictably to changes Absurd that transfer system for poor leads to over-payments (=debt) even if families comply fully Also concluded that – – Participation responses important, hours responses almost irrelevant, but sizable response of taxable income amongst very rich. But not clear what is taxable income elasticity of middle- to high-income individuals Income tax should stay individual …lead to fairly obvious short-run proposals • Higher disregards in all welfare benefits • New disregard in tax credits for second earners • Higher working tax credit • Lower taper in tax credits • All would cost money, and extend the number on tax credit withdrawal. None directly benefit those on lowest incomes who are not working © Institute for Fiscal Studies Longer-term, more dramatic changes • Propose a new Integrated Family Support programme – Hint: look at the initials… • Key features – Unifies welfare benefits and tax credits for low-income families – IFS disregard aligned with income tax personal allowance – Maximum IFS entitlement paid direct to families, and IFS withdrawal operated by employers (ensures IFS is responsive) • Problems – Hugely more generous to low-income families, hugely extends number on some sort of taper (on top of income tax) – HB still problematic: probably requires a change in housing policy – No elegant system for couples – Considerable amount of “churn” • Attempt simple behavioural analysis by assuming families respond to changes in METRs and PTRs: a revenue-neutral reform is strongly redistributive, but slightly reduces total earnings (see BSS for details) © Institute for Fiscal Studies End References Adam, S., (2005), “Measuring the marginal efficiency cost of redistribution in the UK", IFS WP 05/14 Anderberg, D. (forthcoming), “Tax Credits, Income Support and Partnership Decisions”, International Tax and Public Finance Blundell, R., Brewer, M., Haan, P. & Shephard, A., (2009), "Optimal Income Taxation of Lone Mothers: An Empirical Comparison of the UK and Germany", Economic Journal, 119, pp F101-F121. Brewer, M., Saez, E. & Shephard, A. (2008), “Means-testing and tax rates on earnings”, forthcoming in Dimensions of Tax Design, OUP. Draft available at http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview/press_docs/rates.pdf Brewer, M. & Browne, J. (2009), “Can more revenue be raised by increasing income tax rates for the very rich?”, IFS Briefing Notes 84, http://www.ifs.org.uk/bns/bn84.pdf Brewer, M., Muriel, Al. Phillips, D. & Sibieta, L. (2009), Poverty and Inequality in the UK: 2009, IFS Commentary 109, http://www.ifs.org.uk/comms/c109.pdf Brewer, M., Ratcliffe, A. & Smith, S., (2008), “Does welfare reform affect fertility? Evidence from the UK”, IFS WP 08/09 Hoynes, H. (2008), “Means-testing and tax rates on earnings: a commentary”, forthcoming in Dimensions of Tax Design, OUP. Draft available at http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview/press_docs/hoynes.pdf Immervoll, H., Kleven, H., Kreiner, C. & Saez, E., (2007), “Welfare Reform in European Countries: Microsimulation Analysis”, Economic Journal, 117, pp 1-44 Laroque, G. & Salanie, B., (2008), “Does Fertility Respond to Financial Incentives?” CESifo WP 2339 Kleven, H., Kreiner, C. & Saez, E., (2009), "The Optimal Income Taxation of Couples”, Econometrica 77, 2009, pp. 537-560 Meghir, C. and Phillips, D. (2008), “Labour supply and taxes”, forthcoming in Dimensions of Tax Design, OUP. Draft available at http://www.ifs.org.uk/mirrleesreview/reports/labour_supply.pdf Milligan, K., (2005). “Subsidizing the Stork: New Evidence on Tax Incentives and Fertility.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 87(3), pp 539-555 Saez, E., (2001), “Using Elasticities to Derive Optimal Income Tax Rates." Review of Economic Studies, 68, pp 205-229 Saez, E., (2002), “Optimal Income Transfer programmes: Intensive Versus Extensive Labour Supply Responses." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), pp1039-1073 Saez, E., Slemrod, J. and Giertz, S. (2009), "The Elasticity of Taxable Income with Respect to Marginal Tax Rates: A Critical Review“ NBER WP 15012 and forthcoming Journal of Economic Literature © Institute for Fiscal Studies