THE IFS GREEN BUDGET: JANUARY 2003 Robert Chote Carl Emmerson Helen Simpson supported by E •S •R •C ECONOMIC & SOCIAL RESEARCH COUNCIL THE INSTITUTE FOR FISCAL STUDIES Commentary 92 Contents List of figures List of tables v vii 1 Summary 2 2.1 2.2 2.3 2.4 Planning the public finances The Chancellor’s fiscal rules Planning and forecasting revenues Planning government spending Conclusions 7 7 20 25 29 3 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 IFS public finance forecasts Borrowing in 2002–03 Borrowing in 2003–04 Medium-term prospects The Budget judgement 31 32 34 35 39 4 42 4.4 4.5 What do the child poverty targets mean for the child tax credit? Child poverty under Labour The child tax credit Is the government likely to meet its child poverty target in 2004–05? What would it cost to reduce child poverty further? Conclusion 5 5.1 5.2 5.3 Income tax and National Insurance contributions Income tax and National Insurance: a history of convergence The system from April 2003 Options for further reform 54 54 57 60 6 6.1 6.2 6.3 6.4 6.5 Company taxation and innovation policy The August 2002 consultation Dividend taxes North Sea taxation Stamp duty on shares R&D and policy towards innovation 64 64 68 71 74 75 7 7.1 7.2 7.3 7.4 Childcare subsidies Why subsidise childcare? Families’ employment and childcare use Options for subsidising childcare Potential numbers of eligible families and budget costs, holding childcare and employment constant Allowing childcare responses (holding employment constant) Considering employment responses Impacts across families Conclusions 85 86 87 89 92 4.1 4.2 4.3 7.5 7.6 7.7 7.8 1 42 44 48 51 53 95 100 101 102 8 8.1 8.2 Measuring public sector efficiency Efficiency measurement in the public sector Conclusions 105 106 110 9 9.1 9.2 The distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 What fiscal reforms? The distributional impact of reforms directly affecting households Limitations of the distributional analysis Taxes on business Stamp duty on residential properties Conclusion 112 112 115 Appendix A: Forecasting public finances Appendix B: Distributional effects of pre-announced direct tax and benefit reforms due in 2003–04 Appendix C: Budgets since 1979 Appendix D: Headline tax and benefit rates and thresholds Appendix E: Tax revenues ready reckoner 129 135 9.3 9.4 9.5 9.6 117 119 124 128 142 147 150 Figures Figure 2.1 Figure 2.2 Figure 2.3 Figure 2.4 Figure 2.5 HM Treasury estimates of the output gap Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income Public sector net debt as a percentage of national income Public sector net debt as a percentage of national income Estimated future payments under Private Finance Initiative contracts as a percentage of national income Revenues from stamp duty on shares and property Nominal growth in national income, the FTSE All-Share Index and house prices Non-North-Sea corporation tax revenues and forecasts as a share of national income Public sector net investment: out-turns and forecasts as a percentage of national income 8 9 12 15 16 Non-North-Sea corporation tax receipts and forecasts as a percentage of national income Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income 36 Figure 4.1 Figure 4.2 Figure 4.3 Figure 4.4 Child poverty (children in households with less than 60% median income AHC) Financial support for a family with one child under the outgoing system Financial support for a family with one child under the new tax credits Distributional effects of different increases in child-related benefits and tax credits in April 2004 44 46 47 52 Figure 5.1 Figure 5.2 Combined payroll tax schedule, 2003–04 Losses across the income distribution from National Insurance changes announced in the 2002 Budget, and from a package of similar changes to income tax 58 60 Figure 6.1 Figure 6.2 Figure 6.3 Figure 6.4 GERD as a percentage of GDP: G5 countries BERD as a percentage of GDP: G5 countries UK R&D levels: BERD and R&D Scoreboard UK BERD as a percentage of GDP: industry breakdown 76 78 78 79 Figure 8.1 SFA and DEA 108 Figure 9.1 Figure 9.2 Figure 9.3 Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997 Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997 Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997, with and without effect of stamp duty 116 118 127 Figure 2.6 Figure 2.7 Figure 2.8 Figure 2.9 Figure 3.1 Figure 3.2 22 22 25 27 40 Tables Table 2.1 Average errors in forecasting public sector net borrowing, as a percentage of national income and in £ billion Forecast capital spending by the public sector under both conventional finance and the Private Finance Initiative Public finances across the EU in 2001, percentage of national income The size of the AME margin 13 Comparison of Green Budget and HM Treasury forecasts for government borrowing, 2002–03 Comparison of Green Budget and HM Treasury forecasts for government borrowing, 2002–03 and 2003–04 Medium-term public finances forecasts, based on cautious macroeconomic assumptions Medium-term public finances forecasts, based on cautious macroeconomic assumptions 32 Table 4.1 Table 4.2 Possible changes in child poverty (AHC), 2000–01 to 2004–05 Effect of possible increases in per-child element of the child tax credit in April 2004 50 51 Table 5.1 Rates of income tax and National Insurance contributions, 2003–04 57 Table 6.1 Table 6.2 Table 6.3 Applicable taxes and marginal tax rates by date of approval of field Breakdown of R&D by who performs it and who funds it Percentages of BERD by who funds it 72 77 77 Table 7.1 Table 7.2 Table 7.3 Table 7.4 Employment patterns among families with children Childcare use for families with no parent working less than 16 hours each week Number of eligible families and costs of the childcare credit: childcare unchanged Number of eligible families and cost of the childcare credit: with potential childcare responses 87 88 93 98 Table 9.1 Table 9.2 Table 9.3 Table 9.4 Table 9.5 Revenue effects in 2003–04 of changes to taxes and benefits made since 1997 Revenue effects of major changes in ‘business taxes’ Rate of stamp duty on property, 1997 to present day Yield of stamp duty on residential property, 2001–02 Distribution of the value of homes worth more than £250,000, across the income distribution 113 122 124 125 126 Table A.1 130 Table A.2 Table A.3 Table A.4 A comparison of last year’s Green Budget forecast and the Treasury November 2001 Pre-Budget Report forecast with the estimated out-turn for 2001–02 from the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report IFS Green Budget and Treasury main errors in forecasting tax receipts, 2001–02 Forecasts for government borrowing in 2002–03 Main macroeconomic assumptions used in the baseline forecast Table B.1 Table B.2 Table B.3 Table B.4 Table B.5 Table B.6 Table B.7 Percentage gains across the income distribution from reforms in 2003–04 Weekly cash gains across the income distribution from reforms in 2003–04 Percentage gains from reforms in 2003–04, by family type Weekly cash gains from reforms in 2003–04, by family type Numbers of winners and losers, by family type Income bands for each decile for different family types Estimated number of families in Great Britain, by family type 138 138 139 139 140 141 141 Table E.1 Direct effects of illustrative changes in taxation to take effect April 2003 150 Table 2.2 Table 2.3 Table 2.4 Table 3.1 Table 3.2 Table 3.3 Table 3.4 14 19 29 33 37 38 130 132 134 1. Summary Planning the public finances The Chancellor’s tax and spending decisions are constrained by two selfimposed rules. The golden rule states that borrowing should only pay for investment, while the sustainable investment rule limits public debt to no more than 40% of national income. Both have to be satisfied over the economic cycle, but not every year. The Treasury judges progress against the golden rule by looking at the average surplus on the current budget (which excludes investment spending) since the beginning of the present economic cycle in 1999–2000. Large surpluses in the early years mean the golden rule is likely to be overachieved comfortably in the current cycle. But more important in framing the Budget should be whether the present stance of fiscal policy is consistent with meeting the golden rule looking forward. In the past, the Chancellor has sought to overachieve the golden rule by around 0.7% of national income. Treasury estimates suggest that this is enough to ensure that the golden rule would still be met if the trend level of economic activity consistent with stable inflation had been overestimated by 1%. In the 2002 Pre-Budget Report, the Chancellor forecast that the cyclically adjusted surplus would return to this level by 2007-08, but this prediction may be unduly reliant on factors such as ambitious forecasts for corporation tax receipts. The sustainable debt rule is not currently as binding as the golden rule, with the Treasury expecting the debt-to-GDP ratio to rise only fractionally to 33% by 2007–08. The debt measure used does not include all government liabilities – for example, some arising from the Private Finance Initiative. We estimate that if all capital spending under PFI deals signed to date were funded conventionally, public sector net debt would be 3.8% of national income higher by March 2006. If the UK were to join the Euro, fiscal policy might be further constrained by the Stability and Growth Pact and the Excessive Deficits Procedure in the Maastricht Treaty. The former requires member countries to aim in the medium term for a budget balance ‘close to balance or surplus’. The latter requires general government gross debt below 60% of GDP and a budget deficit of less than 3% of GDP (unless it is both exceptional and temporary or it is demonstrably declining towards these levels). The golden rule is by no means perfect, but a balanced-budget rule would make it more difficult to carry out investment that benefits future generations. But the Stability and Growth Pact might be interpreted in a less restrictive way by the time the UK joins the Euro – if it joins at all. The European Commission has suggested that the balanced-budget rule should be assessed with reference to where the economy stands in the economic cycle and that it should have scope to spread the cost of beneficial investment and tax reforms that raise employment or growth potential across generations. This would 1 Green Budget, January 2003 bring the Stability and Growth Pact slightly closer to the UK rules. In any event, the UK’s fiscal position is relatively strong in comparison with those of most Eurozone countries. IFS public finance forecasts In the Pre-Budget Report (PBR) last November, the Chancellor conceded that the unexpected weakness of the economy was depressing tax revenues and that this would force him to borrow more than he had expected this year and next. But over the medium term, he predicted that the economy would bounce back to its trend and that the public finances would return pretty much to the path he had expected in last April’s Budget. In the short run, our forecasts are very similar to those in the PBR. In 2002– 03, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £22.1 billion, slightly higher than the PBR forecast of £20.1 billion. In 2003–04, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £25.2 billion, again slightly higher than the £24.5 billion forecast in the PBR. We expect deficits on the current budget of £8.8 billion this year (compared with the Treasury’s £5.7 billion) and £5.1 billion next year (compared with the Treasury’s £4.9 billion). But in the medium term, we believe the public finances will be weaker than the PBR suggested in November, even if the economy behaves much as the Treasury expects. In part, this is because we do not expect that the loss of revenue that the Treasury attributes to the stock market and the plight of financial companies will recover as sharply as the Chancellor predicts. Hence, for example, we are less optimistic about the medium-term path of corporation tax revenues. By 2005–06, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £28 billion, compared with the PBR forecast of £19 billion. Nonetheless, we believe the Chancellor can credibly claim that both the golden rule and the sustainable investment rule will have been met comfortably over the current economic cycle, which is projected to end in 2005–06. We expect the government to overachieve the golden rule over the current cycle by around £31 billion, compared with the £46 billion the Chancellor predicted in November. But looking forward into the next cycle, our forecasts imply that spending cuts or tax increases will be required if the golden rule is to continue to be expected to be met. If the Chancellor sticks by his PBR forecasts, then he might well argue that no fiscal tightening is necessary. But if our forecasts are correct, he would be unlikely to be able to avoid such measures for long without undermining the credibility of the fiscal rules that he has set such store by. In that event, spending cuts would sit oddly with both the government’s stated objectives and its previous actions. Tax increases would, therefore, seem more likely. The tax increases required depend on how cautious the government wants to be. To expect to meet the golden rule exactly would, we estimate, require tax increases of around £4 billion. But in the past, the Chancellor has been more cautious and sought to overachieve the golden rule by around 0.7% of national income on average. To expect to do this would require tax increases of around £11 billion. 2 Summary What do the child poverty targets mean for child tax credit? The government has pledged to eradicate child poverty within a generation. As an intermediate target, it has also set itself the goal of reducing the number of children in poverty by at least a quarter by 2004. In practice, this means reducing by a quarter the number of children in households that have incomes below 60% of the median, which can be measured either before or after housing costs. Like the government, we focus on the latter measure. There were 4.2 million children in poverty on this definition in the base year of 1998–99, which implies a target of around 3.1 million in 2004–05. By 2000–01 (the last year for which we have data), the number of children in poverty on this definition had fallen to 3.9 million. So if the government is to hit its target, child poverty must fall by a further 0.8 million. This is an average of 200,000 a year, which is faster than it has fallen to date. Whether this will happen depends not only on the financial support that the government offers low-income families, but also on the impact of economic and demographic factors on their incomes and on the median income against which they are compared. The child tax credit, to be introduced in April 2003, will represent the majority of government support for children and is the government’s main instrument for targeting child poverty. Our best estimate is that existing tax and benefit reforms will take 800,000 children out of poverty between 2000–01 and 2004– 05, but that the rise in the median income from earnings growth will ‘move the goalposts’ and put 200,000 of them back in. This estimate implies that the government would fall 200,000 short of its target on the after-housing-costs measure, although there are considerable uncertainties around this prediction. (We assume that population, employment rates and household composition do not change, and that average earnings rise in line with recent trends.) If our estimates are correct, the government could argue that it is on course to hit its target on the before-housing-costs measure of poverty. But what could it do to expect to meet the target on the after-housing-costs measure? We estimate that taking a further 200,000 children out of poverty could be achieved by raising the per-child element of the child tax credit by £3 per week (on top of the increase in line with average earnings that has already been promised) at a cost of £1 billion. Out of the options that we consider, this is the most cost-effective, as it is the best-targeted at reducing poverty. Income tax and National Insurance contributions The income tax and National Insurance systems in the UK have become steadily more similar over the past 40 years. Gordon Brown’s decision to raise National Insurance from April – in part by requiring an employee contribution for the first time on all earnings above the upper earnings limit of £30,940 a year – is another step in this direction. Labour promised in the 1997 election campaign, and again in 2001, not to raise the basic or top rates of income tax. But the distributional impact of April’s increases in employer and employee National Insurance contribution rates will be similar to a 2p increase in the lower, basic and higher rates of income tax. Differences arise because income tax is levied on income from 3 Green Budget, January 2003 sources other than earnings, whereas National Insurance is paid only on earnings. The self-employed are also unaffected by the rise in the employer contribution rate. Given the erosion of the ‘contributory principle’ originally used to justify National Insurance – namely, that people’s social benefit entitlements were meaningfully linked to what they paid in – there now seems little economic justification for separate income tax and National Insurance systems. But this, and previous, governments appear to believe – for now at least – that voters are happier to pay more National Insurance than more income tax. This suggests that further gradual alignment of the two systems might be more likely than wholesale integration. Closing the gap between the earnings level at which employee National Insurance contributions drop from 11% to 1% (£30,940) and the income level at which income tax rises from 22% to 40% (£35,115) is an obvious next step and would also raise significant extra revenues for the Treasury. Revenue could also be raised by further increases in the rates of employer or employee National Insurance. The latter could be done solely on earnings above £30,940 if the Chancellor wanted to raise revenue in a very progressive way. Company taxation and innovation policy Last August, the government issued a consultation document on further reform to the corporation tax system. The objective of the proposals is to align the calculation of taxable profits more closely with the measurement of profits in company accounts. But replacing the current system of capital allowances with a deduction for the depreciation charge in accounts could see big winners and losers among different sectors. Other proposals would have implications for the extent to which companies could offset losses in one part of their business against profits elsewhere. In 1997, the UK government increased the taxation of dividend income for pension funds and some other institutional investors, with the goal of boosting investment. The USA is now proposing to reduce the taxation of dividends with partly the same objective. It is doubtful that the changes in either country will have much impact on investment or share prices. But the US reform would benefit US citizens who hold shares directly, with the wealthiest gaining most. The changes to North Sea taxation announced in the 2002 Budget and PreBudget Report raise extra revenue from this sector. They provide some welcome simplification and are in line with the principles of efficient resource taxation. But they could have gone further. The rules have been changed frequently in the past in response to revenue needs and changes in the oil price. A stable tax regime that could cope automatically with changing oil prices would help investment planning in the sector. Cutting stamp duty on share transactions would reduce distortions and may contribute to the Chancellor’s goal of boosting UK productivity. Stamp duty lacks investment allowances, and is therefore more likely to deter investment than other capital taxes. It reduces the efficiency of the stock market by raising transaction costs and may increase share price volatility. It also distorts merger 4 Summary and acquisition activity, producing a bias towards overseas rather than UK ownership of companies. Childcare subsidies Over the last decade, several initiatives have been undertaken to help families with the costs of childcare, both on distributional grounds and to encourage parents into paid work. Among them is the childcare credit in the working families’ tax credit, which will be transferred to the new working tax credit in April. The Chancellor has said that he wants to do more to help ‘parents to make real and effective choices on balancing work and family life’. Chapter 7 considers ways of extending the scope and generosity of the childcare credit. Options for reform might include: increasing the proportion of childcare costs that can be claimed; raising the cash ceiling on claims; extending the subsidy to ‘informal’ childcare provided by family and friends; allowing parents to claim if they work less than 16 hours a week; and making the means-testing of the credits more generous. Costing these reforms is difficult, as it is hard to predict how many parents would take up an expanded credit and to what extent they would change their employment behaviour and use of paid childcare. Covering a greater proportion of formal childcare costs or extending coverage to informal care could be very expensive if the change encouraged much greater use of subsidised childcare. There is also a danger that parents could claim more money from the government without any significant increase in childcare use. This suggests that any expansion of the childcare credit would have to be designed in such a way as to promote value for money. Such options could include: lowering the weekly ceilings on subsidised childcare spending; specifying the value of the credit per hour of childcare; linking the maximum subsidy to the main carer’s working hours; or linking eligibility to the employment and earnings of the main carer. Measuring public sector efficiency The government has staked its political credibility on delivering clear improvements in public services. Substantially increased resources are being ploughed into areas such as health, education and transport. The challenge for spending departments now is to ensure that these resources are used as efficiently as possible. To help achieve these improvements, the 2002 Spending Review set out performance targets in around 130 Public Service Agreements, covering both outcomes in particular services and the efficiency with which these outcomes are achieved. In April 2000, the Treasury’s Public Services Productivity Panel proposed a new approach to measuring the efficiency of police authorities, drawing on two techniques: stochastic frontier analysis and data envelopment analysis. The government has also commissioned research into their possible use to assess local authorities. The results of applying these efficiency measurement techniques are sensitive to a number of factors, including: which inputs and outputs are considered; 5 Green Budget, January 2003 errors in measuring these inputs and outputs; and the statistical assumptions made. While these methods are potentially useful, the results should be treated cautiously, as should their application as part of a system to affect providers’ performance incentives. The distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 The government has carried out many reforms to the tax and benefit system since coming to office in May 1997. Comparing the system as it will operate next year with that which Labour inherited (adjusted for inflation and statutory uprating) suggests that there have been around £51.7 billion of revenue-raising measures and £53.3 billion of revenue-reducing measures. This leaves a net ‘giveaway’ of around £1.6 billion, or about £1.50 per household per week. Analysing the distributional impact of such changes, IFS research traditionally focuses on measures that directly affect household incomes and spending. This shows a progressive pattern, varying from a boost of more than 15% to the incomes of the poorest tenth of the population to a loss of nearly 3% for the richest tenth. The average impact is an increase in income of around 2%. But focusing on those tax and benefit changes that are relatively easy to allocate to individual households shows a much more generous net ‘giveaway’ than taking all tax and benefit changes into account. Ultimately, all taxes have to be paid by individuals and including those that we do not model would reduce incomes on average by 1.7%, wiping out much of the average net gain. Taxes formally on business are one category that is excluded from our traditional distributional analysis. But assessing what ‘taxes on business’ are – and whether they have risen – is not easy. If we focus on taxes levied on company profits, the net impact of Labour’s reforms since 1997 is an estimated tax increase of around £4 billion in 2002–03, falling to an estimated £1.4 billion in the next year, as the transition to quarterly payments of corporation tax ends. Extending our distributional analysis by attributing this tax increase to households owning shares – who tend to be on relatively high incomes – might make Labour’s reforms look even more progressive. We estimate that the same is true of the increases Labour has implemented for stamp duty on house purchases since 1997. 6 2. Planning the public finances This chapter of the Green Budget discusses the planning of the public finances in the context of the fiscal rules that the government set for itself in 1998. Section 2.1 explains the rules and how compliance with them is assessed and looks at the errors made in the past when forecasting the public finances. It then examines whether getting the private sector to finance public investment can circumvent the rules. It concludes by comparing the current rules with the Growth and Stability Pact that would apply if Britain joined the Euro. Section 2.2 examines current issues that arise in planning and forecasting government revenues. It focuses on the effect of movements in the economic cycle and asset prices – with particular reference to stamp duty and corporation tax. Section 2.3 turns to current issues in forecasting and planning government spending. It focuses on public investment, public sector pay and the safety margin the government provides itself for unexpected spending demands. 2.1 The Chancellor’s fiscal rules In July 1998, the Chancellor outlined two fiscal rules that would constrain his tax and spending decisions. The stated rationale was to provide a credible framework within which the government could operate, to ensure the sustainability and fairness of the public finances. • The golden rule states that the government will only borrow to fund investment and not current expenditures. This aims to ensure that future generations will only be repaying debt the accumulation of which benefits them through the stock of capital it financed. • The sustainable investment rule states that public sector debt should remain at a ‘stable and prudent’ level, interpreted by the Chancellor as no more than 40% of national income. By constraining the total level of debt allowable, the long-term sustainability of the public finances is ensured.1 These rules have to be met over the ups and downs of the economic cycle, rather than each and every year. When activity in the economy runs below the trend level thought consistent with stable inflation, weaker profits and higher unemployment mean that tax receipts are lower and government spending higher than can be sustained over the long term. The resulting injection of spending power into the economy in itself helps take activity back up to a sustainable level. Conversely, when activity is above trend, temporarily buoyant tax receipts and lower social security costs take spending power out of the economy and help cool it down. Applying the fiscal rules over the cycle rather than in every year allows these ‘automatic stabilisers’ to operate 1 For a more in-depth discussion of the sustainability of the public finances, see HM Treasury, Long-Term Public Finance Report: An Analysis of Fiscal Sustainability, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/assoc_docs/prebud_pbr02_adsustain.cfm). 7 Green Budget, January 2003 unimpeded.2 The sustainability of the public finances is ensured since extra borrowing undertaken because the economy is below trend has to be repaid when it moves above trend.3 Assessing whether the golden rule is met The golden rule stipulates that the government’s borrowing should not exceed its spending on investment over the economic cycle. This means that tax revenue has to be sufficient, on average, to pay for the government’s current spending (including depreciation). In other words, the ‘current budget’ – the surplus of receipts over current spending – has to be in balance or in surplus on average over the cycle. Whether the golden rule has been met can only be judged definitively in retrospect, by examining the behaviour of the current budget over a full economic cycle. But it is hard to judge precisely where the economy is in the cycle at any given time. To do so, it is necessary to estimate the ‘output gap’ – a measure of where national income stands relative to the trend level assumed consistent with stable inflation. Figure 2.1. HM Treasury estimates of the output gap 4 Percentage of trend output 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 -4 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year Note: Actual output less trend output as a percentage of trend output (non-oil basis). Source: Chart A4 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). The Treasury’s estimates of the output gap from 1990 to 2008 are shown in Figure 2.1. The current cycle is assumed to have begun when output moved 2 The automatic stabilisers operate in the right direction, but the strength with which they do so is a function of the precise structure of the tax and benefits system and may not be optimal from the perspective of macroeconomic management. 3 A more detailed discussion of the government’s fiscal rules can be found in C. Emmerson and C. Frayne, The Government’s Fiscal Rules, Briefing Note no. 16, IFS, London, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/public/bn16.pdf). 8 Planning the public finances above trend in 1999–2000 following a mini-cycle between quarter 1 of 1997 and mid-1999. Output then fell below trend again in 2001–02. Stronger growth is forecast to close the negative output gap by 2005–06, bringing the current cycle to an end.4 Figure 2.2 shows the surplus on current budget from 1966–67 to 2007–08, according to HM Treasury forecasts. Since the introduction of the golden rule, the current budget has been in surplus every year. This is in contrast to most of the years from 1973–74 until 1997–98, when current budget deficits occurred in all but the three years from April 1988 to March 1991. Over the cycle running from 1986 to 1997, the golden rule was far from met. Current budget deficits averaging over 4% of national income between 1991–92 and 1996–97 far outweighed the modest surpluses in the previous years. Figure 2.2. Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income 8 Percentage of GDP 6 4 Actual HM Treasury November 2002 Pre-Budget Report forecast Cyclically adjusted surplus 2 0 -2 -4 -6 -8 66–67 69–70 72–73 75–76 78–79 81–82 84–85 87–88 90–91 93–94 96–97 99–00 02–03 05–06 Financial year Note: Measures exclude the windfall tax and associated spending. Source: HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank, January 2003, London, 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//4EC32/jan03web.xls). But how are we to judge whether the current fiscal position is consistent with the golden rule, when we are in the midst of an uncompleted cycle? The November 2002 Pre-Budget Report (PBR) measures progress ‘by the average surplus on the current budget since 1999–2000, which on the government’s provisional judgement is the start of the current cycle’.5 Over the first three years of the cycle, the current budget averaged surpluses of 1.7% of national income a year. The Treasury predicts deficits of 0.5% this year and 0.4% in 2003–04, reducing the average over the cycle to date to 0.8% next year. The 4 Whether the mini-cycle between quarter 1 1997 and mid-1999 survives future revisions must remain somewhat in doubt, as output fell only fractionally below trend even at its weakest point. As the Treasury concedes, it may turn out that the current cycle began in 1997 and that the initial upswing was longer than current estimates suggest. 5 Paragraph 2.51 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 9 Green Budget, January 2003 average since 1999–2000 is then expected to stabilise at 0.7% until the cycle ends. This implies that the golden rule will be overachieved comfortably during the current cycle, even if the upswing is weaker than expected and the negative output gap takes a year or two longer to close. In cash terms, the Chancellor said in November that he expected to end the current cycle with a cumulative current budget surplus of £46 billion.6 This implies he could run cumulative current deficits of nearly £50 billion between now and the end of the cycle in 2005–06 without breaking the golden rule, rather than the £2.7 billion he currently projects. But assessing compliance with the golden rule in this way can be unhelpfully backward-looking. Should the government really determine its fiscal room for manoeuvre by asking what deficits it can ‘afford’, given the size of the surpluses it has accumulated in the recent past? And what happens when the current cycle ends? Does the Treasury start again with a blank sheet of paper or does it argue that the deficits accumulated in the second half of the current cycle have to be offset by surpluses in the first half of the next? Economic cycles are an endlessly repeating process and any point in time could, in principle, be taken as the start of a new cycle or the end of an old one. In reaching their Budget judgements, chancellors confront the legacy of past fiscal policy decisions and external shocks in the form of the public debt and its servicing costs. But provided the debt is not in itself on an unsustainable path (for example, as long as the debt-to-GDP ratio is stable over time, which is a requirement of the sustainable investment rule), it is not clear that the current balances recorded in the past should dictate the current balances permitted in the future. More relevant is whether the current budget is on course to be in balance or surplus on average looking forward – or whether tax increases and/or spending cuts are needed to ensure that it is. The International Monetary Fund made a similar point in the concluding statement of its Article IV review of the UK economy in December: ‘It would be useful to assess whether the rules could be designed, or calibrated, so as to reduce their dependence on past over-performance, avoiding the risk that margins accumulated in the past allow excessive leeway in the future’.7 Symmetrically, it could have added that the rules should not mean that past deficits necessarily constrain the government to run an undesirably tight fiscal policy unless there is a risk of missing the debt-to-GDP target. Whether fiscal policy is consistent with the golden rule looking forward is best assessed by focusing on estimates of the current budget balance that are adjusted (albeit imperfectly) for the impact of the economic cycle. The Treasury estimates that a 1% fall in national income increases public sector net borrowing (the current budget balance plus net investment) by 0.5% of 6 Chancellor of the Exchequer’s Pre-Budget Report Statement, 27 November 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_speech.cfm). 7 International Monetary Fund, ‘United Kingdom – 2002 Article IV Consultation Concluding Statement’, 9 December 2002 (www.imf.org/external/np/ms/2002/120902a.htm). 10 Planning the public finances national income after one year and 0.2% after two years.8 So, given an estimate of the output gap, the Treasury can estimate what the underlying budget position would be if national income were at its trend level. The cyclically adjusted current balance is also shown in Figure 2.2. It suggests that the current budget moved into surplus in the late 1980s only because of the extent to which the economy was operating above trend, which inflated tax revenues and cut social security costs. Similarly, it suggests that the big rise in the deficit in the early 1990s reflected both the impact of the recession and a weaker underlying fiscal position. Over the present economic cycle, the actual current balance and the cyclically adjusted current balance are projected to have moved, and to continue to move, pretty closely in line. This reflects lower volatility in national income, and therefore smaller output gaps. The Treasury points to its forecast of an average current budget surplus of 0.7% of national income over this cycle as evidence of adequate caution in the setting of the public finances. The same could be said of its projections for the cyclically adjusted current budget, which is still just in surplus this year and next and which rises to 0.7% of national income by 2007–08. Projections of cyclically adjusted surpluses in future years could be interpreted as a reasonable indication that current policy is consistent with the golden rule, whatever the pattern of deficits or surpluses in the past. This, of course, requires that those projections are realistic and that they contain an appropriate margin for error, given the uncertainties inherent in determining the size of the output gap and in distinguishing between cyclical and underlying movements in the public finances. In the Treasury’s view, the golden rule will still be met even if the trend level of output turns out to be 1% lower than currently projected and if past surpluses therefore owed more to strong economic activity than to the underlying health of the public finances. The average current balance since the start of the cycle would remain positive throughout. Less reassuringly, the cyclically adjusted current balance would be consistently in deficit and only move back to balance by 2007–08. Whether 0.7% of national income is an adequate cushion is a matter of judgement. It would not have been large enough to avoid missing the golden rule given some errors in estimating trend output in the past. But the reduced volatility of national income in the latest cycle suggests such errors are perhaps unlikely to be as large as they were in the late 1980s and early 1990s. Let us assume, for the sake of argument, that trend output has been estimated correctly. Just as important a question in judging whether policy is now consistent with the golden rule is whether it is realistic to expect the cyclically adjusted current balance to rise to 0.7% over the next few years, as forecast in the PBR, without further tax increases or cuts in spending plans. (If this level were achieved and then maintained, the government would have the same level of caution built into its projections looking forward as it has signalled it was looking for in the past.) This prediction may be unduly reliant on 8 Paragraph B17 on page 185 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 11 Green Budget, January 2003 ambitious forecasts – for example, for corporation tax receipts and movements in equity and housing markets, which are discussed in Section 2.2. Assessing whether the sustainable investment rule is met While the golden rule imposes a binding constraint on the government, this is not currently true of the sustainable investment rule. Figure 2.3 shows public sector net debt as a share of national income from 1974–75 to 2007–08. This has declined steadily from 43.7% of national income in March 1997, just before Labour took office, to 30.4% of national income in March 2002. Net debt is set to rise over the next six years, to reach 33.0% of national income in March 2008 according to Treasury plans for receipts and spending. Assuming that the golden rule is met, the government would need to spend an additional 7.0% of national income on public sector net investment to breach the sustainable investment rule. Given the difficulty that the government is having in increasing public sector net investment spending from an historical low of 0.5% of national income in 1999–2000 to 2.0%, such an increase seems highly unlikely. Figure 2.3. Public sector net debt as a percentage of national income 80 Percentage of GDP 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 74–75 77–78 80–81 83–84 86–87 89–90 92–93 95–96 98–99 01–02 04–05 07–08 Financial year Source: HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank, January 2003, London, 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//4EC32/jan03web.xls). Errors made in the past in predicting budget balances In the 2002 PBR last November, the Treasury revised down the estimates of the current budget balance for this year and next that it published in the Budget last April. For the current financial year, it now forecasts a current deficit of 0.5% of national income, rather than a surplus of 0.3%, and for 2003–04, it forecasts a 0.4% deficit, rather than a 0.6% surplus. Both revisions are almost entirely due to lower-than-expected revenues. These forecasts are still consistent with cyclically adjusted surpluses in each year, but of only 0.2% and 0.3% of national income respectively. It would take only a small 12 Planning the public finances forecasting error to see a cyclically adjusted deficit in one or both years. If such a deficit were maintained indefinitely, the golden rule would be missed. Table 2.1 shows the Treasury’s average error in forecasting public sector net borrowing (PSNB) – the current balance plus net investment – one, two, three and four years ahead between 1985–86 and 1997–98. It shows that even one year ahead, the average absolute error is £12.5 billion in today’s prices. Even when the effect of misforecasting national income has been stripped out, there is still an average error of £10.4 billion. Underestimating borrowing by even half that magnitude for 2003–04 would lead to a cyclically adjusted deficit on current budget.9 Table 2.1. Average errors in forecasting public sector net borrowing, as a percentage of national income and in £ billion Time period Average error (% GDP) Average error (£bn) Average error, Average error, correct GDP correct GDP (% GDP) (£bn) One year ahead 1.2 12.5 1.0 10.4 Two years ahead 2.0 20.9 1.4 14.6 Three years ahead 3.0 31.3 2.0 20.9 Four years ahead 4.1 42.8 2.4 25.1 Notes: Figures in £ billion are calculated assuming HM Treasury GDP forecast for 2002–03 of £1,044 billion. Average error corresponds to the average absolute error over the period 1985– 86 to 1997–98. Source: Table B13 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, November 1998, Cm. 4076 (http://archive.treasury.gov.uk/pub/html/prebudgetNov98/index.html). For the last two fiscal years, 2000–01 and 2001–02, the error in forecasting PSNB has been slightly lower, averaging 0.9% of national income. The Endof-Year Fiscal Report, published by HM Treasury alongside the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report, shows the errors made in forecasting borrowing one year ahead from 1989–90 to 2001–02. Over these years, the average error was 1.1% – slightly lower than the 1.2% presented in Table 2.1. Not surprisingly, borrowing tends to be underestimated when economic activity is weak. The Private Finance Initiative and the interpretation of the fiscal rules The fiscal rules constrain policy by requiring that public sector deficits and debt do not exceed particular levels over the economic cycle. Yet the definition of public sector net debt used does not measure the full cost of activities carried out on behalf of the public sector. This raises the possibility that the government could circumvent the fiscal rules by financing spending through liabilities that are not covered by the sustainable investment rule. This is possible under the Private Finance Initiative (PFI). If a public investment project is paid for by conventional deficit financing, then the cost will appear immediately as public sector investment, and add to both public sector net borrowing and public sector net debt. In future years, 9 If the error were in public sector net investment, then this would not lead to a change in the current budget surplus. 13 Green Budget, January 2003 the depreciation of the asset purchased, and the additional debt interest repayments, will score as current expenditure and reduce the size of any current budget surplus. Alternatively, the government might use the private sector to finance and deliver the project. In this scenario, the cost of the capital spending would initially be paid for by the PFI contractor rather than scoring against public sector net borrowing. This would reduce public sector net borrowing and net debt compared with what they would have been under the conventional finance route. Initially, this would make the sustainable investment rule easier to meet. Use of the PFI would also reduce depreciation costs, as the public sector capital stock is lower. The reduction in public sector net debt would also reduce future debt interest payments. But the annual stream of payments to the PFI contractor would score as current expenditure. If a private contractor were able to deliver a public sector investment project with efficiency gains that precisely offset their higher borrowing costs, then the project would cost exactly the same as under conventional finance. Hence it would not make the golden rule easier or harder to meet.10 The only economic rationale for using the PFI is that it is hoped it will offer better value for money. Despite the fact that the private sector faces higher borrowing costs, these are expected to be offset by its greater operating efficiency.11 If this holds, the private contractor can provide a given standard of public service at a lower cost, which will, all other things remaining equal, lead to lower levels of public borrowing. Table 2.2. Forecast capital spending by the public sector under both conventional finance and the Private Finance Initiative 2002–03 2003–04 2004–05 2005–06 Public sector net investment (£bn) 14.3 19.6 21.9 24.1 Depreciation (£bn) 14.1 14.7 15.4 16.2 Asset sales (£bn) 3.8 3.8 3.8 3.8 Public sector gross investment (£bn) 32.2 38.1 41.1 44.1 Capital spending by the private sector (£bn) 3.7 3.3 2.5 2.5 Total publicly sponsored gross investment (£bn) 35.9 41.4 43.6 46.6 PFI investment as a % of total publicly sponsored 10.3% 8.0% 5.7% 5.4% gross investment Notes: Figures on capital spending by the private sector correspond to signed deals only. Figure for 2005–06 is an estimate. Source: Table 2.1 on page 10 of HM Treasury, Spending Review 2002: Departmental Investment Strategies: A Summary, Cm. 5674, Stationery Office, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//343A6/dis_whitepaper02.pdf). Most publicly sponsored investment is still conducted through conventional means rather than through the PFI. In 2002–03, total publicly sponsored 10 Assuming that payments are structured so that the annual payments to the private contractor correspond to the flow of services received. 11 For a discussion of issues arising from private sector involvement in the delivery of public services, see chapter 3 of A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/gb2002/chap3.pdf). 14 Planning the public finances investment is expected by the Treasury to be £35.9 billion, of which just £3.7 billion, or 10.3%, will be financed by the private sector. Table 2.2 shows the share of public investment financed through the PFI declining. This is because the figures are based on deals that have been signed so far. Whether the share actually declines will depend on how many new PFI contracts are agreed. If current policy continues, we can expect to see a steady increase in the number of PFI contracts signed, leading to higher forecasts for government spending on the PFI. On the basis of deals signed so far, public sector net debt at the end of March 2006 would be 3.8% of national income higher if all the capital spending from PFI deals signed so far been carried out using conventional finance.12 This is shown in Figure 2.4. Should further PFI deals be signed, then net debt would be higher still. But it would remain comfortably below the government’s 40% ceiling unless there were an unfeasibly large increase in investment spending (either financed conventionally or through the PFI) or unless the golden rule were also breached, in which case some of the additional borrowing would represent current rather than investment spending. Figure 2.4. Public sector net debt as a percentage of national income 60 Public sector net debt plus capital spending carried out under the PFI Public sector net debt Percentage of GDP 50 40 30 20 10 0 90–91 92–93 94–95 96–97 98–99 00–01 02–03 04–05 Financial year Source: HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank, January 2003, London, 2003 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/media//4EC32/jan03web.xls). Capital spending carried out under the PFI from T. Clark, M. Elsby and S. Love, ‘Trends in public investment’, Fiscal Studies, 2002, vol. 23, pp. 305–42. So far, we have focused on what would have happened to the public debt had conventional finance been used to deliver all of the public sector investment projects that have been financed through PFI deals. An alternative approach is to look at the stream of payments that the government is committed to paying PFI providers in return for the services that they are providing. 12 This assumes that the public sector could have carried out the investment spending at the same cost as the private provider. 15 Green Budget, January 2003 The expected payments over the next 25 years from PFI contracts that have already been agreed are shown in Figure 2.5. It shows that if no further contracts are agreed, payments should rise to 0.45% of national income in 2003–04 before falling to less than 0.1% of national income in the mid-2020s. Again, as with the figures on capital spending by the private sector, this decline is unlikely to materialise because new contracts should be signed. We can therefore expect upward revisions to the projected future flow of payments under the PFI as we have seen in recent Budgets, as is shown in Figure 2.5. Figure 2.5. Estimated future payments under Private Finance Initiative contracts as a percentage of national income 0.50 Percentage of national income 2002 Budget 2001 Budget 0.40 2000 Budget 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 1998–99 2003–04 2008–09 2013–14 Year 2018–19 2023–24 Sources: Table C15 on page 208 of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC346, March 2000; Table C18 on page 206 of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC279, March 2001; Table C10 on page 232 of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, April 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_index.cfm). Summing the payments due until March 2028 (as a share of national income) gives a total of 5.9% of national income, equivalent to £62 billion in today’s prices. But only around 22% of these payments are to finance the initial capital investment.13 The rest will pay for current goods and services – for example, the delivery of usable hospital beds rather than a hospital building. Do the government’s contractual obligations to fund this spending mean that the £62 billion (5.9% of national income) should be regarded as a component of public sector net debt? If so, it would bring the debt level far closer to the ceiling of 40% of national income set by the Chancellor’s sustainable investment rule. It should be noted, though, that £26 billion out of this £62 billion represents payments that are due to be made before March 2008. These are included in the government’s published plans for future current 13 Arthur Anderson and Enterprise LSE, Value for Money Drivers in the Private Finance Initiative, London, 2000. 16 Planning the public finances spending and therefore score against both future public sector net borrowing and future public sector net debt. Including the estimated stream of future payments would provide an estimate of the increase in public sector net debt that we might expect to see if the government decided to pay for all of these contracts upfront and continue to receive the services that they provide in the future.14 But it is far from clear that including them in public sector net debt would be particularly sensible. For one thing, there are large parts of public spending that the government (and all political parties) are, in practice, no less committed to than payments to PFI contractors. Examples of such spending include the provision of many public services (such as some healthcare) free at the point of use and increases in many welfare benefits (such as the basic state pension) at least in line with inflation. These de facto liabilities are not added to public sector net debt – and if they were, they would add up to a very large proportion of national income. They are paid for conventionally out of future national income when the services they provide are consumed.15 One could also argue that future payments to PFI providers are different from these other liabilities because they are contractual obligations. But if the government were to decide that it no longer wanted the services that it had bought from these private providers, it should be able to negotiate a substantial discount on the contracted payments because they would no longer have to provide them. The provider would doubtless still demand sufficient payment from the government to cover the cost of the initial capital investment. In any event, the future stream of payments due to PFI providers does not necessarily represent an unavoidable cost to a future government that might not want to consume some packages of services that its predecessors have signed up to. On balance, including the stream of future payments as public sector net debt on transparency grounds does not seem particularly sensible. It would also provide an incentive for governments not to use the PFI even if this offered demonstrably better value for money than conventional finance. There is also nothing sacrosanct about the ceiling of 40% of national income placed by the Chancellor on a particular measure of government debt. Economic theory has little to tell us about what an optimal debt-to-GDP ratio is, just that it should not be allowed to increase continuously over time. The Chancellor could just as easily have chosen a different measure of debt, or a different percentage. Indeed, if the Chancellor had chosen a measure of debt that included the future financing of PFI contracts, he may well have chosen a target higher than 40%. 14 The actual value would depend on the discount rate of the private sector. Using the £62 billion calculated above would assume a discount rate equal to nominal growth in national income of 4.8% (which comprises long-term real growth in national income of 2¼% and inflation of 2½%). 15 Whether or not current government policy is sustainable in the medium and long term can be examined, under a number of assumptions, using generational accounts. See HM Treasury, Long-Term Public Finance Report: An Analysis of Fiscal Sustainability, November 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/assoc_docs/prebud_pbr02_adsustain.cfm). 17 Green Budget, January 2003 The Stability and Growth Pact Should the UK decide to join the Euro, fiscal policy might be further constrained by the Stability and Growth Pact. This requires member countries to set a medium-term budgetary objective of ‘close to balance or surplus’. This implies either higher taxes or lower public spending than required by the golden rule since it prohibits the government from borrowing to invest. Joining the Euro also formally requires the UK government to comply with the Excessive Deficits Procedure in the Maastricht Treaty. This requires that general government gross debt should be below 60% of national income and that deficits should be below 3% of national income. Should these criteria not be met (either in terms of actual outcomes or in terms of plans), the European Council could choose to apply penalties such as fines. The danger with a balanced-budget rule is that it could inappropriately prevent spending on beneficial investment projects that are prohibitively expensive for current taxpayers alone to finance, because it would not permit future generations to bear part of the cost.16 This seems unreasonable, given that individuals often choose to fund long-term purchases by borrowing – for example, paying for a house with a mortgage. As we discussed earlier, the golden rule does make a distinction between capital and current spending and therefore would allow such investment projects to go ahead. This is not to say that the golden rule is necessarily ideal. For one thing, it is hard to decide whether some categories of spending (e.g. education) should be current or capital. Neither is it clear that the golden rule delivers true intergenerational fairness, because the timing of the flow of services financed by borrowing may not coincide with the timing of payments on the debt. It is possible that the balanced-budget rule – or at least its interpretation – might be relaxed by the time the UK joined the Euro. EU President Romano Prodi has stated that ‘the stability pact is stupid, like all decisions that are rigid’.17 Also, in a November 2002 Communication to the European Council and Parliament, the European Commission argued that the balanced-budget rule should be interpreted using a cyclically adjusted measure of the budget position and that countries with debt ‘well below the 60% reference level’ would be allowed small deviations from the balanced-budget rule. In parallel, the Commission argued that the balanced-budget rule ‘could be required to cater for the inter-temporal budgetary impact of large structural reforms (such as productive investment or tax reforms) that raise employment or growth potential’.18 While these changes would not make the Stability and Growth 16 An argument made in favour of a balanced-budget rule is that a golden rule would simply provide an incentive for countries to redefine how they classify investment spending and, in particular, how depreciation is measured. This is discussed in, for example, M. Buti, S. Eijffinger and D. Franco, ‘Revisiting the Stability and Growth Pact: grand design or internal adjustment?’, Centre for Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper no. 3692, 2002 (www.cepr.org/pubs/new-dps/dplist.asp?dpno=3692). 17 Interview to the Le Monde newspaper, 17 October 2002. 18 Commission of the European Communities, Communication from the Commission to the Council and the European Parliament, COM (2002) 668 final, Brussels, 27 November 2002. 18 Planning the public finances Pact criteria identical to the UK fiscal rules, they would certainly bring them closer – not least by potentially allowing higher deficits to finance investment spending, provided debt is significantly lower than the 60% mark. Table 2.3 shows how in 2001 the UK compared with other EU countries in terms of both government borrowing and debt. In that year at least, the UK had a relatively strong public balance (net borrowing or lending), with a surplus of 0.8% of national income compared with a weighted average of – 0.8% across the entire EU and –1.5% across the Eurozone. Equally, when the cyclically adjusted measure of the public balance is considered, the UK’s surplus of 0.6% of national income compares favourably with both the EU weighted average of –1.0% and the –1.5% average in the Eurozone countries. The UK also had a relatively low level of general government gross debt (39.1% of national income compared with a weighted EU average of 63.1% and a weighted Eurozone average of 69.2%). Table 2.3. Public finances across the EU in 2001, percentage of national income Public balance Cyclically adjusted Debt public balance Portugal –4.1 –4.6 55.5 Germany –2.8 –2.4 59.5 Italy –2.2 –2.1 109.8 France –1.4 –1.7 57.3 Greece –1.2 –1.7 107.0 Spain –0.1 –0.2 57.1 Netherlands 0.1 –0.2 52.8 Austria 0.2 0.1 63.2 Belgium 0.4 0.3 107.6 UK 0.8 0.6 39.1 Ireland 1.5 –0.1 36.4 Denmark 3.1 2.9 44.7 Sweden 4.8 4.7 56.6 Finland 4.9 5.1a 43.4 Luxembourg 6.1 n/a 5.6 Unweighted EU average 0.7 0.1b 59.7 Weighted EU average –0.8 –1.0 63.1 b Unweighted Eurozone 0.1 –0.7 62.9 Weighted Eurozone –1.5 –1.5 69.2 a Given as a proportion of mainland potential GDP. The figure excludes revenues from oil production. b These unweighted averages exclude Luxembourg. Note: Public balance refers to net borrowing or lending of consolidated general government sector. Debt refers to general government consolidated gross debt. Source: EUROSTAT website (http://europa.eu.int/comm/eurostat/) and OECD, Economic Outlook, no. 72, December 2002 (www.oecd.org/EN/document/0,,EN-document-0nodirectorate-no-2-21578-0,00.html). Even if the interpretation of the balanced-budget rule were to be relaxed – for example, by allowing countries with a relatively low level of debt to borrow more – the UK might still be constrained by the Excessive Deficits Procedure. UK public sector net investment is forecast to grow to 2.0% of national 19 Green Budget, January 2003 income in 2005–0619 (which is the last year of the current Spending Review period). Even with a balance on the cyclically adjusted current budget, the limit on borrowing of 3% of national income would be being breached if economic growth in 2004–05 were more than 1¼ percentage points lower than expected and there were no bounce-back in the following year.20 2.2 Planning and forecasting revenues Most tax revenues tend to follow the ups and downs of the economic cycle, because they are levied on elements of incomes and spending that move roughly in line with activity in the economy as a whole. For example, when the economy is strong, more people will be in paid employment and paying income tax and National Insurance. As earnings generally rise in excess of inflation, over time people will also tend to be pulled into higher income tax brackets. The number of higher-rate taxpayers has increased from 1.7 million in 1990–91 to an estimated 3.1 million in 2002–03.21 This process of ‘fiscal drag’ results from the progressive structure of the tax system and means that income tax receipts tend to rise as a proportion of national income. As we discussed in Section 2.1, it is possible to adjust revenue (and spending) figures for the impact of the economic cycle and thereby better gauge the underlying strength of the public finances. But this is never easy, and it may be particularly difficult now. One important reason is that some tax revenues are affected significantly by movements in asset markets, such as the housing market and the stock market. These tend to be prone to longer, more pronounced and less predictable cycles than economic activity as a whole. This is evident from the boom and recent decline in the stock market, with fears mounting in recent months that the housing market is due for a similar setback after a lengthy period of strong growth. A recent study published by the European Central Bank concluded that asset price movements are an important determinant of budget balances in many countries – over and above the impact of the cycle in national income.22 But the study found that this effect was particularly marked in the UK. There is a danger that the Treasury has underestimated the impact of asset price movements on the public finances. This may mean that revenues bounce back 19 Table B6 on page 191 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 20 The Treasury estimates that a 1 percentage point reduction in growth increases borrowing by 0.5% of national income in the first year and by a further 0.3% of national income the following year. Therefore a 1¼ percentage point reduction in growth would increase borrowing by 1% of national income in the following year. This, added to the 2% planned investment spending, would lead to public sector borrowing of 3% of national income. Source: Paragraph B17 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 21 Inland Revenue, Inland Revenue Statistics (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats/income_tax/it_t01_1.htm). 22 F. Eschenbach and L. Schuknecht, ‘Asset prices and fiscal balances’, European Central Bank, Working Paper no. 141, 2002 (www.ecb.int/pub/wp/ecbwp141.pdf). 20 Planning the public finances less sharply than the Chancellor expects as the economy moves back to trend output. This would make it harder to be confident of meeting the golden rule. The stock market has a direct impact on revenues via stamp duty, which is levied on share transactions (and also property transactions). We discuss both types of stamp duty in greater detail below. The stock market also has an indirect effect by influencing the fortunes of financial companies, which pay corporation tax and whose employees contribute to income tax and National Insurance receipts. In the November 2002 PBR, the government revised down its revenue forecasts by £5 billion specifically because of the plight of financial sector companies. This comes on top of a £3½ billion downward revision for other stock market effects. Although income tax revenues generally track movements in the economy, in recent years they have come in more strongly than anticipated by the Treasury. For example, the March 2001 Budget revised upwards its forecast of income tax revenues in 2001–02 by £6 billion compared with the forecast made a year earlier.23 If a significant proportion of the unexpected increases in income tax receipts was due to the strength of the stock market, then there has to be some concern about the path that income tax receipts will take in the future. Corporation tax (CT) revenues have become increasingly reliant on the financial sector too in recent years, with the share coming from that quarter doubling from 18% to 36% between 1990 and 2000 alone.24 This helps explain the recent weakness of CT revenues (which we discuss in greater detail below) and suggests that the future path of CT revenues will depend much more than in the past on the performance of the financial sector. Unless one is willing to assume that stock markets and financial companies’ profits soon return to the unusual levels of performance seen in the late 1990s, it seems doubtful that corporation tax revenues will rebound as quickly as the Chancellor expects. Even if the stock market does recover strongly, boosting the financial sector, there remain risks to the UK public finances from the uncertain prospects for house prices. Even a relatively small fall in house prices, if associated with a sharp decrease in the volume of sales, could have a big impact on stamp duty revenues and a smaller impact on inheritance tax and capital gains tax. Moreover, any downturn in the housing market could lead to a decline in consumer confidence and a corresponding fall in revenues from VAT. A third asset price effect could operate through the currency market. Some analysts expect a sharp drop in sterling, accompanied by a rebalancing in the economy away from consumer spending and towards exports. As the government receives more tax revenue from each pound of the former than of the latter, this too could have a sustained depressing effect on tax revenues. We now turn to stamp duty and corporation tax in more detail. 23 See paragraph C37 of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC279, March 2001. 24 Tables 11.4 and 11.5 of Inland Revenue, Inland Revenue Statistics, various years. 21 Green Budget, January 2003 Stamp duty We can see the impact of asset markets on the UK public finances in the path of revenues from stamp duty on property and share transactions. The tax bases for these duties are directly related to the level of prices and volume of transactions in the housing market and stock market respectively. Figure 2.6. Revenues from stamp duty on shares and property Percentage of national income 0.5 0.4 Stamp duties on stocks and shares Stamp duties on property 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.0 1980-81 1983-84 1986-87 1989-90 1992-93 1995-96 1998-99 2001-02 Financial year Source: Inland Revenue Statistics, various years. Figure 2.7. Nominal growth in national income, the FTSE All-Share Index and house prices 40.0 National income FTSE All-Share Index Halifax house price index Nominal growth (%) 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 -10.0 -20.0 1980-81 1983-84 1986-87 1989-90 1992-93 1995-96 1998-99 2001-02 Financial year Source: GDP – ONS, www.statistics.gov.uk; Halifax house price index – HBOSplc, www.hbosplc.com/view/housepriceindex/housepriceindex.asp; FTSE – Thomson Financial Datastream, www.datastream.com. 22 Planning the public finances Revenues from these taxes between 1980–81 and 2001–02 are shown as a share of national income in Figure 2.6. Annual growth in national income, house prices and the FTSE All-Share Index are shown in Figure 2.7. As the increases in national income, the FTSE All-Share and house prices are shown in nominal terms, they will be higher at times of high inflation, other things being equal. The figures confirm that stamp duty revenues do not have a consistent relationship with economic growth. Instead, stamp duty on property tracks movements in house prices, although stamp duty on stocks and shares has, at best, a weak lagged correlation with share prices. In the case of stocks and shares, the volume of transactions plays an important role, and a high volume need not be linked to a bull market. It should be noted that stamp duty on shares was cut from 2% to 0.5% during the mid-1980s, while the stamp duty rate on property has been increased four times since Labour came into power in May 1997.25 But these changes do not alter the underlying picture. For most of the years from 1980–81 to the late 1990s, stamp duty revenues from stocks and shares were broadly constant as a proportion of national income – despite the cuts in the rate of stamp duty on shares in the mid-1980s. The peak observed in 1988–89 did coincide with strong economic growth, both in the current and the previous financial year. But the dramatic revenue increases observed since 1995–96 come at a time of unspectacular economic growth. These increases in stamp duty revenues do, then, appear to be explained by a rising stock market and also an increase in the number of shares and share turnover, rather than by economic growth.26 Revenues from stamp duty on property transactions also diverge from the path of the wider economy. From 1970–71 to the mid-1980s, they rose slowly. From 1985–86 to 1995–96, they followed the economy with a lag of a year or two. Since then, the pattern has been broadly in line with revenues from stamp duty on stocks and shares, rising steadily despite average economic performance. Despite the obvious contribution of increases in the rate of stamp duty on property since May 1997, an important factor has been the rise in the housing market, which has increased in value by over 75%. Taking out the effect of the increases in rates would still leave revenues from property by 2001–02 being more than double the revenue in 1996–97. Corporation tax Corporation tax accounts for a relatively modest 12% of total tax revenues.27 But it plays an important role in explaining movements in the public finances 25 See Chapter 9 for more details on changes to stamp duty on property in recent years. 26 For more details and an assessment of the economic impact of stamp duty on shares, see M. Hawkins and J. McCrae, Stamp Duty on Share Transactions: Is There a Case for Change?, Commentary no. 89, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/comm89.pdf). 27 This is the average over calendar years 1987 to 2001. Data source: National Statistics, Financial Statistics, The Stationery Office, London 23 Green Budget, January 2003 because it is one of the most volatile sources of tax revenue. More than half the cut in revenue forecasts made in the 2002 PBR came in corporation tax.28 Whether or not such a fall is worrying will depend on whether corporation tax revenues can be relied upon to bounce back soon. The government believes they can. In 2001–02, corporation tax raised 2.9% of national income.29 The Treasury expects this to fall to 2.5% for two years and then return to 2.9% in 2004–05. In the following two years, the forecasts predict even higher revenues, of 3.2% and 3.3% of national income respectively. This sounds reassuring, but is it credible? Since Budget 2001, corporation tax forecasts have been cut on three consecutive occasions in the light of disappointing outturns. Each downward revision of the forecast for the near future has been accompanied by an upward revision of the growth rate of revenues for later years. This implies that almost the entire revenue decline is attributed to cyclical or other temporary factors that will soon reverse. But even if one were to accept that the entire fall in revenues were due to such factors, the long-run forecast of 3.3% would still seem optimistic, as Figure 2.8 illustrates. This figure shows corporation tax revenues as a share of national income over the last 15 years (thick black line) and predictions for the following five years (thick grey line). Over the last 15 years, corporation tax revenues averaged 3.2% of national income. While this seems very close to the forecast, it ignores the fact that tax rates have been cut. Revenues also received a temporary boost in the four years from 1999–2000 to 2002–03 from the introduction of a payment system in quarterly instalments (see Chapter 9). This had the effect of bringing tax payments forward and thus led to companies paying more than one year’s tax per year during the transition to the new system. The dotted line shows an approximation of the revenues that would have been raised with current tax rates and having stripped out the temporary effect of the introduction of quarterly payments. These adjustments shift the graph downwards in each of the last 15 years. The average yield, represented by a thin grey line, drops to only around 2.9% of national income. This casts some doubt on the long-term forecast of 3.3%. Not only is the forecast clearly above the average of what the current system would have raised (despite the fact that the Treasury does not currently forecast output rising above trend after 2005– 06), but also it is set so high that the forecast level would only have been reached three times during the last 15 years according to our adjusted series. The predicted level of corporation tax revenues for the long term therefore seems unduly optimistic, especially given the importance of the financial sector we noted earlier. 28 Forecasted tax revenues fell by £6 billion; the cut in forecasted corporation tax revenues contributed £3.7 billion to this figure. Source: Table B9 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 29 This and the following figures exclude corporation tax revenues from the continental shelf and are gross of enhanced and payable tax credits. Source: HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 24 Planning the public finances Figure 2.8. Non-North-Sea corporation tax revenues and forecasts as a share of national income Percentage of national income 5.0% Estimated outcomes Adjusted series Forecasts Average (of adjusted) 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% 87–88 89–90 91–92 93–94 95–96 97–98 99–00 01–02 03–04 05–06 07–08 Year Notes: The adjusted series shows the tax revenue that the current tax system would have raised in previous years. It takes account of the fact that tax rates have been reduced in two steps from 33% to 30% and that the introduction of a quarterly payments system boosted revenues temporarily between 1999–2000 and 2002–03. Sources: Inland Revenue, Inland Revenue Statistics, London, 2002; HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm); Inland Revenue, ‘A Modern System for Corporation Tax Payments’, Press Release IR 9, 17 March 1998. Corporation tax revenues are very volatile and difficult to predict, and frequent revisions are not surprising. It makes sense not to change long-term forecasts every time short-term revenues change. But when revisions always go in the same direction, the long-term forecasts need to be questioned at some point. Looking further ahead, other forces may affect the UK’s ability to raise revenue from corporate income taxes. These include more intense tax competition between governments and possible action by the European Court of Justice in response to company complaints or new European Union directives. 2.3 Planning government spending Since taking office in 1997, the government has substantially reformed the planning and presentation of government spending, including the creation of new aggregates with which to measure it. Total managed expenditure (TME) is the broadest measure of public sector spending. At 40.2% of national income in 2002–03, it is currently lower than the 41.0% spent in the last year 25 Green Budget, January 2003 of the Conservative government (1996–97). But TME is now set to rise to 42.3% by 2007–08.30 TME is divided into annually managed expenditure (AME) and departmental expenditure limits (DELs), with around 45% of TME falling in AME and the remaining 55% in DELs. AME is planned on an annual basis, as its name suggests, and includes spending on items that are deemed more difficult to plan years in advance, such as social security and debt interest payments. DELs include spending plans for most government departments and, since 1998, are set up to three years in advance in biennial Spending Reviews. The third Spending Review, in July 2002, revised the plans set out in July 2000 for spending in 2003–04, and set out new spending limits for the years 2004–05 and 2005–06. The plans for 2005–06 are expected to be revised in the next Spending Review, in July 2004, which will also unveil plans for 2006–07 and 2007–08. Unusually, we do have some information about spending in those two years, as the April 2002 Budget set out the NHS spending plans for all years until 2007–08. These allow for an average annual real increase in NHS spending of 7.3% by 2007–08 compared with last year. The point of having Spending Reviews that set DELs up to three years in advance is that it should allow departments to plan their spending with a longer-term perspective. In recent years, the government has added money to DELs between Spending Reviews. But this is unlikely in the forthcoming Budget due to the weakness of receipts, which has already led to upward revisions in the borrowing forecasts, and due to the fact that the last Spending Review was only in July 2002. Instead, we are likely only to see revisions to AME. Planning departmental expenditure limits In the early years of the current planning regime, several departments failed to spend their full allocations and overall spending under DELs came in lower than planned. It was argued that this may have been partly due to the introduction of End-Year Flexibility, which gave departments an entitlement to spend any of their unspent allocation for a given year in subsequent years. The idea was to remove the incentive that previously existed for departments to spend all their money at the end of a financial year, even if they could have obtained better value for money by spending it later. Spending out-turn figures for 2001–02 show that underspending on current items has ceased to be a problem. Figures to date for 2002–03 show that, if anything, current spending is increasing faster than the plans allow.31 But the delivery of investment spending remains problematic. Figure 2.9 shows investment spending as a percentage of national income from 1979–80 to 2005–06 according to Treasury forecasts. Net investment as a percentage of national income was volatile over most of the 1980s. After reaching just over 30 Table B6 on page 191 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 31 For more details, see IFS Public Finances Bulletin, 21 January 2003 (www.ifs.org.uk/press/pub_fin.shtml). 26 Planning the public finances 2% of national income in 1992–93, it fell to less than 0.6% by 1997–98. The July 1998 Comprehensive Spending Review (CSR) included plans to increase investment spending steadily over the next three years to nearly 1.1% of national income by 2001–02. This is also shown in Figure 2.9. Despite these plans, investment spending fell in the first year of the plans (1999–2000) to the lowest level since 1988–89. Although investment spending increased in 2000– 01 and 2001–02, it was only in 2001–02 that spending was higher than when Labour came into power in 1997. In 2001–02, net investment stood at £8.8 billion – 30% lower than the £13 billion announced in the July 1998 CSR. In the first nine months of 2002–03, we have seen net investment increase by 11.3% over the same months last year. In order to attain the level expected under current plans, the overall increase in investment spending would have to be 53.9% for the whole year. In order to attain this and spend the £14.3 billion outlined in the November 2002 PBR, investment spending for the remaining three months would have to be 97.5% higher than the same period last year. Figure 2.9. Public sector net investment: out-turns and forecasts as a percentage of national income Actual July 1998 Comprehensive Spending Review November 2002 Pre-Budget Report 2.5 Percentage of GDP 2.0 1.5 1.0 0.5 0.0 79–80 82–83 85–86 88–89 91–92 94–95 97–98 00–01 03–04 Financial year Source: Out-turn figures from HM Treasury, Public Finances Databank, January 2003, London, 2003 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//4EC32/jan03web.xls); forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm); July 1998 Comprehensive Spending Review figures from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, Cm. 4076, London, November 1998, as the plans set out in the actual Comprehensive Spending Review were set using a different accounting system. Public sector pay Over the three years from 2002–03 to 2005–06, resource departmental expenditure limits are due to increase by 7.6% a year on average in nominal 27 Green Budget, January 2003 terms.32 This represents a 5.1% average annual increase in real terms. It is from within these increases that the government will have to fund any pay increases in the public sector. It is clear from the increases planned in overall spending that there is considerable scope for increasing the amount the government spends on wages in the coming years. These significant increases for resource DELs, initially unveiled in the July 2002 Spending Review, were presented to enable an improvement in the quality of public services. There are some parts of the public sector where relatively high pay increases may be necessary to improve services by recruiting more high-quality staff or by motivating and retaining existing staff. While large increases in the pay of particular public sector workers will be easily affordable within the existing spending plans, large pay increases across the board will not be. Total remunerations to public sector workers are in the region of £115 billion a year – so each additional 1% increase in pay will use just over £1 billion of resources available to the government.33 The government should certainly weigh up carefully the benefits it might expect from increases in wages against those it could expect to derive from spending the money differently. Issues in planning annually managed expenditure Given the proximity of the Spending Review in July 2002, which set departmental expenditure limits through to March 2006, it is likely that any revisions to public spending announced in the Budget will be changes to annually managed expenditure rather than changes to DELs. Changes to AME might occur for at least two reasons. First, the Chancellor, as discussed in Chapter 4, might decide that he would like to announce further increases in financial transfers to low-income families with children so that the government can continue to progress towards its child poverty targets. Secondly, the Chancellor might decide that he needs to increase the funds he has available in case of unforeseen contingencies. This contingency reserve is known as the AME margin, and recent years have seen it used to pay for the costs of the BSE crisis and the foot-and-mouth epidemic. Since the 1998 Comprehensive Spending Review, the Chancellor has tended to ensure that the margin contains £1 billion for the following financial year, £2 billion for two years hence and £3 billion for three years hence. Table 2.4 shows the size of the AME margin in recent years. Each Spending Review (in 1998, 2000 and 2002) and Budget (1999, 2000, 2001 and 2002) has left the AME margin at £1 billion, £2 billion and £3 billion in one, 32 Table B17 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 33 According to the National Accounts Blue Book of 2000, total wages and employers’ social contributions of those in public corporations, central government and local government were £104 billion. Assuming 5% nominal growth a year over the last two years would imply spending in 2002 of around £115 billion. 28 Planning the public finances two and three years’ time respectively. As shown in last year’s Green Budget, these levels of reserve are low by historical standards.34 At the time of the Pre-Budget Report, the Chancellor has tended to adjust the AME margin to offset changes in the remainder of AME. So, for example, in November 1998 and November 1999, falls in forecast expenditure on AME led to increases in the size of the margin. In the following Budgets, the Chancellor was able to ‘reset’ the AME margin back to its normal level and use the funds to cut taxes, increase public spending or reduce debt. At the time of the 2002 Budget, £0.5 billion of additional funds were needed to restore the AME margin in 2003–04 to £2 billion. Table 2.4. The size of the AME margin (£ billion) 1999– 2000 1.0 3.0 1.0 3.5 0.0 2000– 01 2.0 4.5 2.0 3.9 1.0 2001– 02 3.0 6.0 3.0 6.4 2.0 1.0 2.7 1.0 0.2 0.0 0.0 2002– 03 2003– 04 2004– 05 Comprehensive Spending Review, July 1998 Pre-Budget Report, November 1998 Budget, March 1999 Pre-Budget Report, November 1999 Budget, March 2000 Spending Review, July 2000 2.0 3.0 Pre-Budget Report, November 2000 3.6 4.6 Budget, March 2001 2.0 3.0 Pre-Budget Report, November 2001 1.2 1.5 Budget, April 2002 1.0 2.0 Spending Review, July 2002 1.3 1.0 2.0 Pre-Budget Report, November 2002 0.1 1.8 0.5 Possible Budget 2003 scenario 1.0 2.0 Addition to spending? –0.8 +1.5 Sources: Various HM Treasury Pre-Budget Report, Budget and Spending Review documentation. 2005– 06 3.0 0.5 3.0 +2.5 Should the Chancellor wish to restore the AME margin back to its normal levels in the 2003 Budget, then he will need to find an additional £1.5 billion in 2004–05 and an additional £2.5 billion in 2005–06. This will require an increase in borrowing, an increase in taxation or a reduction in spending elsewhere of the same magnitude. 2.4 Conclusions Under its current plans, the government is set to meet both the golden rule and the sustainable investment rule over the current economic cycle. But the golden rule is forecast to be met with less margin for error than in previous years. The likelihood of deficits on the current budget in the near future underlines the importance of judging whether policy at any given time is consistent with the golden rule looking forward. The sustainable investment rule poses less of a constraint – even if we were to add the future liabilities of the government for capital spending undertaken under the Private Finance 34 See figure 2.7 in A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds.), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, IFS, London (www.ifs.org.uk/gb2002/chap2.pdf). 29 Green Budget, January 2003 Initiative. The fiscal rules are less constraining than the Stability and Growth Pact as it is currently interpreted, although this interpretation may already have changed by the time the UK joins the Euro – if it ever does. The government expects revenues to recover as the economy picks up. But movements in asset markets complicate the task of assessing the underlying health of tax revenues and the public finances more generally. The Chancellor’s forecasts show stamp duty and corporation tax receipts increasing. As a significant part of these revenues is linked to the performance of the stock market and financial companies, it may be risky to rely too much on this rebound. The public finances might well turn out to be less healthy if the stock market does not deliver these missing revenues, while the possibility of a decline in house prices poses a further risk. On top of any concern about revenues, the Chancellor must also decide whether to allocate resources to restore his contingency reserve to the levels he has felt necessary in the past. Robert Chote, Carl Emmerson, Christine Frayne and Alexander Klemm 30 3. IFS public finance forecasts In his Pre-Budget Report last November, the Chancellor conceded that the impact of a weak economy on tax revenues would force him to borrow more this year and next. But, over the medium term, he predicted that the economy would bounce back – and that the public finances would bounce back with it. This chapter details the January 2003 IFS public finance forecasts and compares them with the Treasury’s November 2002 Pre-Budget Report (PBR) projections. Taking the two fiscal rules and the degree of caution that the Chancellor has previously chosen to incorporate into his plans, we consider whether he will need to announce reductions in public spending or further tax increases. Our main conclusions are as follows: 1. In the short run, our forecasts are very similar to those in the PBR. In 2002–03, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £22.1 billion, slightly higher than the PBR forecast of £20.1 billion. In 2003–04, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £25.2 billion, compared with £24.5 billion forecast in the PBR. 2. In the medium term, we believe that the public finances will be weaker than the PBR suggested in November, even if the economy behaves much as the Treasury expects. In 2005–06, we forecast public sector net borrowing of £28 billion, compared with the PBR forecast of £19 billion. 3. Nonetheless, we believe the Chancellor can credibly claim that both the golden rule and the sustainable investment rule will have been met comfortably over the current economic cycle, which is projected to end in 2005–06. 4. If the Chancellor sticks by his PBR forecast of a surplus on current budget in 2005–06 of 0.4% of national income, he could say that there is no need for any further tax increases. But looking forward into the next economic cycle, our forecasts imply that spending cuts or tax increases will be required if the golden rule is to continue to be met. 5. Spending cuts would sit oddly with both the government’s stated objectives and its previous actions. Tax increases, therefore, seem more likely. 6. The scale of tax increases required depends on how cautious the government wants to be. To expect to continue to meet the golden rule exactly would require tax increases of around £4 billion. But in the past, the Chancellor has been more cautious and sought to overachieve the golden rule by around 0.7% of national income on average. To do this would require tax increases of around £11 billion. 31 Green Budget, January 2003 3.1 Borrowing in 2002–03 In 2001–02, government revenues came in lower than forecast either by the Treasury in the November 2001 PBR or by IFS in the January 2002 Green Budget. Public spending also came in lower than the Treasury expected, but slightly higher than forecast by IFS. The net effect was to leave public sector net borrowing in balance, compared with the £1.4 billion deficit predicted by the Treasury and the £1.6 billion surplus predicted by IFS.1 Receipts have continued to come in lower than expected during the current financial year. In the PBR last November, the Treasury cut its April Budget forecast for current receipts in 2002–03 by £7.5 billion to £399.7 billion, as shown in Table 3.1. On the spending side, it revised its Budget forecast for total managed expenditure up by £1.4 billion to £419.8 billion. This largely reflected the carrying forward of last year’s underspending in departmental expenditure limits, plus a £1 billion special allocation to help finance a possible conflict in Iraq. Table 3.1. Comparison of Green Budget and HM Treasury forecasts for government borrowing, 2002–03 (£ billion) Budget, Apr. 02 PreBudget Report, Nov. 02 Green Budget, Jan. 03 Differences in Green Budget forecast relative to: Budget PBR Current receipts 407.2 399.7 396.6 –10.6 –3.1 Total managed expenditure 418.4 419.8 418.7 0.3 –1.1 Of which: Departmental expenditure limits 239.7b 241.3 240.3 0.6 –1.0 Annually managed expenditure 178.7b 178.5 178.4 –0.3 –0.1 Public sector net borrowinga 11.2 20.1 22.1 10.9 2.0 Net investment 14.4 14.3 13.3 –1.1 –1.0 Surplus on current budgeta 3.2 –5.7 –8.8 –12.0 –3.1 a Includes windfall tax and associated spending. b DEL and AME forecast adjusted for accounting changes introduced between the Budget and the Spending Review. For more details, see table B14 on page 202 of the 2002 Pre-Budget Report. Sources: Treasury forecasts – HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm), and HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_bud02/budget_report/bud_bud02_repindex.cfm). Weaker receipts and higher spending imply higher borrowing. The Budget had forecast public sector net borrowing of £11.2 billion and a surplus on the current budget of £3.2 billion. The PBR showed public sector net borrowing of £20.1 billion and a current budget deficit of £5.7 billion. 1 See Appendix A for a breakdown of the November 2001 Pre-Budget Report and the January 2002 IFS Green Budget forecast for 2001–02. 32 IFS public finance forecasts Table 3.2. Comparison of Green Budget and HM Treasury forecasts for government borrowing, 2002–03 and 2003–04 (£ billion) 2002–03 PBR Gr. Budget Nov. 2002 Jan. 2003 2003–04 PBR Gr. Budget Nov. 2002 Jan. 2003 Inland Revenue Income tax (gross of tax credits) 114.1 110.0h 123.0 118.5h a h Corporation tax (CT) 29.3 28.5 30.8 30.0h Tax creditsb –3.5 n/a –4.9 n/a Petroleum revenue tax 1.1 1.1 1.3 1.3 Capital gains tax 2.0 2.0 1.4 1.4 Inheritance tax 2.4 2.4 2.6 2.6 Stamp duties 8.2 7.8 8.6 8.2 Social security contributions 65.5 65.0 75.4 75.1 Total Inland Revenue (net of tax credits) 219.1 216.8 238.3 237.1 Customs and Excise Value added tax (VAT) 64.5 63.7 67.3 67.0 Fuel duties 22.4 22.4 23.1 23.1 Tobacco duties 8.2 8.2 7.8 8.2 Spirit duties 2.2 2.2 2.4 2.4 Wine duties 1.9 1.9 1.9 1.9 Beer and cider duties 3.1 3.1 3.1 3.1 Betting and gaming duties 1.3 1.3 1.3 1.3 Air passenger duty 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 Insurance premium tax 2.1 2.1 2.2 2.2 Landfill tax 0.5 0.5 0.7 0.7 Climate change levy 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 Aggregates levy 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.4 Customs duties and levies 2.0 2.0 1.9 1.9 Total Customs and Excise 110.1 109.3 113.8 113.9 Vehicle excise duties 4.4 4.4 4.8 4.8 Oil royalties 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.0 Business ratesc 18.0 18.0 18.2 18.2 Council tax 16.6 16.6 17.8 17.8 Other taxes and royaltiesd 10.9 10.9 12.3 12.3 Total taxes and social security contribnse 379.6 376.5 405.1 404.1 Accruals adjustments on taxes –0.6 –0.6 3.4 3.4 Less Own resources contribution to EU –3.0 –3.0 –2.4 –2.4 Less Public corporations’ CT payments –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 Tax creditsf 1.2 1.2 0.6 0.6 Interest and dividends 4.1 4.1 4.1 4.1 Other receipts 18.6 18.6 19.7 19.7 Current receipts 399.7 396.6 430.3 429.3 Current spending 405.5 405.4 435.2 434.4 Current balanceg –5.7 –8.8 –4.9 –5.1 Net investment 14.3 13.3 19.6 20.1 Public sector net borrowingg 20.1 22.1 24.5 25.2 a National accounts measure: gross of enhanced and payable tax credits. b Includes enhanced and payable company tax credits. c Includes district council rates in Northern Ireland. d Includes money paid into the National Lottery Distribution Fund. e Includes VAT and ‘traditional own resources’ contributions to EC budget. Cash basis. f Excludes children’s tax credit and other tax credits that score as a tax repayment in the National Accounts. g Includes expenditure associated with the windfall tax. h Net of tax credits. Note: For more details of the IFS forecast in 2002–03, see Table A.3 in Appendix A. Sources: Treasury forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm) – this table is similar to table B12 on page 197); authors’ calculations. 33 Green Budget, January 2003 IFS now forecasts receipts this year of £396.6 billion, a further £3.1 billion below the Treasury’s PBR prediction. We also expect total managed expenditure to come in £1.1 billion below the PBR forecast, at £418.7 billion. This implies a deficit on the current budget of £8.8 billion and public sector net borrowing of £22.1 billion, worse than the PBR forecast by £3.1 billion and £2.0 billion respectively. Table 3.2 compares our revenue forecasts for 2002–03 and 2003–04 with those of the PBR. Ours are gloomier for this year because we expect lower income tax, corporation tax, stamp duty and VAT receipts than projected in the PBR. We also have a lower forecast for public spending, dominated by a predicted underspend of £1 billion on capital spending within departmental expenditure limits. This reflects the fact that public sector net investment has proved difficult to deliver during the year to date.2 We also assume that the £0.1 billion in the annually managed expenditure margin in 2002–03 at the time of the November 2002 PBR will not be spent. 3.2 Borrowing in 2003–04 Wherever possible, our forecasts for 2003–04 are based on the same macroeconomic assumptions that underlie the ‘cautious’ forecasts in the 2002 PBR, including the assumption that the trend rate of economic growth is 2½%. We assume that no new measures are announced in the Spring 2003 Budget. But, as discussed in Chapter 4, the government might decide to increase further the generosity of payments to lower-income families with children to increase its chance of hitting its child poverty target. We forecast receipts of £429.3 billion in 2003–04, £1 billion lower than the £430.3 billion in the PBR. This is a smaller undershoot than we forecast in 2002–03 because we expect stronger revenue growth than the Treasury for a number of taxes, such as tobacco duties. But we do expect weaker receipts from corporation tax and stamp duty than the PBR, as we are less confident that the loss of revenue attributed by the Treasury to the performance of financial companies will be recouped. On the expenditure side, we forecast current spending of £434.4 billion next year, £0.8 billion less than in the PBR. This is because we assume that the AME margin for 2003–04 will be set to £1.0 billion, rather than the £1.8 billion in the PBR. As shown in Table 2.4 in Chapter 2, this is line with recent Budget practice. But we forecast that net investment spending will be £0.5 billion higher than the PBR forecast, at £20.1 billion, because we assume that half the £1 billion underspend we forecast for this year will be carried forward and spent in 2003–04, with the remainder spent in 2004–05. With our projections of lower receipts and lower spending than in the PBR partially offsetting each other, our predictions for borrowing are little different 2 For more details, see IFS Public Finances Bulletin, 21 January 2003 (www.ifs.org.uk/press/pub_fin.shtml). 34 IFS public finance forecasts from the Treasury’s November forecasts. For 2003–04, we expect a deficit on the current budget of £5.1 billion (compared to the Treasury’s £4.9 billion) and public sector net borrowing of £25.2 billion (compared to the Treasury’s £24.5 billion). 3.3 Medium-term prospects Our forecasts for the current budget balance and public sector net borrowing this year and next are not very far out of line with those in the PBR. But looking further ahead, we are rather less optimistic. As with our short-term forecasts, our medium-term projections (shown in Table 3.3 later) are based on similar macroeconomic assumptions to those the Treasury used in the PBR. Further details can be found in Appendix A. One of the key uncertainties in projecting the outlook for the public finances is the path of corporation tax revenues, traditionally one of the hardest taxes to forecast. As discussed in Section 2.2, in recent years the Treasury has forecast strong growth in corporation tax receipts, taking them to a level that by historical standards appears rather high. In last year’s IFS Green Budget, we said, ‘Due to the difficulties in forecasting corporation tax in the current environment, we take the November 2001 PBR forecasts, although … it would be helpful if the Treasury published further discussion of what is driving the forecast increase in revenues in the medium term.’3 The Treasury has not published further details of its forecasts. In the January 2003 Green Budget, we assume that the Treasury’s forecast growth in corporate tax revenues will not materialise. Instead, we assume that, as the economy returns to trend, corporate tax receipts will return to their average level of recent years. This implies annual nominal growth in underlying corporation tax receipts of around 8.5% a year to March 2008. This is lower than the growth rate implied by recent Treasury forecasts. Figure 3.1 shows non-North-Sea corporation tax receipts adjusted for changes to the corporation tax system from 1987–88 to 2001–02, along with the Treasury and IFS projections for 2002–03 to 2007–08. The recent average in adjusted corporation tax receipts is 2.9% of national income. By 2007–08, when the economy is still forecast to be at trend, the Treasury expects corporation tax receipts of 3.3% of national income – a level only achieved in the past at the peak of the economic cycle. We forecast corporation tax receipts of just over 2.9% in 2007–08 (when the economy is assumed to be at trend output). The difference between the two projections equals 0.3% of national income, or £3.5 billion in today’s prices. 3 Page 25 of A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/gbfiles/gb2002.shtml). 35 Green Budget, January 2003 Figure 3.1. Non-North-Sea corporation tax receipts and forecasts as a percentage of national income 5.0% Percentage of GDP 4.0% 3.0% 2.0% 1.0% 0.0% 87–88 89–90 91–92 93–94 IFS forecasts 95–96 97–98 99–00 Treasury forecasts 01–02 03–04 05–06 07–08 Adjusted series Notes: The adjusted series shows our estimates of the tax revenue that the current tax system would have raised in previous years. It takes account of the fact that tax rates have been reduced in two steps from 33% to 30% and that the introduction of a quarterly payments system boosted revenues temporarily between 1999–2000 and 2002–03. Sources: Inland Revenue, Inland Revenue Statistics, London, 2002; HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm); Inland Revenue, ‘A Modern System for Corporation Tax Payments’, Press Release IR 9, 17 March 1998. On VAT receipts, the Treasury has introduced a new strategy for combating VAT fraud and avoidance. It expects that this will produce more than £2 billion a year in additional revenues by 2005–06. In order to be cautious, the Treasury has only assumed that £1.4 billion extra is collected by 2005–06.4 Our forecasts take a more cautious approach and assume that none of this revenue materialises. Offsetting this, at least to some extent, is the fact that our forecasts assume that the ratio of VAT receipts to consumer spending remains constant over time, whereas the Treasury forecasts assume a gradual decline. Our medium-term forecasts, like those of the Treasury, are for VAT receipts to be stable, at around 6.1% of national income. Over the medium term, we expect receipts overall to be lower than the Treasury forecast in the PBR, despite our very similar forecast for 2003–04 (see Table 3.3). By 2005–06, when the economy is predicted to return to trend, we forecast that receipts will be £6.5 billion lower than forecast in the PBR, at £486.5 billion. We expect a slightly lower shortfall of £6.1 billion in 2007–08, when the current planning period for the public finances ends. 4 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 36 IFS public finance forecasts Table 3.3. Medium-term public finances forecasts, based on cautious macroeconomic assumptions (£ billion) IFS forecasts Current budget Current receipts Current expenditurea Surplus on current budgetb Capital budget Net investment Public sector net borrowingb 2002–03 2003–04 2004–05 2005–06 2006–07 2007–08 396.6 405.4 –8.8 429.3 434.4 –5.1 459.1 461.5 –2.4 486.5 490.6 –4.0 514 518 –4 542 546 –5 13.3 22.1 20.1 25.2 22.4 24.8 24.1 28.1 27 31 30 35 HM Treasury forecasts Current budget Current receipts 399.7 430.3 463 493 521 548 Current expenditurea 405.5 435.2 459.7 487.5 513 538 Surplus on current budgetb –5.7 –4.9 3 5 8 10 Capital budget Net investment 14.3 19.6 21.9 24.1 27 30 Public sector net borrowingb 20.1 24.5 19 19 19 20 a In line with the National Accounts, depreciation has been included as current expenditure. b Includes spending financed by the windfall tax. Sources: Treasury forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm) – this table is similar to table B5 on page 190; authors’ calculations. In forecasting spending, we take the Treasury’s current departmental expenditure limits to 2005–06, with an additional £0.5 billion of capital spending in both 2003–04 and 2004–05. We also assume that the AME margin will be set to £2.0 billion in 2004–05 and £3.0 billion in 2005–06, as shown in Table 2.4 of Chapter 2. This implies £1.5 billion of additional spending in 2004–05 and £2.5 billion of additional spending in 2005–06. We also take account of any differences in debt interest spending arising from previous differences in borrowing levels. The result is that, in 2005–06, we forecast current spending of £490.6 billion, £3.1 billion higher than the PBR forecast. Forecasting public spending in 2006–07 and 2007–08 is more difficult. It requires an assumption about the level of funds that the Chancellor will wish to allocate in the 2004 Spending Review. The PBR assumes that departmental expenditure limits excluding expenditure on the NHS will fall as a share of national income. With annually managed expenditure, the PBR assumes annual growth of ‘1¾ per cent in real terms in line with its recent trend’,5 which is lower than expected GDP growth. The PBR therefore assumes that non-NHS spending will fall as a share of national income. It remains to be seen whether this is consistent with the government’s stated objectives of reducing child poverty and delivering ‘world-class’ public services. The Chancellor might decide that more funds are required to meet the government’s objectives, as he did in the April 2002 Budget. It seems appropriate that these decisions be left until the 2004 Budget, 5 Paragraph B20 on page 187 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 37 Green Budget, January 2003 by which point more information on how the government is progressing towards its objectives will be available. In the mean time, we assume that all non-NHS current spending grows in line with national income in 2006–07 and 2007–08. As shown in Table 3.3, this implies current spending of £546 billion in 2007–08, some £8 billion above the PBR estimate. With lower forecasts for receipts and higher forecasts for spending, we believe that the public finances will be weaker in the medium term than the Treasury currently projects. In 2005–06, we forecast a deficit on the current budget of £4.0 billion rather than the surplus of £5 billion forecast by the Treasury. In 2007–08, we project a current deficit of £5 billion, while the Treasury has a current surplus rising to £10 billion. We expect public sector net borrowing to rise to £28.1 billion in 2005–06 and then to £35 billion in 2007–08, whereas the Treasury has it rising only from £19 billion to £20 billion over the same period. Table 3.4. Medium-term public finances forecasts, based on cautious macroeconomic assumptions (% of national income) IFS forecasts Current budget Current receipts Current expenditurea Surplus on current budgetb Average surplus on current budget since 1999–2000b Capital budget Net investment Public sector net borrowingb Public sector net debt Output gapc 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 38.0 38.8 –0.8 1.1 39.2 39.6 –0.5 0.8 39.6 39.9 –0.2 0.6 39.9 40.2 –0.3 0.5 40.1 40.4 –0.3 0.4 40.4 40.7 –0.3 0.3 1.3 2.1 31.2 –1.3 1.8 2.3 32.4 –1.0 1.9 2.1 33.2 –0.3 2.0 2.3 34.1 0.0 2.1 2.4 35.1 0.0 2.2 2.6 36.5 0.0 HM Treasury forecasts Current budget Current receipts 38.3 39.3 40.0 40.4 40.7 40.8 Current expenditurea 38.8 39.7 39.7 40.0 40.0 40.1 Surplus on current budgetb –0.5 –0.4 0.3 0.4 0.6 0.7 Average surplus on current 1.2 0.8 0.6 0.7 0.7 0.7 budget since 1999–2000b Capital budget Net investment 1.4 1.8 1.9 2.0 2.1 2.2 Public sector net borrowingb 1.9 2.2 1.6 1.6 1.5 1.5 Public sector net debt 31.0 32.1 32.4 32.6 32.7 33.0 Output gapc –1.3 –1.0 –0.3 0.0 0.0 0.0 a In line with the National Accounts, depreciation has been included as current expenditure. b Includes spending financed by the windfall tax. c Measured as a percentage of trend output rather than actual output. Sources: Treasury forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm) – this table is similar to table B5 on page 190; authors’ calculations. Table 3.4 shows the IFS and Treasury forecasts as percentages of national income. The higher borrowing forecast by IFS translates into debt being 0.2 percentage points higher in 2002–03 than the 31.0% of national income that the Treasury expects. By 2007–08, the IFS forecast is for debt to stand at 38 IFS public finance forecasts 36.5% of national income, which is 3.5 percentage points higher than the 33.0% forecast by the Treasury. Nevertheless, under both the Treasury’s and IFS’s forecasts, net debt is set to stay below the 40% level stipulated by the sustainable investment rule. Our forecasts suggest that there will have been an average surplus on the current budget of 0.5% of national income between 1999–2000 and 2005–06 – the Treasury’s estimate of the current economic cycle – as shown in Table 3.4. In cash terms, the cumulative surplus of £31 billion is less than the £46 billion the Chancellor predicted in the PBR, but over the current economic cycle, the golden rule is still comfortably overachieved. However, we see the present cycle ending in 2005–06 with the current budget in deficit to the tune of 0.3% of national income, compared with the surplus of 0.4% and rising expected by the Treasury. Our projections therefore imply that further tax increases or spending cuts will be needed to ensure that the golden rule is not missed looking forward. 3.4 The Budget judgement The current budget balances forecast in the April 2002 Budget, the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report and the January 2003 IFS Green Budget are shown in Figure 3.2. The PBR predicts that the golden rule will continue to be met, but with less room to spare than looked likely at the time of the April 2002 Budget. We expect the current budget to remain in deficit. The large current budget surpluses seen in 1999–2000, 2000–01 and 2001–02 would still allow the government to claim that the golden rule had been met over the current economic cycle. But our forecast implies that the current budget will remain in deficit from 2005–06 onwards during a period when the economy is operating at trend. Without tax increases or spending cuts at some point, the golden rule will be missed. So if the government has to raise taxes or cut spending, which is it likely to choose? Cutting public spending significantly would seem inconsistent with the government’s stated objectives, as it would involve big cuts in either transfer payments or spending on public services. Within transfer payments, the largest recipient groups are families with children and pensioners. Meeting the government’s target for reducing child poverty by one-quarter by 2004–05 might require further increases in spending (see Chapter 4). The government has also pledged increases in support to those aged 65 or over, including the introduction of the pension credit in October 2003. Reductions in other transfer payments – for example, disability or unemployment benefits – are possible but would need to reduce recipients’ incomes significantly to make substantial savings. Looking at public services, the recent July 2002 Spending Review announced supposedly fixed spending plans covering all departmental expenditure limits to March 2006, apart from the NHS, where the settlement runs until March 2008. Changing these plans so soon would sit very uncomfortably with the government’s commitments to sustained increases in public spending in order to deliver world-class public services. 39 Green Budget, January 2003 Figure 3.2. Current budget surplus as a percentage of national income 2.0% Treasury April 2002 Budget forecast Current balance as a % of GDP Treasury November 2002 Pre-Budget Report forecast IFS January 2003 forecast 1.0% 0.0% -1.0% -2.0% 2001–02 2002–03 2003–04 2004–05 2005–06 2006–07 2007–08 Year Sources: Treasury forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report: 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm), and HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_bud02/budget_report/bud_bud02_repindex.cfm); authors’ calculations. Tax increases therefore seem more likely, particularly given the choices the Chancellor has made in the past: the July 1997 Budget increased taxes in order to reduce borrowing, while the April 2002 Budget increased taxes in order to increase public spending. How big do these tax increases need to be? Let us assume that the Chancellor wants to end the current economic cycle in 2005–06 in a position that would not require him to make any further tax increases or spending cuts to hit the golden rule over the following economic cycle. This would imply a current budget balance in that year. If he sticks by his PBR forecast of a surplus on current budget in 2005–06 of 0.4% of national income, the Chancellor could say that there is no need for any further tax increases. But, on our forecasts, he would need to close the current deficit of 0.3% of national income that we expect for that year. This would require a tax increase of about £4 billion, effective by April 2005. But in the past, the Chancellor has been more cautious than this. He has sought to build caution into his projections by aiming for a current surplus of around 0.7% of national income on average, sufficient to ensure that the golden rule is met even if the Treasury has overestimated the level of trend output by 1%. On the basis of his PBR forecast, this could be seen as requiring a tax increase of around £3 billion to raise the projected current surplus in 2005–06 from 0.4% of national income to 0.7%. But the Chancellor might also point out that he expects the surplus to rise to 0.7% of national income in any event by 40 IFS public finance forecasts 2007–08, even without the economy moving above trend. So again there is no need for tax increases. But on our forecast, the Chancellor would need to raise taxes by around £11 billion to move from a current deficit of 0.3% of national income to a current surplus of 0.7% – and thereby restore the level of caution he has sought in the past with regard to the golden rule. We do not expect the underlying budget position to improve of its own accord beyond 2005–06, in part because we are not as confident as the Treasury that the revenues lost from the stock market and the troubles of the financial sector will bounce back. In addition, we expect spending to grow more quickly than the economy in the 2004 Spending Review – although the Chancellor will not have to make a firm decision on this until next year. A rise in spending as a share of national income would offset fiscal drag, the natural tendency for revenues to rise as a share of national income as people move into higher tax brackets. To conclude, if the Chancellor believes that the forecasts he made in the PBR are still realistic – and that the recent weakening of the public finances is a temporary phenomenon – he could argue that there is no need for significant tax increases. He might well add that with the outlook for the world economy fragile, now is not the time for a tightening of fiscal policy that could put too much of the burden of supporting the UK economy on interest rates. But we believe that the outlook for the public finances is weaker than the PBR suggested. If the golden rule is expected to be met going forwards, then taxes would need to rise. Now may not be the ideal time for this, but rises cannot be delayed for too long without undermining the credibility of those very rules in which the Chancellor places such store. Robert Chote, Carl Emmerson and Christine Frayne 41 4. What do the child poverty targets mean for the child tax credit? The child tax credit will be introduced in April 2003. When fully operational, it will represent the majority of government financial support for children. It is designed to help reduce child poverty and is means-tested against family income. The Labour government has an explicit target for the level of child poverty – defined in terms of relative incomes – for 2004–05. This chapter therefore examines whether the government’s current commitments are likely to enable it to meet this target, and what it might cost to reduce child poverty further by increasing the rates of the child tax credit or through other means in and beyond April 2004. Our calculations suggest that around £1 billion of further spending might be needed to meet the target – a sizeable amount of money given the current state of the public finances, but small compared with the total increases in spending on benefits for families with children since 1997. Yet, regardless of whether the government is able to find more for families with children, child poverty in 2004–05 should still be substantially lower than it was in 1996–97. 4.1 Child poverty under Labour In his Beveridge speech at Toynbee Hall in March 1999, the Prime Minister announced a radical ambition – to ‘eradicate child poverty within a generation’. Subsequently, the Treasury set out further objectives: to eradicate child poverty by 2020, to halve it by 2010 and to ‘make substantial progress towards eliminating child poverty by reducing the number of children in poverty by at least a quarter by 2004’.1 The government has yet to specify how we might tell whether poverty has been eradicated in 2020 and what measure of poverty is due to be halved by 2010, although the Department for Work and Pensions has been consulting on a new measure of poverty and is due to announce its conclusions shortly.2 But the government’s target for 2004–05 is more specific: ‘the target for 2004 will be monitored by reference to the number of children in low-income 1 From HM Treasury, Spending Review 2000: Public Service Agreements 2001–04, Cm. 4808, Stationery Office, London, 2000 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Documents/Public_Spending_and_Services/Public_Service_Agreements_200 1-2004/pss_psa_whitepaper.cfm). The target was initially a joint Public Service Agreement target for HM Treasury and the former Department of Social Security accompanying the 2000 Spending Review, and was carried forward in the 2002 Spending Review. In this, and the rest of the chapter unless otherwise specified, ‘child’ means ‘dependent child’ – a child under 16, or under 19 and in full-time education. 2 Department for Work and Pensions, Measuring Child Poverty: A Consultation Document, London, 2002 (www.dwp.gov.uk/consultations/consult/2002/childpov/childpoverty.pdf). 42 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit households by 2004/5. Low-income households are defined as households with income below 60% of the median, as reported in the Households Below Average Income (HBAI) statistics … Progress will be measured against the 1998/9 baseline figures and methodology’.3 The data to assess these targets should be available in early 2006. In the HBAI statistics, children are considered poor depending on the total income of the household in which they live, leaving aside the question of whether money channelled to low-income families with children is actually beneficial to the children themselves. The wording of the government’s target does not specify whether income is to be measured before housing costs (BHC) or after housing costs have been deducted (AHC), nor whether self-employed households are to be included. In practice, ministers’ statements have tended to focus on progress on the AHC measure including the self-employed.4 As there were 4.2 million children in poverty in 1998–99 on this definition, there will need to be fewer than 3.1 million children in poverty in 2004–05 to meet the target.5 What has happened to date? Between 1996–97 and 2000–01 (the latest year for which data are currently available), the number of children in households below 60% of median AHC income fell from 4.4 million to 3.9 million.6 This implies that if the government is to reach its target in 2004–05 (AHC), child poverty will have to continue to fall each year by an average of around 200,000 – faster than in the period from 1996–97 to 2000–01. Measuring poverty BHC, the target level is 2.3 million children, and the government is closer to reaching its target for 2004–05, having seen a decline from 3.1 million in 1998–99 to 2.7 million in 2000–01.7 As Figure 4.1 illustrates, 3 HM Treasury, ‘Technical Note for HM Treasury’s Public Service Agreement 2003–2006’, London, 2002, www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/tech_notes.pdf. The median household is the one for which half the rest of the population has an income higher than it does and half has an income lower. 4 For example, page 87, box 5.3 of HM Treasury, Budget Report 2001: Investing for the Long Term, London, 2001 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Budget/Budget_2001/Budget_Report/bud_bud01_repchap5.cfm?). 5 The data in this chapter on children in poverty up to 2000–01 come from M. Brewer, T. Clark and A. Goodman, The Government’s Child Poverty Target: How Much Progress Has Been Made?, Commentary no. 88, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/inequality/childpov.pdf), or M. Brewer, T. Clark and A. Goodman, ‘What really happened to child poverty in the UK in Labour’s first term?’, Economic Journal, forthcoming. Some of the numbers can also be found in Department for Work and Pensions, Households Below Average Income 1994/95 to 2000/01, Corporate Document Services, Leeds, 2002 (www.dss.gov.uk/asd/hbai/hbai2001/hbai2000_01.html). 6 Tests reveal that the fall in child poverty since 1996–97 is statistically significant – in other words, it is unlikely to be driven by random variations in the data used to analyse poverty rates. 7 Poverty is lower when measured BHC than when measured AHC because housing costs are a larger proportion of total expenditure of low-income families with children. Because the government and commentators tend to focus on measuring incomes AHC when thinking about the bottom end of the income distribution, we do so in this chapter, reporting the results BHC only where they are substantially different. 43 Green Budget, January 2003 the fall since 1996–97 follows a very long period during which child poverty grew substantially.8 Figure 4.1. Child poverty (children in households with less than 60% median income AHC) Children (million) 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 1964 1968 1972 1976 1980 1984 Child poverty 1988 1992 1996 2000 Target for 2004-05 Notes: The poverty line of 60% median income AHC is a fraction of the contemporary median household income across the whole population (i.e. not just for children). Data up to and including 1992 are for calendar years, while those thereafter are for financial years, so 1993 should be read as 1993–94, and so on. Changes in the income definitions make comparisons before and after 1993–94 difficult. Source: Authors’ calculations based on Family Expenditure Survey for years until 1993 and on Family Resources Survey thereafter. 4.2 The child tax credit The structure of new tax credits in April 2003 In Budget 2002, the government confirmed that it will be introducing two new tax credits from April 2003: the child tax credit and the working tax credit. The child tax credit will bring together three parts of the existing tax and benefit system that support families with children. Separately, the working tax credit will support adults with or without children in low-paid work, as well as providing subsidies for certain childcare expenditure for some working parents (see Box 4.1). 8 See also P. Gregg, S. Harkness and S. Machin, ‘Poor kids: trends in child poverty in Britain, 1968–96’, Fiscal Studies, 1999, vol. 20, pp. 163–87. 44 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit Box 4.1. The new tax credits from April 2003 • What is being abolished? The children’s tax credit reduces the income tax bills of around 5 million income-tax-paying families with children under 16. It was introduced in April 2001 and will be subsumed within the child tax credit in April 2003. The working families’ tax credit (WFTC) provides support to 1.34 million low-paid families with dependent children working 16 or more hours a week. It will be subsumed within the child tax credit and the working tax credit in April 2003. The childcare tax credit subsidises some eligible childcare costs of 167,000 families who also receive the WFTC. It was introduced in October 1999 as part of the WFTC and will be subsumed within the working tax credit in April 2003. Child allowances in income support provide extra money to 1.18 million families with dependent children claiming income support and income-related jobseeker’s allowance. The child allowances will be subsumed within the child tax credit in April 2004. • What is new? The child tax credit will provide income-related support to the main carer. By April 2004, around 5.75 million – all but the richest 10% – of families with dependent children should receive it. The working tax credit will provide inwork support to around 1 million single people or couples in low-paid work. Both will be introduced in April 2003, although families on income support will not be affected by the reforms until April 2004. • What is staying? Child benefit is a universal, non-means-tested payment. All 7 million families with dependent children in the UK are entitled to receive it. It will be unaffected by the reforms. Note: A dependent child is one under 16, or under 19 and in full-time education. Sources: Inland Revenue, Working Families Tax Credit Statistics Quarterly Enquiry, May 2002, London, 2002 (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/wftctables/wftc_may_02.pdf); Department for Work and Pensions, Income Support Quarterly Statistical Enquiry, August 2002, London, 2002 (www.dwp.gov.uk/asd/asd1/qse/aug2002/is_aug2002_pub.pdf); HM Treasury, The Child and Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of Britain’s Tax and Benefit System no. 10, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf). Budget 2002 announced that, in April 2003, the child tax credit will consist of two components:9 9 This chapter does not discuss how these tax credits work in detail; for that, see HM Treasury, The Child and Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of Britain’s Tax and Benefit System no. 10, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf), or D. Thurley, ‘Tax credits and income changes’, Welfare Rights Bulletin, no. 169, Child Poverty Action Group, August 2002. Childcare subsidies are also discussed in Chapter 7. M. Brewer, T. Clark and M. Myck, Credit Where It’s Due? An Assessment of the New Tax Credits, Commentary no. 86, IFS, London, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/taxben/taxcred.pdf), and 45 Green Budget, January 2003 • a family element of £10.45 per week, doubled in the financial year of a child’s birth; • an amount per dependent child of £27.75 per week. Families with incomes below £13,230 p.a. (£254.42 p.w.) are entitled to the full amount. Incomes above £13,230 p.a. reduce entitlement to the per-child elements at the rate of 37p in the pound until a family is left with just the family element (this happens at £17,130 p.a. for a one-child family and at £21,030 p.a. for a two-child family).10 Incomes above £50,000 p.a. (£961.54 p.w.) reduce entitlement to the family element at the rate of 6.7p in the pound, meaning that families with children with incomes over £58,110 (or £66,221 if they have a child under 1) will be entitled to child benefit only. Around 90% of families with children will be entitled to some child tax credit: around half of families will be entitled to the per-child element and the family element, and around 40% will be entitled to the family element only. The structures of the existing system and of the new tax credits are illustrated in Figures 4.2 and 4.3. Figure 4.2. Financial support for a family with one child under the outgoing system (£ per week) Benefit and tax credit income £120 £100 £80 £60 £40 WFTC IS adult C WFTC child F Children's tax credit £20 Child benefit £0 £0 £200 £400 £600 Gross income £800 £1,000 £1,200 Notes: IS is adult allowance, F is the family premium and C is the child allowance in income support. The figure uses hypothetical April 2003 rates for the WFTC and the children’s tax credit. It does not show childcare tax credit. chapter 5 of A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/gb2002/chap5.pdf), (both written before the government confirmed the precise structure of the new tax credits) analysed the likely impact of the new tax credits on work incentives, incomes and take-up. 10 These three annual thresholds are higher if a family qualifies for extra credits for working at least 30 hours a week, having disabled adults or children, or receiving help for childcare costs. 46 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit Figure 4.3. Financial support for a family with one child under the new tax credits (£ per week) Benefit and tax credit income £120 £100 £80 £60 Working IS tax credit Child tax credit £40 £20 Child benefit £0 £0 £200 £400 £600 £800 £1,000 £1,200 Gross income Notes: The new tax credits are annual systems but this figure assumes them to be weekly. It also assumes that the new tax credits are implemented fully in April 2003 and that a family qualifies for working tax credit at 16 hours of minimum-wage work (£67.20 p.w.) and for the 30-hour premium at £126 p.w. It does not show support for childcare costs. It assumes one dependent child aged at least 12 months. The future structure and rates The structure of the child tax credit effectively means that the government has two targeted instruments with which to redistribute to families with children (as well as child benefit). The family element can be used to direct money to the vast majority of families in a near-universal way, regardless of income or family size. The child element, on the other hand, is focused on low- to middle-income families, and also helps larger families more than smaller ones. This suggests that, for a given level of expenditure, increasing the per-child element will have a larger direct impact on poverty than increasing the family element (we show this in Section 4.4). Perhaps for this reason, the government has promised to increase the per-child element (£27.75 p.w.) in line with average earnings growth until the end of this Parliament. This means that the rate from April 2004 will be around 63p higher in real terms than the rate in 2003 if earnings rise in line with their trend of recent years.11 This is a much smaller annual increase in child-related payments than families saw between 11 The average annual growth in nominal earnings between 1998 and 2001 is 4.74%. This would imply a per-child element of £29.05 in April 2004. The inflation rate averaged over the same period is 2.43%, implying that the real rise is some 63p. 47 Green Budget, January 2003 1996 and 2003, and equates to a real increase in incomes of only 0.7% for the poorest couple with two children (0.8% for a lone parent with two children).12 4.3 Is the government likely to meet its child poverty target in 2004–05? The government has chosen to target a relative measure of child poverty rather than an absolute one. Whether a household is judged to be poor depends not only on the cash value of its income, but also on how much it has relative to the median household. This means we cannot judge whether the government is going to meet the target simply by looking at the impact of its own policy reforms on the incomes of poor families with children. We also need to assess the likely impact of economic and demographic factors on the incomes of poor families and on the median income against which they are to be compared. This distinction is sometimes overlooked. For example, in Budget 2001, the Treasury claimed that reforms introduced from 1997 to 2001 would reduce the number of children in poverty by 1.2 million. This number was widely believed to be a forecast of how much child poverty would fall. But the Treasury subsequently had to clarify that it was only an estimate of how much higher child poverty would have been if the government had only increased benefits and tax credits in line with inflation.13 In other words, it abstracted from the impact of economic and other demographic factors on poverty rates. Changes in these other factors are important for two reasons. First, some changes – such as increased employment amongst mothers – will increase the incomes of low-income families with children and directly reduce child poverty.14 Secondly, changes in median income can have a large impact on child poverty by ‘moving the goalposts’. Figure 4.1 shows that child poverty fell by only 500,000 between 1996–97 and 2000–01, based on a relative poverty line. If the government had instead chosen to fix the poverty line at its 1996–97 level in cash terms, then it could have claimed that child poverty had fallen by 1.4 million.15 Unfortunately, accurately forecasting what might happen to the distribution of income by 2004–05 is very difficult. Median household income is affected by 12 Total income defined as income support, child benefit and the child tax credit. 13 See HM Treasury, Tackling Child Poverty: Giving Every Child the Best Possible Start in Life, London, 2001 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/TacklingChildPoverty.pdf). 14 D. Piachaud and H. Sutherland, ‘Changing poverty post-1997’, CASEpaper 63, London School of Economics, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, 2002, show that changes in employment patterns amongst families with children were very important in reducing child poverty between 1996 and 2000. 15 See M. Brewer, T. Clark and A. Goodman, The Government’s Child Poverty Target: How Much Progress Has Been Made?, Commentary no. 88, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/inequality/childpov.pdf), or M. Brewer, T. Clark and A. Goodman, ‘What really happened to child poverty in the UK in Labour’s first term?’, Economic Journal, forthcoming. 48 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit numerous factors, including growth in earnings and unearned income, as well as changes in the population, household composition, patterns of employment, tax and benefit policies, and take-up of means-tested benefits and tax credits. To make our forecast, we assume that the population, employment rates and household composition do not change from their 2000–01 values, but that real earnings grow in line with past trends. (We assume that all workers benefit from real earnings growth of 2.3% between April 2000 and April 2004, the average annual rate between 1998 and 2001.) Our model estimates that this growth in real earnings increases median income – and thus the poverty line – by an annual average of 1.96%, or 8.05% over four years; real median income grows by less than real earnings because earnings are not the only source of income for the median household, and the progressive nature of the income tax system will tend to make net earnings grow more slowly than gross earnings.16 Other things being equal, a rise in median income resulting from a uniform increase in earnings for all workers will tend to worsen child poverty. This is because earnings are a less important source of income for poor households with children than they are for the median household, and nonearned income sources (except pre-announced changes in taxes and benefits) have not been increased in real terms in our forecast. Table 4.1 shows our overall assessment of likely changes in child poverty between 2000–01 and 2004–05. Column 1 shows the actual level of child poverty in 2000–01. Column 2 shows our estimate of the change in child poverty over the following four years arising solely from the government’s tax and benefit reforms.17 In other words, adjusting suitably for likely price changes over that period, it shows how different child poverty would have been in 2000–01 had the 2004–05 tax and benefit system already been in place then. We estimate that these reforms to personal tax and benefits could reduce the number of children in households with incomes below 60% of the median by 0.8 million. Column 3 gives our forecast of the impact of three years of real earnings growth, pushing around 0.2 million children back below the new, higher poverty line. Column 4 shows the predicted overall impact of both policy changes and earnings growth. Applying this to the actual child poverty data in the first column gives us the predicted level in 2004–05 (column 5). The bottom line is that child poverty is likely to reach 3.3 million children in 2004–05 (AHC), slightly adrift of the government’s target of 3.1 million. For comparison, we also show estimates for other poverty lines the government could have chosen relative to median income. If it had stated that 16 Actual average growth in median income in recent years has been higher than 1.96%, but our estimate is in line with those of other researchers who performed similar calculations (see D. Piachaud and H. Sutherland, ‘Changing poverty post-1997’, CASEpaper 63, London School of Economics, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, 2002). 17 This change is actually calculated from an estimate of child poverty in 2000–01 generated by our model, which simulates tax payments and benefit entitlements rather than drawing on actual tax payments and benefit receipts as the HBAI methodology does. The model gives numbers of children in poverty of 2.4 million (50% median), 4.0 million (60% median) and 5.2 million (70% median). Although these starting levels are fractionally different from the HBAI estimates, the calculated changes can reasonably be applied to the actual figures. 49 Green Budget, January 2003 the target was to be assessed by measuring incomes before housing costs (not shown in the table), our estimate is that child poverty would reach 2.3 million children by 2004–05, precisely meeting the target on that definition.18 The estimates in Table 4.1 have attempted to take into account likely real earnings growth between 2000–01 and 2004–05. But many other things could affect child poverty over this period, such as the number of families and children, and the employment rates of parents and other adults. In addition, our assumptions may be incorrect: for example, earnings growth may differ between low-paid and high-paid workers (although recent evidence supports our assumption of uniform earnings growth19), or take-up of means-tested benefits and tax credits may change. This means that there is a considerable degree of uncertainty around the estimates in Table 4.1. But, on our central forecast, the government will need to do more to help low-income families with children in order to hit its after-housing-costs child poverty target for 2004–05. We quantify how much more in Section 4.4. Table 4.1. Possible changes in child poverty (AHC), 2000–01 to 2004–05 (millions of children) Poverty line (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Actual child Change due to Change due to Total change, Estimate for poverty, tax and benefit earnings 2000–01 to 2004–05 using 2000–01, reforms, growth, 2004–05 HBAI values HBAI 2000–01 to 2000–01 to for 2000–01 2004–05 2004–05 2.5 –1.0 +0.1 –0.9 1.7 50% median 60% 3.9 –0.8 +0.2 –0.6 3.3 median 70% 5.0 –0.6 +0.1 –0.5 4.6 median Notes: Column 4 = column 2 + column 3; column 5 = column 1 + column 4. Column 3 assumes annual real earnings growth of 2.31%. Numbers are rounded to the nearest 100,000, as is the custom in HBAI, but this should not be interpreted as a measure of accuracy. Changes are based on unrounded numbers. Numbers may not sum due to rounding. Source: Authors’ calculations from IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, using 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. 18 D. Piachaud and H. Sutherland, ‘Changing poverty post-1997’, CASEpaper 63, London School of Economics, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, 2002, use a similar methodology. Their results (page 26) are less optimistic than ours, as they estimate that policies introduced between 2000–01 and 2003–04 might reduce child poverty by 0.6 million (AHC) – a slightly smaller number than our estimate for policies introduced between 2000–01 and 2004–05 – and that real earnings growth between 2000–01 and 2003–04 might increase child poverty (AHC) by around 250,000 – a slightly larger number than our estimate of the impact over the period 2000–01 to 2004–05. The differences in estimates are due to differences in the data-sets, in the tax and benefit models or in the assumptions about take-up of benefits and about future real earnings growth. 19 D. Piachaud and H. Sutherland, ‘Changing poverty post-1997’, CASEpaper 63, London School of Economics, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, 2002, find that earnings growth at the bottom of the full-time earnings distribution was around as high as that at the median. 50 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit Nonetheless, it is important to remember that, if the estimates in Table 4.1 are realised and the government misses its target, this would still represent a substantial fall in child poverty from its 1996–97 level. Child poverty would still be at its lowest level since 1990, having fallen by 1.1 million children from its peak of 4.4 million in 1996–97. 4.4 What would it cost to reduce child poverty further? So how generous does the child tax credit need to be for the government to achieve its child poverty target in 2004–05? The rates of the child tax credit for April 2003 have been pre-announced, so the earliest date from which an increase could take effect is April 2004. We have estimated the number of children that would be taken out of poverty by various increases in the perchild element of the child tax credit in April 2004 above the default option of increases in line with earnings growth (which has already been included in the public finance forecasts). By way of comparison, we have also shown the implications of increasing child benefit or increasing the family element of the child tax credit (together with the extra child tax credit for families with babies in their first year). The results are shown in Table 4.2. Table 4.2. Effect of possible increases in per-child element of the child tax credit in April 2004 Increase in per-child element Weekly per-child Number of children taken Cost per of child tax credit in April child tax credit out of poverty (60% year, 2004 2004 rate, 2004 prices median income AHC) prices (£ p.w.) (£ p.w.) (millions) (£ million) Average earnings growth +£2 31.05 0.1 660 Average earnings growth +£3 32.05 0.2 1,000 Average earnings growth +£5 34.05 0.4 1,690 Average earnings growth +£10 39.05 1.0 3,460 Other possible changes in April 2004 (£ p.w.) £3 on child benefit n/a 0.2 2,000 £6 on the family element of n/a 0.2 2,100 child tax credit Notes: ‘Number of children taken out of poverty’ is rounded to the nearest 100,000 and ‘Cost per year’ is rounded to the nearest £10 million, but these should not be interpreted as measures of accuracy. Changes are based on unrounded numbers. The poverty line was allowed to move if the reform altered median household income. Source: Authors’ calculations from IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, using 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. To reduce child poverty from 3.3 million to the target level of 3.1 million, our estimates suggest that the per-child element of the child tax credit would need to be increased by around £3 per week in addition to the indexation in line with earnings growth that has already been promised. This would cost approximately £1 billion (in 2004 prices). According to our calculations, the 51 Green Budget, January 2003 results from the Piachaud and Sutherland study20 suggest that more expenditure than this may be required. Equivalent reductions in child poverty could be achieved by increasing child benefit by £3 per week or by increasing the family element of the child tax credit by £6 per week. But both these options would cost around twice as much, because both would benefit well-off families with children and not just those on low-to-middle incomes.21 Figure 4.4 shows the average percentage income increase in each decile of the population for three of the options in Table 4.2. We can see that the child element of the child tax credit is a well-targeted instrument for tackling child poverty, with the gains concentrated in the bottom half of the income distribution. (The estimated gains have been averaged over all families, whether or not they contain children: the bottom decile gains by less than the second decile because there are fewer children in the bottom decile than in the second decile.) Figure 4.4. Distributional effects of different increases in child-related benefits and tax credits in April 2004 Percentage change in net income 1.5% 1.0% 0.5% 0.0% Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income decile £3 on child element of child tax credit £3 on child benefit £6 on family element of child tax credit Notes: The figure shows gains in addition to the increase to the per-child element of the child tax credit in line with earnings growth in April 2004 to which the government is already committed. Income deciles are derived by dividing all families (with and without children) into 10 equally sized groups according to income adjusted for family size using the McClements equivalence scale. Decile 1 contains the poorest tenth of the population, decile 2 the second poorest and so on, up to decile 10, which contains the richest tenth. Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. 20 D. Piachaud and H. Sutherland, ‘Changing poverty post-1997’, CASEpaper 63, London School of Economics, Centre for Analysis of Social Exclusion, 2002. 21 All families with children gain from increases in child benefit, and increases in the family element of the child tax credit by £6 p.w. would benefit all but around half a million families with children with a combined gross income of over £62,830. 52 Child poverty targets and the child tax credit It is important, though, to remember that the government may have other considerations when thinking about increasing further the amount paid per child. For example, the amount of extra income that parents receive from the government because they have children has increased substantially since 1997: the poorest families now receive more for their first child than a young jobseeking adult is entitled to receive for him or herself.22 Secondly, increases in the child tax credit also have small but adverse effects on parents’ work incentives; these could be counteracted with changes to the working tax credit, but this would increase the cost.23 These factors will need to be considered alongside the desire to reduce child poverty. 4.5 Conclusion Despite its commitment to increase the per-child element of the child tax credit by more than the rate of inflation in April 2004, the government is more likely than not to miss its target of reducing child poverty by a quarter from its 1998–99 level by 2004–05, on an after-housing-costs basis. Once the likely effect of future earnings growth on median income and child poverty is taken into account, around £1 billion of extra spending in 2004–05 may be required for the government to hit this target, although there are considerable uncertainties around this estimate. But if this extra money cannot be found, and if our forecasts for the level of child poverty in 2004–05 are correct, then the government could still point to a substantial fall in child poverty to its lowest level since 1990. Furthermore, if a before-housing-costs definition of child poverty is adopted, our results indicate that the government may indeed hit its target. Mike Brewer and Greg Kaplan 22 See S. Adam, M. Brewer and H. Reed, The Benefits of Parenting: Government Financial Support for Families with Children Since 1975, Commentary no. 91, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/taxben/c91.pdf). The weekly jobseeker’s allowance (JSA) for an adult under 25 will be £43.25 from April 2003, compared with £54.25 in child-related payments that will be received by a non-working family on income support or JSA for their first child – a gap which will widen as the child element of the child tax credit increases in line with earnings growth while there are no real increases in JSA. 23 There are two impacts: increases in any part of the child tax credit reduce the need for parents to work; and increases in the per-child element of the child tax credit widen the range of incomes over which parents can face a marginal deduction rate of 70% (they only receive 30p extra income for each £1 of extra earnings), which reduces the cash gain from working. 53 5. Income tax and National Insurance contributions The Labour manifesto for the 2001 general election promised that ‘we will not raise the basic or top rates of income tax in the next Parliament’.1 This pledge featured heavily in the party’s successful re-election campaign (and, indeed, the previous election campaign of 1997). However, the government refused to rule out increases in other taxes if re-elected, and in his first Budget Speech of the new parliament in April 2002, Chancellor Gordon Brown announced that National Insurance contributions (NICs) for employees, employers and the self-employed would go up with effect from April 2003. The government estimates that the National Insurance (NI) increases will raise around £8.2 billion in 2003–04.2 The Chancellor stated that the increases were necessary to fund the increases in NHS spending also announced in the April 2002 Budget. But increases in NICs of this magnitude, when set against the commitment not to raise income tax, raise several questions. Why did the government feel it necessary to make a pledge on income tax but not on NI? What is the justification for having NI as a separate tax from income tax? Have the two taxes become more alike? And how might the two systems develop in future? In this chapter, we start by briefly discussing the historical relationship between NI and income tax. We then compare and contrast the current income tax system with the current NI regime and look at the distributional effects of the changes scheduled for April 2003. We finish by assessing what further reforms of the NI and income tax systems might be likely, and what might be economically desirable. 5.1 Income tax and National Insurance: a history of convergence Income tax and National Insurance contributions have traditionally played quite separate roles in the tax system. Income tax was introduced in 1799 to raise revenue for general government expenditure. The present structure of the income tax system came into being in 1973: taxpayers have a tax-free personal allowance, and income above this level is taxed at progressively higher rates. In contrast, National Insurance started life in 1948 as a social insurance scheme based on the ‘contributory principle’ – that benefits received should 1 Page 10 of Labour Party, Ambitions for Britain (Labour’s manifesto 2001), London, 2001 (www.labour.org.uk/ENG1.pdf). 2 Source: authors’ calculations from HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, Stationery Office, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_index.cfm) and HM Treasury, Tax Ready Reckoner and Tax Reliefs, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/adtrr02.pdf). 54 Income tax and National Insurance contributions reflect contributions paid. Workers and their employers paid contributions at a flat rate, independent of earnings, in return for entitlement to various flat-rate benefits. 1961 saw a major change as NICs became earnings-related for the first time. Since benefits received bore little relation to previous earnings, this constituted a weakening of the contributory principle and made NICs more like income tax. Since then, the two systems have moved closer together in many more ways – largely through reforms that have made NI operate more like income tax. Under the current system, NICs are levied as a percentage of employees’ earnings and employers’ labour costs above a lower weekly earnings limit. Box 5.1 gives an explanation of the jargon associated with the two systems. Box 5.1. A glossary of income tax and National Insurance terms The personal allowance is the income on which no income tax is paid. In 2003–04, it will be £4,615 per year, or £89 per week (higher for those aged 65 or over). Income immediately above this is taxed at the starting rate, currently 10%. The basic-rate threshold is the level of taxable income (i.e. income above the personal allowance) at which the 10% rate stops and the basic rate of tax, currently 22%, starts to be paid. The threshold for 2003–04 will be announced in the next Budget, but the ‘default’ increase (in line with inflation) would set it at £1,960 per year, so that those with incomes above £6,575 per year, or £126 per week, would pay basic-rate tax. Similarly, the higher-rate threshold is the level of taxable income at which the 40% higher rate of tax becomes payable. Default indexation would take the higher-rate threshold to around £30,500 in 2003–04; higher-rate taxpayers would be those with incomes above £35,115 per year, or £675 per week. The lower earnings limit (LEL) is the level of earnings – £77 per week in 2003–04 – at which employees build up entitlement to NI (contributory) benefits. Employees do not actually start paying contributions, however, until the primary threshold (PT) is reached; employer contributions begin at the secondary threshold (ST) and self-employed contributions at the lower profits limit (LPL). At the moment, the PT, ST and LPL are all equal to the income tax personal allowance, i.e. £89 per week in 2003–04. Until April 2003, the upper earnings limit (UEL) and upper profits limit (UPL), both £595 per week in 2003–04, are the level of earnings at which employees and the self-employed respectively stop paying contributions (employer contributions have no limit). From April 2003, however, contributions of 1% will be payable above the UEL and UPL. The following are some of the most important reforms that have contributed to the convergence of NI and income tax: • In 1990, the income tax system moved from a joint system of assessment (where a married woman’s income was treated as her husband’s income for tax purposes) to an individual system, where both partners pay tax separately. This moved income tax closer to the NI system, which is based 55 Green Budget, January 2003 on individual earnings. Further to this, the married couple’s income tax allowance was abolished in 2000.3 • The levels of weekly earnings at which employees and employers start paying NICs were aligned with the weekly level of the income tax personal allowance4 in 1999 (for employer contributions) and 2001 (for employee contributions). • Both employee and employer NICs used to have a ‘kink’ in the contributions schedule whereby, as weekly earnings passed the lower earnings threshold, contributions became payable on the whole of weekly earnings, not just earnings above the threshold. This kink was finally eliminated in 1999; contributions are now payable only on earnings above the threshold. This is equivalent to the treatment of income in the income tax system. • The tax rates levied on the majority of taxpayers under the two systems have moved closer together. The basic rate of income tax has decreased from 33% in 1979 to 22% in 2002–03. Meanwhile, the rate of employee NICs rose from 6.5% to 10% between 1979 and 2002; it will rise to 11% in 2003. The standard rate of employer NICs rose from 10% to 11.8% between 1979 and 2002; it will rise to 12.8% in 2003.5 • The treatments of those with higher incomes have also become more similar. Before 1985, NICs were not payable on earnings above the weekly upper earnings limit. This was in contrast to income tax, where there was (and is) no such upper limit. However, the UEL on employer NICs was removed in 1985. For employee NICs, the UEL is still in place, but the additional 1 percentage point on employee NICs from April 2003 will apply to earnings above the UEL as well as earnings below it. Meanwhile, the series of progressively higher income tax rates (ranging from 40% to 83%) that existed before 1988 have given way to a single 40% higher rate. • The contributory principle of NI has been eroded over time. Not only are contributions increasingly earnings-related, as discussed above, but also benefits are increasingly related to current circumstances rather than past contributions. Most of the main benefits and tax credits are noncontributory, relying instead on means testing (e.g. housing benefit, working families’ tax credit, income support and the minimum income guarantee), and their generosity has increased in recent years. Contributory benefits such as the basic state pension and contributory jobseeker’s allowance, on the other hand, have mostly been frozen in real terms since the 1980s. Expenditure on contributory benefits has therefore fallen as a proportion of total government benefit (and tax credit) expenditure, from a 3 The introduction of the children’s tax credit in 2001 reintroduced some joint assessment into the income tax system. The married couple’s allowance still exists for people born before 6 April 1935. 4 By ‘weekly level’, we mean the weekly equivalent, for someone working throughout the year, of the level of the annual income tax personal allowance. 5 The employer and employee contribution rates given here apply to individuals contracted into the State Second Pension (S2P). 56 Income tax and National Insurance contributions high of 76% in 1965–66 to an estimated 45% in 2003–04.6 Furthermore, some so-called ‘contributory’ benefits can now be received by people who have not actually paid contributions: for example, since 1999, people with earnings between the LEL and the PT receive benefit entitlements despite not paying contributions; and since 2001, incapacity benefit has been available to non-contributors if they have been unable to work from a young age. Conversely, some ‘contributory’ benefits are not available to people who have contributed (since 2001, for example, incapacity benefit has been means-tested against an individual’s private pension income). Taken as a whole, the changes to NICs and the income tax system detailed above have made the two systems much more similar. Nonetheless, there remain substantial differences between the two systems. In the next section, we look at these differences and examine what the combined structure means for effective marginal tax rates. We also take a detailed look at the distributional effect of the recently announced NI increases. 5.2 The system from April 2003 Despite the convergence of income tax and NICs over the years, there remain differences between them. The most obvious difference is in the rates and thresholds, shown in Table 5.1 (Box 5.2 lists the reforms announced in the 2002 Budget that take effect in April 2003). Both income tax and NICs become payable at the same level – £89 per week, or £4,615 per year – but while income tax has increasing marginal rates, the rate of NICs falls at higher levels of earnings. Table 5.1. Rates of income tax and National Insurance contributions, 2003–04 Income taxa Weekly Tax rate incomeb (%) National Insurance contributions Employee Employer Selfrate (%) rate (%) employed rate (%)c £0–£89 0 0 0 £89–£595 11f 12.8f 8 £595– 1 12.8 1 Weekly earnings £0–£89d 0 £89–£126e 10 £126–£675e 22 £675–e 40 a Gross of tax credits. b Income tax is an annually-based system; this table therefore assumes year-round work. c The self-employed also pay flat-rate contributions of £2 per week if their profits exceed £79. d A higher tax-free allowance applies for those aged 65 or over with all thresholds moved up correspondingly; the extra allowance is tapered away at higher income levels. e Assumes 1.7% indexation of basic- and higher-rate income tax thresholds and statutory rounding. f If an employee is contracted out of the State Second Pension, a reduced rate applies. 6 Source: authors’ calculations from Department for Work and Pensions, ‘Benefit Expenditure Tables’ (www.dwp.gov.uk/asd/asd4/expenditure.htm). 57 Green Budget, January 2003 Box 5.2. Reforms to income tax and National Insurance contributions taking effect in April 2003 • The employer rate of NICs will rise by 1 percentage point. • The employee rate of NICs will rise by 1 percentage point. This increase will extend to earnings above the UEL, which were not previously subject to employee NICs. • The self-employed rate of NICs will rise by 1 percentage point. This increase will extend to profits above the UPL, which were not previously subject to NICs. • The PT, ST and UPL – the level at which NICs start to be paid – will be frozen at £89 per week, and so fall in real terms. • The income tax personal allowance will be frozen at £4,615 in 2003– 04, and so fall in real terms. Figure 5.1. Combined payroll tax schedule, 2003–04 60% Marginal tax rate 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 0 200 400 600 800 1000 Pre-tax earnings (£/week) Notes: Assumes 1.7% indexation of basic- and higher-rate income tax thresholds and statutory rounding. Rates shown are for a childless employee under 60 years old, not contracted out of the State Second Pension, with no unearned income. In so far as the main difference between income tax and NICs is the rate structure, we can simply add up the rates at different earnings levels to find a combined ‘payroll tax’ schedule; this is done in Figure 5.1, which combines income tax, employer NICs and employee NICs.7 7 For Figure 5.1 and what follows, we assume that employees bear the full burden of both employee and employer NICs. The justification for this assumption is discussed in detail in Chapter 9. 58 Income tax and National Insurance contributions Yet this is not quite the whole story: other differences remain. One is that income tax is assessed on an annual basis whereas NI is a weekly system. This may be important for people working less than a full year. Another difference is the treatment of the self-employed. Earnings from selfemployment are treated like any other earnings for income tax purposes. NICs, however, are much lower for the self-employed, as Table 5.1 shows: the contribution rate is lower than for employees, and there is no equivalent to the employer element. The self-employed do pay an additional flat-rate contribution of £2 per week and also have reduced benefit entitlement. But even after accounting for that, the government calculates that, in 2001–02, NI for the self-employed raised £2.4 billion less than it would have done had the Class 1 (employer/employee) system applied.8 The final difference between income tax and NICs is the tax base: NICs are a tax on earnings, income tax a tax on income. Income tax, then, has a broader base: it is payable on unearned income. The biggest single source of unearned income is pension income, but it also includes property income, interest from bank accounts, share dividends and many state benefits. These are subject to income tax but not to NICs.9 Figure 5.1, then, is not a complete representation of income taxation for anyone with unearned or self-employment income: the combined tax rates for these will be lower, since less (or no) NICs are paid. Despite these differences, income tax and NICs are now quite similar. By way of illustration, Figure 5.2 shows the distributional impact of the changes to NICs announced in the 2002 Budget – a freeze in the threshold at which NICs start to be paid, and an extra 1 percentage point on contributions for employers, employees and the selfemployed (including on earnings above the UEL and UPL). Also shown is the impact of an equivalent change to income tax – a freeze in the personal allowance and an extra 2 percentage points on the lower, basic and higher rates. As Figure 5.2 shows, the impacts of these two sets of reforms are similar, although not identical. The income tax rise would cost families more throughout the income distribution – we estimate that it would raise around £1.7 billion more than the reforms to NICs. The main reason is the taxation of unearned income – most of the extra revenue would come from people with higher incomes (and the richest tenth in particular), who not only have more unearned income but also pay tax on it at a higher rate.10 8 Source: HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, Stationery Office, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_index.cfm). 9 The two systems also differ in their treatment of pension contributions: NICs are not paid on employers’ pension contributions but are on individuals’; income tax, by contrast, is not paid on any contributions. 10 Unearned income of higher-rate taxpayers is taxed at the higher rate. Basic-rate taxpayers, however, pay tax on their income from savings at a slightly reduced rate of 20%; we also increase this rate by 2 percentage points for this simulation, though it does not make a large difference to the overall results. 59 Green Budget, January 2003 Figure 5.2. Losses across the income distribution from National Insurance changes announced in the 2002 Budget, and from a package of similar changes to income tax Percentage change in net income 0.0 -0.5 -1.0 -1.5 -2.0 -2.5 -3.0 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income decile NI changes Income tax changes Notes: Income deciles are derived by dividing all families into 10 equally sized groups according to income adjusted for family size using the McClements equivalence scale. Decile 1 contains the poorest tenth of the population, decile 2 the second poorest and so on, up to decile 10, which contains the richest tenth. Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using data from the Family Resources Survey 2000–01. The income tax reforms would also raise more money because of the different treatment of the self-employed. The self-employed will see a 1 percentage point rise in NICs, whereas they would have faced a 2 percentage point rise in their income tax rates had that option been chosen. Employees, by contrast, are affected by both the rise in the employee rate and the rise in the employer rate, and so pay 2 percentage points more in either case. The self-employed are disproportionately represented in the top income decile, which also helps explain why the income tax increase falls more heavily on the top decile than does the NI increase. 5.3 Options for further reform As discussed in Chapter 3, the government may feel it has to raise taxes further in due course to strengthen the public finances. If it chooses to do this by raising payroll taxes, there are a number of routes it could take.11 One obvious option is a straightforward increase in NI rates of the kind announced in the 2002 Budget. The distributional impact of such a rise would 11 It should be noted that changes to NI could not take effect immediately – a result of its weekly structure. Changes could, however, be pre-announced, as they were in the 2002 Budget. 60 Income tax and National Insurance contributions be similar to that shown in Figure 5.2. An uncapped 1 percentage point rise in employee NI would raise about £3.8 billion.12 The innovation in the last Budget of levying 1% employee NICs on earnings above the UEL also creates a precedent: there is ample scope for increases in this new ‘additional rate’ of NICs. A 1 percentage point increase above the UEL (and UPL) alone would raise around £0.8 billion, with the burden of the increase falling mainly on families in the top income decile. Abolishing the UEL (and UPL) altogether would be roughly equivalent to a 10 percentage point increase in the ‘additional’ rate, and would raise around £8.3 billion.13 Rises in income tax rates seem much less likely, primarily because of Labour’s manifesto pledge not to raise the basic or higher rates. The government could still raise money through income tax, however, by freezing or even reducing tax allowances and thresholds. The 2002 Budget froze the personal allowance, and also the PT and ST to keep them all aligned in 2003–04. The Chancellor might plausibly do this again in 2004–05, raising about £0.8 billion. Most of the revenue would come from higher earners (since income tax allowances reduce the amount of income taxed at the highest rate paid by each taxpayer), but middle-income families would lose most as a proportion of income. Reducing the basic-rate threshold seems unlikely because of a manifesto pledge that ‘we will extend the 10p tax band’.14 That leaves the higher-rate threshold and the National Insurance UEL. At present, the higher-rate threshold is higher than the UEL. This causes a dip in the effective tax rate for income between £595 and £675 per week (as shown in Figure 5.1) for which it is hard to find an economic rationale. Aligning the UEL and the higher-rate threshold would correct this anomaly, and would be consistent with previous changes (such as the alignment of the NI thresholds with the income tax personal allowance). Indeed, the Chancellor moved in this direction by increasing the UEL by more than inflation in both April 2000 and April 2001, thus reducing the gap to the higher-rate threshold. An alignment could be achieved either by raising the UEL to match the higher-rate threshold (so that income currently between the two would be subject to ‘standard’ NICs and basic-rate income tax, like the income below it) or by lowering the higher-rate threshold to match the UEL (so that income currently between the two would be subject to ‘additional’ NICs and higherrate income tax, like the income above it). Either reform would be extremely progressive – the richest 10 per cent would provide two-thirds of the revenue, while the bottom half of the income distribution would be virtually unaffected – but they would raise very different amounts of revenue: increasing the UEL 12 A 1 percentage point rise in employer NI would raise slightly more – about £4 billion – because, unlike employee NI, it is payable in respect of employees who are at or above the state pension age. 13 We assume that the UEL would be maintained (at its current level) in its role as a cap on the band of income where the contracted-out rebate applies, as it has been for employer NICs. 14 Page 10 of Labour Party, Ambitions for Britain (Labour’s manifesto 2001), London, 2001 (www.labour.org.uk/ENG1.pdf). 61 Green Budget, January 2003 to the higher-rate threshold would raise around £1 billion, while reducing the higher-rate threshold to the UEL would raise a little over £2 billion. The increasing similarity of income tax and NICs outlined in this chapter makes this discussion of future changes look rather strange from an economic perspective. Why, if the two are so similar, are increases in NICs widely perceived as more likely than increases in income tax? One answer is that Labour has a manifesto commitment not to raise income tax but no such commitment in respect of NICs. But that is, at best, a partial answer: why did Labour feel impelled to make a pledge in respect of one but not the other? Clearly, the government either perceives the two taxes differently or thinks that the public perceives them differently. From a purely economic perspective, it makes little sense to be implacably opposed to a percentage point increase in the basic and higher rates of income tax, but at the same time to have no objection to a National Insurance increase with similar effects over most of the income distribution. The trend towards increased levels of NICs coupled with lower rates of income tax began almost thirty years ago and shows no sign of abating. What this demonstrates is that a pledge by the government or the opposition not to increase basic- or higher-rate income tax means very little in economic terms, as without a pledge not to increase NICs either, there is no barrier to the overall level of taxation on earnings increasing in the future. On economic grounds, it would seem sensible in many ways to aim towards a complete integration of the income tax and NI systems. This would offer the advantages of transparency and administrative efficiency with few apparent drawbacks. The original rationale for separate systems – the ‘contributory principle’ underlying the NI system – is all but obsolete. There is no reason to suppose that the slow death of the contributory principle will reverse, or even halt, in the near future. For example, the basic state pension (easily the biggest contributory benefit) is set to increase in line with prices, whereas the government’s stated long-term aspiration is to increase the non-contributory minimum income guarantee (MIG) for those aged 60 or over in line with earnings. That means the basic state pension is due to become less important relative to the MIG, and contributions records will gradually become less relevant in determining the amount of benefits received by those aged 60 or over. Nor do the other remaining differences between income tax and NI provide a strong justification for maintaining separate systems. Lower rates of taxation on unearned income and on self-employment income create a distortion in favour of these income sources, which is probably undesirable. Yet even if the government wishes to retain either or both of these anomalies, it would still be possible to do so within the income tax system (to have a lower rate of tax on pension income, for example). If the government believes that payroll taxes have different effects depending on whether they are levied on the employer or the employee, another option would be to integrate employee NI with income tax, leaving NI as a pure employer tax. Given these arguments, the barrier to full integration of the two systems seems primarily political. Governments appear to believe that raising NICs is likely to be less costly to them in votes than raising income tax. It will be interesting 62 Income tax and National Insurance contributions to see if the high-profile increases in NICs due to take effect in April change this political calculus. If they do not, full integration of NI and income tax remains much less likely than further gradual alignment, with equalisation of the UEL and higher-rate threshold perhaps the obvious next step. Stuart Adam and Howard Reed 63 6. Company taxation and innovation policy This chapter begins with a discussion of four issues in company taxation. First, we assess the recent government consultation document on reform to corporation tax, which looks at possible changes to the rules for calculating taxable income. (This follows a series of reforms to the taxation of corporate profits since 1997, which are discussed in Chapter 9.) In Section 6.2, we look at the taxation of dividends, in the light of the changes to the UK tax system since 1997 and recent proposals for reform in the USA. In Section 6.3, we assess the structure of North Sea taxation following the changes announced in Budget 2002 and in the 2002 Pre-Budget Report. Then, in Section 6.4, we consider an issue that is not on the government’s immediate agenda, but one where there might be a case for reform – stamp duty on share transactions. The chapter also looks at innovation policy, following the 2002 Pre-Budget Report announcement of a review into the interaction between universities and business, which will report at the same time as a separate review of the UK’s innovation performance. In the final section of the chapter, we examine trends in UK research and development (R&D) activity and consider current policy towards innovation, including the two new R&D tax credits. 6.1 The August 2002 consultation In August 2002, the government issued a consultation document on further reform to the corporation tax system.1 This considered possible reforms in three main areas relating to the calculation of taxable income: the treatment of depreciation and gains and losses on capital assets; the schedular system, which distinguishes between income from different sources; and the distinction between trading companies and investment companies. The objective of the proposed reforms in each area is to align the calculation of taxable income more closely with the measurement of profits in company accounts. This follows the approach taken in recent changes to the taxation of intangible assets (Finance Act 2000), loan relationships (Finance Act 1996) and foreign exchange gains and losses (Finance Act 1993). In many areas, such alignment with accounting practice can achieve useful simplification of the tax system. However, some of the proposals considered in the consultation document could have radical impacts on tax reliefs for depreciation and on the tax treatment of losses, as we discuss in this section.2 As the trading/ 1 HM Treasury and Inland Revenue, Reform of Corporation Tax, London, 2002 (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/consult_new/taxreform_final.pdf). 2 A more detailed response to this consultation is provided by A. Klemm and J. McCrae, Reform of Corporation Tax: A Response to the Government’s Consultation Document, Briefing Note no. 30, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/bn30.pdf). A wider discussion of the issues involved in aligning tax and commercial accounts is provided by G. 64 Company taxation and innovation policy investment company distinction affects only a limited number of firms, our discussion here focuses on the first two issues. Capital allowances Capital equipment that is used in producing goods or supplying services typically falls in value as it is used, and may become worthless at the end of its useful life. This fall in the value of capital assets, known as economic depreciation, represents a cost to the owner, which is reflected in depreciation charges against profits in company accounts, and in capital allowances against taxable income in the corporation tax. Capital allowances claimed in 1999– 2000 amounted to £65 billion, or about half of total income chargeable to corporation tax (net of these and all other allowances).3 About 90% of these capital allowances were for plant and machinery. Any reform to the system of capital allowances could therefore have large effects on the tax bills facing individual companies, even if it were revenue-neutral overall. Capitalintensive industries such as energy, engineering and other manufacturing could be particularly affected. Under the current rules, most types of plant and machinery qualify for a 25% per annum writing-down allowance, on a declining-balance basis.4 There are more generous provisions for favoured forms of investment, such as some energy-saving technologies and investment by smaller companies, and a lower rate for some ‘long-lived’ assets used mainly by utility companies. Industrial buildings benefit from a 4% per annum writing-down allowance on a straightline basis,5 whilst there is no writing-down allowance for commercial buildings. At present, there is no connection between these writing-down allowances prescribed for tax purposes and the depreciation charges that are used in firms’ published accounts. In reporting their profits, firms may use higher or lower depreciation rates, depending on the nature of the capital assets they own. For example, expenditure on computers with very short useful lives may be written off more quickly, whilst expenditure on pipelines with very long useful lives may be written off more slowly. The treatment of these assets in company accounts has no implications for the firm’s corporation tax liability. Replacing the current system of capital allowances by a deduction for the depreciation charge reported in company accounts would have major implications for firms that account for depreciation at substantially different rates from the current schedules of capital allowances. Retailers who depreciate their commercial property would benefit, gaining a deduction for depreciation where none is currently provided under capital allowances. Macdonald, The Taxation of Business Income: Aligning Taxable Income with Accounting Income, Tax Law Review Committee Discussion Paper no. 2, IFS, London, 2002. 3 Inland Revenue Statistics (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats/index.htm). 4 For a £100 investment, the capital allowance is £25 in the first year, £18.75 in the second year (i.e. 25% of the remaining £75 balance), and so on. These allowances are treated as costs in the calculation of taxable income for each period. 5 For a £100 investment, the capital allowance is £4 per year for a period of 25 years. 65 Green Budget, January 2003 Engineering firms that write off their plant and machinery more slowly than the 25% capital allowance rate would tend to lose out, receiving less generous depreciation deductions than under the current tax rules. The consultation document omits any detailed analysis of which sectors would gain and lose from this change, whether the tax relief for depreciation would become more or less generous overall as a result, and what the consequent effects on corporation tax revenues would be. We estimate that, on average, depreciation rates used in company accounts tend to be lower than those specified by capital allowances. If so, tax relief for depreciation would become less generous, on average, if this reform were to be implemented, and corporation tax payments would tend to be higher, unless there were an offsetting reduction in the corporation tax rate. There would also be substantial redistribution of corporation tax payments, with plant-and-machineryintensive sectors such as manufacturing tending to lose and other sectors, such as services, tending to gain.6 Such a change in the tax treatment of depreciation would have a substantial impact on the cost of capital and the incentive to undertake investment in the UK. Existing capital allowances do not provide particularly generous tax relief for depreciation when compared with corporate income taxes in other major economies.7 Whilst there may be a case for linking tax depreciation schedules more closely to economic depreciation rates for assets used by different sectors, or for cutting tax allowances for depreciation overall, such radical reforms should clearly be evaluated with regard to their effects on business investment and corporation tax payments, and not slipped in under the banner of simplifying the calculation of taxable income. A problem with aligning tax and accounting depreciation deductions is that, by choosing to increase the rate at which capital expenditures are written off against profits, firms would be able to defer their corporation tax payments. Not only would this be a potential threat to corporation tax revenues in the longer term, but it would also reduce the quality of the information provided in published accounts. Especially after recent accounting scandals, it would seem risky to introduce tax incentives for companies to produce accounts that may not provide an appropriate measure of profits. To avoid too much abuse, the likely outcome would be prescribed maximum rates of depreciation for different types of assets, similar to the present capital allowances, with accounting depreciation provisions tending to converge on these prescribed rates. So rather than aligning tax allowances with company accounts, the result may be the opposite, i.e. to align accounts with tax rules. 6 A. Klemm and J. McCrae, Reform of Corporation Tax: A Response to the Government’s Consultation Document, Briefing Note no. 30, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/bn30.pdf), discuss the available empirical evidence in more detail. 7 A. Klemm and J. McCrae, Reform of Corporation Tax: A Response to the Government’s Consultation Document, Briefing Note no. 30, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/bn30.pdf), compare the tax treatments of depreciation in 16 OECD countries. 66 Company taxation and innovation policy The schedular system The consultation document also considers changes to the schedular system currently used to compute taxable income, which would have implications for the tax treatment of losses. Like most corporate income taxes, corporation tax is charged when taxable income is positive, but there is not a symmetric treatment when taxable income is negative. A symmetric treatment would require a negative tax payment, or a payment from the Inland Revenue to the firm, equal to the tax rate times the loss. Instead, the loss can, at best, be set against taxable profits from a limited number of earlier years. When this carryback provision is exhausted, losses can only be carried forward to set against taxable profits in subsequent years, with no compensation for the delay before losses can actually be used. These limitations on loss relief discriminate against large, risky investments, which, in the event that they turn out to be unsuccessful, could push the firm into a loss-making position. High tax payments expected if returns turn out to be high are not balanced by tax rebates expected if profits turn out to be negative, an effect that can be avoided if the firm chooses a safer investment with less chance of returning a loss. This effect is particularly important in the case of new, start-up firms, which do not have past profits against which losses can be carried back, and which may not expect to generate positive taxable profits for some considerable time. The tax treatment of the same investment project undertaken by an established firm with profits generated by existing operations is also more generous, which runs counter to the government’s objective of stimulating enterprise and business start-ups. The schedular system in the UK corporation tax introduces further limitations on relief for losses. Profits and losses from different sources are not aggregated at the level of the firm, but are calculated separately under different ‘schedules’, and ‘cases’ within schedules (for example, Schedule A Property Income and Schedule D Case I Trading Income), and for trading income, separately for different trades. In the current year, any losses can generally be offset against current profits from any schedule or trade. Losses carried back or forward, however, can generally only be offset against profits from the same schedule or trade.8 The result is that a loss generated on one activity may not even be offset against a profit generated by the same firm but from a different source and in a different time period. Such losses in an otherwise profitable firm are often called trapped losses, particularly if they stem from a scaled-down or abandoned activity that is not expected ever to produce profits high enough to relieve past losses. The effect of the schedular system is that integrated companies are currently taxed similarly to groups, as group relief also only allows losses to be offset against profits of other subsidiaries in the same accounting period. The origins of the schedules, however, date back to the development of the personal income tax in the nineteenth century, and have no parallel in the calculation of profits in company accounts. 8 The exact limitations on the set-off of losses vary somewhat across different schedules and cases. 67 Green Budget, January 2003 The Inland Revenue estimates that, of the £80 billion losses generated by UK companies in 2000–01, around £15 billion were unrelieved and left to be carried forward to later years. Providing full relief for these losses would therefore be expensive: using the standard corporation tax rate of 30% suggests a cost of around £4.5 billion, compared with total corporation tax receipts in 2000–01 of around £32 billion. Such expensive measures are unlikely to be on the government’s agenda at the present time. The consultation document does not estimate what fraction of these losses would be relieved under various proposed relaxations of the schedular system, but it is likely to be rather small. Of much greater quantitative significance would be changes to the current system of group relief. If the schedular system were to be significantly relaxed or abolished, then there would be a strong case for relaxing the limits on group relief as well, allowing group-wide carryforward of losses. Otherwise, there would be a tax incentive for groups with large stocks of losses carried forward to integrate their subsidiaries, so as to be able to offset these losses against profits from other activities. Another argument for relaxing the limits on group relief would be the logic of aligning taxable income more closely with accounting profit, which would suggest taxing groups of companies on the same consolidated basis as reported in their consolidated accounts. However, the cost of the additional loss relief that this implies may make such changes prohibitively expensive for the foreseeable future. The extent to which changes to the schedular system would deal with the concern over start-up companies is unclear, since relatively few new firms are likely to have income from more than one source. A more targeted approach to this issue would be to allow at least some tax reliefs to be paid immediately to loss-making firms in their start-up phase, along the lines of the R&D tax credit for small and medium-sized companies introduced in April 2000. 6.2 Dividend taxes Since 1997, there have been important changes to the taxation of dividends in the UK – namely, the abolition of repayable tax credits to tax-exempt shareholders in 1997 and the abolition of advance corporation tax (ACT) in 1999. While no new reforms have been announced since the abolition of ACT, this topic remains interesting, especially as the USA has just announced a possible change to its system of dividend taxation. Background Across the world, many different approaches to dividend taxation are taken. This is because different views can be held about the extent to which double taxation of dividends should be avoided. Double taxation can arise because dividends are paid out of taxed profits but may then be subject to income taxes levied on the recipient of the dividend. In a classical system of dividend taxation, corporate taxes and taxes paid by recipients of dividends are completely separate, and dividends therefore face 68 Company taxation and innovation policy taxation both at the firm and at the individual level. Theoretically, there are two ways this double taxation can be completely avoided. One possibility is to tax dividends only at the shareholder level. This can be achieved by a full imputation tax system, in which a tax credit accompanies dividends paid out of taxed profits, reflecting the full amount of corporate tax paid on the underlying profits. The individual can then set this tax credit against his or her own tax liability. If the personal tax rate is higher than the corporation tax rate, additional tax payments are required; if it is lower, some of the tax credit will be paid out to the shareholder. The other possibility is to tax dividends at the company level only. This can be achieved by exempting dividends from income taxation, which is in fact the US proposal. Whilst full imputation ensures that dividends are taxed only once at the recipient’s marginal income tax rate, the latter approach imposes a single flat-rate charge at the corporate income tax rate. In practice, few countries employ any of these systems in a pure form. Instead, most countries operate systems that relieve some, but not all, of the possible double taxation of dividends. Systems practised include: applying a lower personal tax rate on dividends than on other personal income; using partial imputation (i.e. dividends come with a tax credit, but the tax credit does not reflect the full tax paid at the corporate level); or applying a lower corporation tax rate on distributed earnings. The systems of some countries incorporate more than one of these features. The system in the UK From 1973 to 1997, the UK used a partial imputation system, in which dividends were accompanied by a tax credit that was set at the standard personal income tax rate, so that basic-rate taxpayers did not face any additional tax liability on dividend income. Higher-rate taxpayers had to pay additional tax on dividends, and tax-exempt shareholders could claim back the tax credit. The latter point was especially important for pension funds, as a high proportion of shares are held indirectly through such institutions. The reason for calling this system a partial imputation system is that the rate of the tax credit was generally lower than the corporation tax rate. Since the July 1997 Budget, these tax credits are no longer repayable to taxexempt institutional shareholders. For other domestic shareholders, nothing of substance changed,9 so that the UK now has a hybrid system, with partial imputation for taxpaying shareholders and a classical treatment of tax-exempt shareholders. The reform could therefore be seen as a move towards a more classical system of dividend taxation. In effect, the current UK system could also be described as having no income tax on dividends for most domestic shareholders and a preferential tax rate on dividends for higher-rate taxpayers. 9 The tax credit was cut from 20% to 10%, but this did not affect domestic shareholders, because their tax rates on dividend income were reduced correspondingly (currently 10% for basic-rate taxpayers and 32.5% for higher-rate taxpayers). 69 Green Budget, January 2003 The system in the USA The situation in the USA is rather different. As yet, the USA is one of only four OECD countries applying a pure classical system of dividend taxation.10 The recent proposal to abolish dividend taxation at the shareholder level would therefore move the US system more in line with those of other countries, which give some relief for double taxation, even if in very diverse ways. The direction of change in the proposed US reform, away from a classical system, is opposite to the direction of the recent changes in the UK. The final system achieved is, however, rather similar. The only substantial difference in its effect is that the tax liability in the UK is still to some extent determined by the tax rate of the shareholder, as higher-rate taxpayers face an additional tax charge on dividends. The US proposals would abandon progressive taxation of dividends, as dividend income would be subject to a flat-rate charge at the corporate tax rate. The US announcement also contained a proposal to exempt retained profits from capital gains taxation at the personal level. As the practicality of this proposal is somewhat unclear, we do not discuss it further in this section. Effects of reforms The reforms in the UK and those proposed in the USA have both been accompanied by claims that they would have beneficial effects on investment. In the USA, the further claim was made that they would be beneficial for the stock market. Interestingly, even though the reforms go in opposite directions, it has been claimed in both cases that they will lead to higher investment. The argument in the UK was that pension funds were thought to prefer a large share of profits to be paid out rather than reinvested, because only dividends paid out benefited from the tax credit. It was then argued that removing the repayability of the tax credit would diminish the pressure that pension funds were thought to exert on companies to pay out dividends rather than reinvest earnings, possibly to the detriment of investment. If this were right, the US proposals would seem unlikely to lead to higher investment, as they reduce taxes on dividends and therefore make dividend payouts more attractive from the point of view of shareholders. There is another less speculative effect that operates through the cost of capital. Lower taxes on dividend income may reduce the cost of capital for investment financed by issuing new shares, since the anticipated return in the form of future dividend payments is subject to lower taxation. In aggregate, however, most investment is financed not by new equity but by either retained earnings or borrowing.11 The cost of capital using these sources of finance will not change. In particular, since financing investment by retained earnings 10 The other three countries are Switzerland, Luxembourg and the Netherlands. There are other countries that do not have imputation systems; however, as they have reduced income tax rates on dividends, they have in effect relieved some of the double taxation and are therefore not classified here as pure classical systems. These countries include Austria, Belgium, Hungary, Japan, Poland and Sweden. 11 Some firms depend more heavily on new equity finance – for example, small start-up firms. 70 Company taxation and innovation policy exchanges dividends now for the expectation of higher dividends in the future, a permanently lower tax rate on dividends has no effect on the required rate of return. Even for firms using new equity finance, the cost of capital will only fall if their key shareholders are taxpaying individuals, affected by the proposed reform. A large proportion of company equity is owned indirectly through pension funds or plans, which are already exempt from income tax on dividends. The cost-of-capital effect could therefore lead to higher investment for some firms as a result of the proposed US tax change, but it is doubtful that the aggregate effect will be large. The proposed US reform may have other effects. Some stimulus to the stock market is possible, but again not likely to be large, as domestic taxpaying individuals are the only shareholders for whom taxation will change as a result of the reform. More likely effects are changes in the way companies pay out cash to shareholders. The current US tax system taxes dividends more highly than share buy-backs, and arguably this has led to high levels of buy-backs in the USA. Removing the tax disadvantage of dividends may well lead to firms switching from buy-backs to dividend payments. But it should be stressed that this is a change to the form in which cash is paid from firms to their shareholders, not to the level of cash distributed by firms, and consequently it is unlikely to have any substantive effects. To sum up, while many countries have recently changed their dividend tax systems, it is unlikely that the effects on business investment or the stock market have been large. Specifically in the case of the USA, it is difficult to avoid the conclusion that the main effect of the proposed US reform would be to raise the post-tax incomes of individuals who own equities directly rather than through tax-exempt pension plans, with the largest beneficiaries likely to be among the wealthiest stockholders. Whilst such a measure is unlikely to appeal to Gordon Brown, further changes to dividend taxation in the UK should not be ruled out. Whether the UK can keep its current system, which still uses tax credits, will also depend on international developments, such as rulings by the European Court of Justice and the possible drafting of further European Union directives. 6.3 North Sea taxation Changes to North Sea taxation announced in Budget 2002 have some merits, but policy in this area still seems to be driven too much by short-term revenue needs or changes in the oil price. More consideration should be given to creating a stable tax regime that would facilitate long-term investment decisions. The changes announced in the April 2002 Budget include the introduction of a new supplementary charge in addition to corporation tax and new 100% capital investment allowances, plus the abolition of licence royalties. The first two changes applied with immediate effect, but the abolition of licence royalties was subject to consultation on its timing. In the November 2002 PreBudget Report, it was announced that they would be abolished from 1 January 2003. 71 Green Budget, January 2003 Box 6.1. North Sea taxation The following taxes and charges are levied on North Sea production. Most remaining taxes are charged on a measure of profits, but the exact definition of taxable profits varies across taxes. The taxes charged vary with the date of approval of a field. A summary is given in Table 6.1. Petroleum revenue tax (PRT): Charged on profits at a rate of 50% on fields approved prior to 15 March 1993. Corporation tax (CT): Charged on profits at a rate of 30% on all fields. This is the same tax as charged on the UK mainland, except that it is ring-fenced, i.e. losses from other activities cannot be set against profits from oil and gas production. Supplementary charge: Charged on profits at a rate of 10% on all fields. Unlike for corporation tax purposes, financing expenses (mainly interest) are not deductible. Prior to 1 January 2003, there were also: Licence royalties: Charged on gross value of output, less some limited expenditure, at a rate of 12.5% on fields approved prior to 31 March 1982. Table 6.1. Applicable taxes and marginal tax rates by date of approval of field Date of approval of oilfield Up to 31/3/82 1/4/82–15/3/93 Since 16/3/93 Taxes that apply: Marginal tax rate CT, supplementary charge, PRT, licence royalties (until 31/12/02) CT, supplementary charge, PRT CT, supplementary charge 73.8% until 31/12/02 70% from 1/1/03 70% 40% Economic effects of the reforms The new 10% supplementary charge and the 100% capital allowances are in line with the economic theory of resource taxation. Many economists have argued that taxes levied on profits from the exploitation of natural resources should be neutral with respect to investment. In other words, they should not discourage investment in projects that would be profitable in the absence of taxation. This can be achieved by taxing economic rents rather than total profits. Economic rents are any profits in excess of the minimum level that makes a project commercially viable. Extracting natural resources typically generates a high level of economic rents, as the underlying resources are intrinsically scarce. The level of rents an oilfield generates also depends strongly on the price of crude oil and therefore varies if prices are volatile. Capital allowances of 100% ensure that a large share of the minimum required 72 Company taxation and innovation policy return to a project remains untaxed,12 while the supplementary charge increases the tax rate on rents. These two changes together can thus be seen as a step towards economically efficient rent taxation for new investment activity in the North Sea. The remaining change is the abolition of licence royalties. This only affects oilfields approved prior to 31 March 1982, as only those fields were liable to royalties. Royalties were levied on the gross value of output, less some limited expenditure. Being revenue-based, royalties can have extremely harmful effects on incentives to invest. Not only are they charged on fields earning less than the minimum required return, but they can even apply to loss-making fields, as most costs are not deductible in the calculation of their base. The use of royalties also meant that there were three different tax regimes coexisting in the North Sea, depending on the date of approval of a field. Their abolition reduces this number to two. (See Box 6.1 for a summary of North Sea taxation.) Effects on revenues The combined effect of the 10% supplementary charge and the new 100% investment allowances is to increase tax revenues by about £600 million yearly by 2004–05.13 Licence royalties raised £558 million in 2001–02,14 just under 11% of total tax revenues from the North Sea. However, as royalties were deductible as an expense for all other North Sea taxes, the revenue cost of their abolition is estimated to average £143 million per year.15 The net effect of all the new changes to North Sea taxes will therefore be to raise annual revenues by nearly half a billion pounds. Conclusion Although the recent changes have merit in themselves, it is important to view North Sea taxation in historical perspective. Too often in the past, North Sea tax rules have changed in response to short-term revenue needs or changes in the oil price. Investment in the North Sea needs to be planned over a long time horizon, and stability is needed to allow firms to make informed decisions. This implies the need for a stable tax regime that is able to cope automatically with the volatility of oil prices. The current reforms arguably did not go far enough as there are still two different tax regimes, depending on the date of approval of a field. While opinions on the optimal level of taxation may differ, it is hard to see how 12 Some normal profits will still be taxed, because the 100% allowance does not apply to all capital investment and because the value of any unused allowances diminishes in presentvalue terms. 13 Table A.1 of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Budget/bud_bud02/budget_report/bud_bud02_repchapa.cfm?). 14 Table 11.11 of Inland Revenue Statistics (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats/corporate_tax/ct_t11_1.htm). 15 Table B.4 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Pre_Budget_Report/prebud_pbr02/report/prebud_pbr02_repannexb1.cfm?). 73 Green Budget, January 2003 different rates on fields approved at different times form part of a welldesigned tax system. The argument that high taxes on old fields do not cause any harm because investment is a sunk cost does not completely hold. As older fields reach the end of their lifetimes, incremental investment is often needed. Premature abandonment of fields would be undesirable, as the cost of reopening fields later is likely to be prohibitive and any unused resources would potentially be lost. 6.4 Stamp duty on shares In 2001–02, stamp duty on share transactions raised £2.9 billion, down from £4.5 billion in 2000–01. This represents about ¾% of total public sector net receipts, a small but not insignificant sum.16 The Chancellor’s fiscal room for manoeuvre is clearly limited in the forthcoming Budget, but given his oftstated goal of increasing productivity, there is no reason why, in principle, he could not consider policy change involving a reduction in the rate of stamp duty on shares. Stamp duty is levied at ½% of the purchase price on all share transactions in UK incorporated companies. Reducing stamp duty on shares – perhaps instead of a reduction in a less distorting tax such as corporation tax – would be likely to boost productivity for three main reasons. First, stamp duty lacks any investment allowances and is therefore likely to discourage investment more than other kinds of capital taxes. Secondly, it reduces the efficiency of the stock market for UK listed companies by raising transactions costs and possibly increasing share price volatility. Finally, it distorts merger and acquisition activity, producing a bias towards overseas rather than UK ownership of companies. Each of these effects is discussed in turn below. Stamp duty is levied on the purchase price of a share. Unlike corporation tax, which taxes profits after allowing at least partially for the cost of investment, stamp duty in effect taxes both the full amount invested and the subsequent profits. Thus, for a given revenue yield, stamp duty imposes a heavier tax burden on investments that just break even, making it more likely that the tax will prevent them taking place. Stamp duty on shares is therefore likely to be a less efficient way of raising revenue than corporation tax. Because stamp duty is levied on transactions, it directly reduces share turnover and market liquidity, thereby reducing the efficiency of the market in UK company shares wherever they are traded. The limited empirical evidence available suggests that reducing the rate of stamp duty on shares may increase share turnover substantially.17 Transactions taxes such as the ‘Tobin tax’ on foreign exchange transactions have been proposed as a way of reducing price volatility and therefore risk in financial markets by discouraging short-term speculative behaviour. However, stamp duty may actually increase volatility 16 Inland Revenue Statistics (www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats/index.htm). 17 See table 3.1 of M. Hawkins and J. McCrae, Stamp Duty on Share Transactions: Is There a Case for Change?, Commentary no. 89, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/comm89.pdf). 74 Company taxation and innovation policy by reducing the liquidity of the market and increasing the price impact of a given size of share transaction. The empirical evidence is mixed, but on balance it does not support the idea that stamp duty on share transactions is likely to reduce price volatility.18 Stamp duty may also distort the market for corporate control. A UK company planning a foreign takeover will be willing to pay less than an otherwise identical overseas competitor for the target company, due to the stamp duty that its shareholders will have to pay on future share transactions in the foreign subsidiary. On the other hand, a foreign company considering a takeover of a UK company will be willing to pay more for it than otherwise identical UK companies, since it will take the shares in the company outside the stamp duty base. The resulting distortion to merger and acquisition activity means that companies may end up not being run by the set of managers that would deliver the best performance. In the last Budget, which raised taxes overall, the Chancellor still found room to spend £900 million on measures designed to raise productivity.19 If he wishes to focus on this goal again, then taking together the effects described above, there may be a case for reducing stamp duty on shares to alleviate these distortions. 6.5 R&D and policy towards innovation Following the introduction of a research and development (R&D) tax credit for larger firms in Budget 2002, the 2002 Pre-Budget Report went on to announce an independent review into collaboration between business and universities. The review will report by Summer 2003, around the same time as the Department of Trade and Industry (DTI) Innovation Review, which is to examine business innovation and its contribution to UK productivity growth. This section documents trends in UK R&D over the last two decades and discusses the role of government in supporting R&D and innovation. It summarises recent changes to the tax treatment of R&D, and discusses the current direction of government policy towards innovation. Trends in UK R&D Gross expenditure on R&D as a percentage of GDP or national income (GERD intensity) has declined steadily in the UK over the last two decades, while in other G5 countries it has either increased or shown little overall change. In particular, while all of the G5 experienced stagnant or falling GERD intensity between 1990 and 1994, the USA, Japan and Germany all showed strong increases over the second half of the 1990s. In contrast, the UK 18 See section A.3 of M. Hawkins and J. McCrae, Stamp Duty on Share Transactions: Is There a Case for Change?, Commentary no. 89, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/corptax/comm89.pdf). 19 HM Treasury, Budget 2002: The Strength to Make Long-Term Decisions, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/Budget/bud_bud02/bud_bud02_index.cfm?). 75 Green Budget, January 2003 continued to decline after 1994, with signs of a small pick-up only emerging after 1998. The result is that the UK now has levels of GERD intensity up to 1 percentage point of national income lower than other G5 countries. (See Figure 6.1.) Figure 6.1. GERD as a percentage of GDP: G5 countries GERD as a % of GDP 3.0 2.5 2.0 1.5 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Year UK USA France Germany Japan Note: Data for Germany cover West Germany until 1990 and unified Germany from 1991. Source: OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org). GERD is composed of three main constituent parts according to who performs the R&D. By far the largest component is business enterprise expenditure on R&D (BERD), followed by higher education expenditure on R&D (HERD) and government expenditure on R&D (GOVERD). GERD can also be broken down according to who funds the R&D, which may not be the same as who performs it. The main sources of funding are government (including Research Councils and Higher Education Funding Councils), domestic business enterprise, abroad, and other national sources (mainly private non-profit organisations). Breakdowns of GERD both by who performs the R&D and by who funds it are shown in Table 6.2. The shares of GERD funded and carried out by government fell sharply between 1981 and 1990, with a smaller decline between 1990 and 2000.20 The share funded from abroad has been rising steadily over the period. Within BERD, there has also been a shift in funding away from government and towards domestic business and overseas sources, as Table 6.3 shows. 20 The Atomic Energy Authority was transferred from the government sector to the business enterprise sector after 1986. While the effect of this transfer and later privatisations is to overstate slightly the extent of the trend away from government activity, the overall picture is not significantly affected. 76 Company taxation and innovation policy Table 6.2. Breakdown of R&D by who performs it and who funds it GERD as a % of GDP GERD, £ma % of GERD by who performs it: BERD HERD GOVERD Of which: defence civil % of GERD by who funds it: Government Of which: defence civil Domestic business Of which: defence civil Abroad Other national sources 1981 2.38% 13,720 1990 2.15% 16,381 2000 1.86% 17,532 63% 14% 21% – – 71% 16% 13% 6% 7% 66% 21% 12% 8% 4% 50% – – 41% – – 7% 2% 34% 14% 20% 50% 3% 47% 12% 4% 29% 8% 21% 49% 3% 46% 16% 6% a In millions of 2001 pounds sterling, deflated by the GDP deflator. Note: Figures do not sum to 100 as the private non-profit sector has been omitted from the table. Sources: OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org); ONS, Gross Expenditure on Research and Development, London, 2002 (www.statistics.gov.uk). Table 6.3. Percentages of BERD by who funds it % of BERD by source of funding Government Domestic business Abroad Other national sources 1981 30% 61% 9% – 1990 16% 68% 16% – 2000 9% 70% 21% – Source: OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org). Almost all of the fall in GERD intensity over the 1990s is due to a fall in BERD intensity, its largest component. In particular, Figure 6.2 shows that BERD intensity continued to fall from 1994 to 1998 in the UK, while it was rising in the USA, Japan and Germany, and only began to recover after 1998. In fact, the level of UK spending on BERD was only very slightly higher in real terms in 2000 than in 1990. BERD is particularly significant because it is the most commercially relevant component of GERD, and it is also the component that should be affected by the new R&D tax credits. A key feature of UK R&D performance over the 1990s has been the rapidly increasing amount of R&D done by UK firms abroad, especially in the USA. Figure 6.3 shows total levels of UK R&D from two different sources over the period 1992–2000. The first is BERD as discussed above, which includes all R&D that is performed in the UK, while the second comes from the DTI’s R&D Scoreboard. This lists all R&D done by UK firms including their 77 Green Budget, January 2003 subsidiaries abroad, plus R&D done by UK subsidiaries of foreign firms, as reported in company accounts. The R&D Scoreboard figure thus corresponds Figure 6.2. BERD as a percentage of GDP: G5 countries BERD as a % of GDP 2.5 2.0 1.5 1.0 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Year UK USA France Germany Japan Notes: Data for the UK and Germany extend up to 2001. Data for Germany cover West Germany until 1990 and unified Germany from 1991. Source: OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org). Figure 6.3. UK R&D levels: BERD and R&D Scoreboard R&D level, 1992=100 200 150 100 50 0 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 Year BERD R&D Scoreboard Note: Nominal levels have been deflated by the GDP deflator and rebased to equal 100 in 1992. Sources: OECD, Main Science and Technology Indicators, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org); Department of Trade and Industry, R&D Scoreboard, 1993–2001. 78 Company taxation and innovation policy roughly to the BERD figure plus the R&D done by UK firms abroad.21 The graph shows that R&D spending by UK firms has grown much faster over the 1990s than R&D performed in the UK. This discrepancy raises the question of whether we should be concerned from a policy point of view with R&D that is located in the UK or R&D that is done by UK firms. The latter may be more important if firms are locating R&D abroad in order to source new technologies from the cutting edge of innovation.22 Figure 6.4. UK BERD as a percentage of GDP: industry breakdown BERD as a % of GDP 1.5 Services 1.0 Aerospace Motor vehicles Pharmaceuticals 0.5 Chemicals Machinery and equipment Other manufacturing 0.0 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Year Source: OECD, Analytical Business Enterprise Research and Development, Paris, 2002 (www.sourceoecd.org). The industry composition of UK BERD has changed over the last two decades. Figure 6.4 shows UK BERD intensity between 1987 and 2000 broken down into broad industrial sectors. Most R&D is done in manufacturing industries, with ‘pharmaceuticals’ now the largest single contributor to aggregate BERD. Most of the decline in overall intensity during the 1990s can be explained by the ‘chemicals’, ‘machinery and equipment’ and ‘other manufacturing’ sectors. ‘Pharmaceuticals’ is the only sector to have increased its contribution to BERD intensity over the period, replacing ‘machinery and equipment’ as the largest contributor in about 1996. A fall in aggregate BERD intensity over time can be decomposed into two contributing factors: a fall in intensity within industries, and a shift in the 21 There are some differences in the definition of eligible R&D between the two. For example, the R&D Scoreboard does not include R&D done under contract for government or other firms. These differences should not seriously affect the comparison of overall trends. 22 See M. Serapio and D. Dalton, ‘Globalization of industrial R&D: an examination of foreign direct investments in R&D in the United States’, Research Policy, 1999, vol. 28, pp. 303–16. The authors suggest that this ‘technology-sourcing’ behaviour is increasingly common amongst foreign firms that locate R&D activity in the USA. 79 Green Budget, January 2003 composition of output away from high-intensity towards low-intensity industries. Figure 6.4 does not distinguish between declines in intensity within industries and shifts in activity between industries. Almost all OECD countries have seen their service sectors grow faster than manufacturing over the last twenty years, and this would automatically tend to reduce aggregate BERD intensity due to the second, between-industry factor. However, almost all of the decline in aggregate BERD intensity in the UK relative to other G5 countries during the mid-1990s is due to a fall in R&D intensity within manufacturing industries, rather than to a particularly rapid decline in the share of manufacturing activity in the UK over this period.23 Government policy towards innovation The government intervenes in innovation markets in a number of ways. As shown above, a significant part of R&D expenditure is financed directly by government. Other forms of intervention include R&D tax credits, support for technology transfer between universities and business, and measures designed to overcome failures in financial markets. In addition, government funds education and other aspects of national infrastructure that are essential inputs into R&D and innovation, and provides patent protection and regulation. In this section, we briefly describe some of these measures and discuss the rationales behind them. Direct support Direct government support for innovation largely consists of funding for R&D. This funding comes through one of three channels: directly from central government departments (about 50%), from the Research Councils (about 25%) and from the Higher Education Funding Councils (about 25%).24 Where the R&D is actually carried out varies between the different channels. For example, in 2000, about 45% of R&D funded directly by government departments was performed in government laboratories and about 40% was performed by businesses, with the majority of the rest performed in higher education institutions. In contrast, almost all of the R&D funded through the other two channels was carried out in higher education institutions. There are several reasons why government may want to fund or carry out R&D. In the case of defence R&D, the government is a provider of a service – namely, national defence – to the country. The government has considerable information advantages over the private sector as regards its defence needs, suggesting a role for government in funding defence-related R&D. Whether the government carries out this type of R&D itself or funds the private sector to carry it out should be decided on grounds of cost-efficiency and perhaps also the need for secrecy. In 2000, just under a third of all R&D funded by government was for defence purposes. This contrasts with only 6% of R&D 23 See R. Griffith and R. Harrison, IFS Working Paper, forthcoming. 24 ONS, R&D Performed in the UK in Each Sector According to Source of Finance, London, 2002 (www.statistics.gov.uk/STATBASE/tsdataset.asp?vlnk=584). 80 Company taxation and innovation policy funded by businesses, although over half of the defence R&D funded by government was actually carried out by businesses.25 Another reason why the government may want to fund R&D is that it would not otherwise be funded by the private sector because it would not be profitable for any particular firm to fund it. R&D covers a spectrum, with general scientific research that does not have a specific commercial use in mind at one end, and R&D designed around the introduction of a specific commercial product or process at the other. The market will provide weaker incentives to undertake the former kind of R&D because it is more difficult for an individual firm to appropriate the benefits of this type of research. In this context, new knowledge can be thought of as a public good, in that once it is generated it can be used by everyone. Thus, in the absence of government intervention, if all R&D were funded by businesses, there would be too little of this type of research from society’s point of view.26 These kinds of concerns apply particularly to fundamental scientific research. This is the main economic argument behind government funding for research in the higher education sector, via the Research Councils and Higher Education Funding Councils. These institutions should ideally act as agents of government to commission and deliver research that fulfils the needs of society as a whole and that would not be provided by the private sector. As mentioned above, government also directly funds R&D performed by businesses. This direct funding in the UK has declined in real terms over the last twenty years. Over the last decade, about 75% of it has been for defence purposes, with the remainder for civil R&D. Again, the idea that businesses cannot completely capture all the benefits of their research forms the main justification for this kind of funding. R&D tax credits Direct funding is not the only way that the government can support R&D performed by the private sector. In recent years, there has been a general trend in many OECD countries away from direct grants and towards indirect assistance via the favourable tax treatment of R&D expenditure. One reason is that businesses may, in many cases, have better information than government as regards which programmes of research are likely to be successful. Tax credits attempt to stimulate private sector R&D by reducing its cost while keeping control over the nature and direction of research in the hands of businesses. With the introduction of the R&D tax credit for small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in April 2000 and for larger firms in April 2002, the UK has now joined several other OECD countries in supporting private sector R&D by this method. The SMEs tax credit rate is 50% and the rate for larger firms is 25%. Both credits operate as an extra deduction, which in practice means that qualifying 25 ONS, Sources of Funds for Civil and Defence R&D in UK Businesses, London, 2002, www.statistics.gov.uk/STATBASE/tsdataset.asp?vlnk=571. 26 More generally, the patent system is one way in which government intervenes to overcome this appropriation problem: ensuring that inventors are able to profit from their inventions protects their incentives to innovate. 81 Green Budget, January 2003 SMEs are able to deduct 150%, and larger firms 125%, of eligible current R&D expenditure from their taxable profits in the year it is incurred.27 The SMEs credit also has a refundable component. Qualifying SMEs with insufficient taxable profits to claim the full deduction can claim a cash payment equal to 24% of eligible expenditure, instead of carrying forward eligible R&D losses to offset against future profits. The amount payable is limited to the company’s PAYE and National Insurance contributions for the period. The SMEs credit was projected to cost the exchequer around £100 million in lost revenue in 2001–02 and £150 million per year from 2002–03, potentially benefiting around 4,500 firms.28 The actual cost in 2001–02 is estimated in the 2002 Pre-Budget Report to have been only £80 million,29 although it is as yet unclear whether this was due to lower-than-expected take-up or lower R&D per SME. The equivalent cost of the tax credit for large firms was forecast to be £200 million in the first year, rising to £400 million by 2004–05.30 Estimates of actual costs will not be available until after the end of the current tax year. These figures compare with £1.5 billion of direct government funding for private sector R&D in 2001, of which only £190 million was for non-defence purposes.31 The 2002 Pre-Budget Report states that one of the areas to be covered by the forthcoming review into business–university collaboration will be the effectiveness of the R&D tax credits in stimulating business demand for research and skills. While evaluation is extremely important for the design of successful policy, it should be stressed that the effects of these policies are only likely to be fully realised over a longer time period. Evidence from the USA and other countries suggests that firms’ responses to the introduction of R&D tax credits are characterised by long lags while investment and research plans respond to the new incentives, with the full response only realised after as long as 10 years.32 This suggests that the government should resist the temptation to alter policies significantly in the short term, so that the policy regime has a chance to ‘bed down’. The interaction between the R&D tax credits and other forms of government support for innovation differs between the two tax credits. The R&D tax credit 27 The R&D allowance allows firms to deduct 100% of capital expenditure on R&D from their taxable profits. This is already more generous than standard capital allowances. 28 HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, London, 1999 (http://archive.treasury.gov.uk/budget/1999/fsbr/29807.htm). 29 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 30 Table A.1 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_bud02/budget_report/bud_bud02_repchapa.cfm). 31 ONS, Sources of Funds for Civil and Defence R&D in UK Businesses, London, 2002 (www.statistics.gov.uk/STATBASE/tsdataset.asp?vlnk=571). 32 See, for example, N. Bloom, R. Griffith and J. Van Reenen, ‘Do R&D tax credits work? Evidence from an international panel of countries, 1979–1994’, Journal of Public Economics, 2002, vol. 85, pp. 1–31. 82 Company taxation and innovation policy for SMEs is unavailable on projects that have benefited from notified State Aids such as DTI Smart or Link awards, and is restricted to the unsubsidised portion of R&D expenditure for projects benefiting from non-State Aids.33 Larger firms, on the other hand, can claim the R&D tax credit even on R&D that has been partly or fully subsidised directly. They also receive the full credit on R&D subcontracted to universities and other non-profit bodies such as scientific research organisations or NHS bodies, but not on other subcontracted R&D. SMEs receive a credit on 65% of all subcontracted R&D expenditure provided they retain intellectual property rights. Other policies Government policy towards science and innovation has also focused on the science base and on the efficient use of research – for example, through knowledge transfer from universities to businesses. In July 2002, the government published its science strategy, Investing in Innovation,34 and the November Pre-Budget Report announced an independent review into business–university collaboration. The review will report by Summer 2003, around the same time as the DTI Innovation Review, which is to examine business innovation and its contribution to UK productivity growth. There are currently a large number of relatively small-scale policies aimed at enhancing knowledge transfer, especially between universities and businesses. These include the Higher Education Innovation Fund, with funding projected to be £90 million by 2005–06, and other DTI knowledge-transfer activities, projected to cost £300 million by 2005–06. Together with the Wellcome Trust and the Gatsby Foundation, the government has funded the University Challenge scheme. This is aimed at encouraging commercial spin-offs from university research, with a total £30 million of initial investment capital so far combined with £40 million from private sector sources.35 The forthcoming reviews might provide a good opportunity to examine the economic rationales for such schemes, the incentives each scheme provides for innovation and commercialisation of research, and the interactions between different policies. Economic justification of such policies should identify specific market failures – for example, those leading to insufficient uptake by businesses of new technologies developed in universities; in the case of the University Challenge scheme, a case might be made that private investors do not have sufficient information to determine whether to invest in new technologies. A further issue is whether any of the schemes distort firms’ decisions about how to implement and organise new innovations. For example, the University Challenge scheme only funds the commercialisation 33 The legal definition of State Aids is set out in Article 87(1) of the Treaty of Rome. A subsidy is considered a State Aid when the effect of aid: distorts competition; is selective in its effects (e.g. only affects subgroups of firms, or only affects businesses in a specific region or locality); or affects trade, or could potentially affect trade, between EU member states. 34 HM Treasury, Department of Trade and Industry and Department for Education and Skills, Investing in Innovation: A Strategy for Science, Engineering and Technology, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/spending_review/spend_sr02/spend_sr02_science.cfm). 35 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 83 Green Budget, January 2003 of research through start-ups and not through licensing agreements, which may be more suitable in some cases. Stephen Bond, Rupert Harrison, Mike Hawkins, Alexander Klemm and Helen Simpson 84 7. Childcare subsidies The link between the affordability of good-quality childcare and the ability of mothers to undertake paid employment remains at the centre of policy debate, even though a higher proportion of mothers are currently active in the formal labour market than ever before. There are concerns that mothers are constrained from paid employment by a lack of suitable childcare options1 and that care costs are rising, consuming a greater proportion of families’ financial resources. In addition, there is an ongoing debate about whether the type of care that is available and affordable is beneficial to children. In his Pre-Budget Report of November 2002, the Chancellor said the government wanted to help ‘parents to make real and effective choices on balancing work and family life’. Over the last decade, several initiatives have been introduced to help families with the cost of childcare. A childcare deduction was introduced in family credit in 1994 and expanded with the introduction of the working families’ tax credit (WFTC) in 1999. The Childcare Voucher Scheme (later the nursery education grant) was implemented in 1997. In April, the childcare credit currently included in the WFTC will transfer to the new working tax credit (WTC). The types of care eligible for the childcare credit will be extended in a limited way ‘to include those who use approved childcare in their own home, benefiting, among others, parents of disabled children and those who work outside conventional hours’ (italics added).2 Further plans for the expansion of the types of care covered by the credit have been announced, although many are relatively minor extensions.3 This chapter considers the potential effects on the number of eligible families and the annual budget cost of further expanding the scope and generosity of the childcare credit. The estimates are initially made under the unrealistic 1 For example, see paragraph 3.26 on page 21 of HM Treasury and Department of Trade and Industry, Balancing Work and Family Life: Enhancing Choice and Support for Parents, January 2003 (www.dti.gov.uk/er/individual/balancing.pdf). 2 Page 91 (chapter 5) of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/report/prebud_pbr02_repchap5.cfm) 3 It has been announced that the Home Childcarers Scheme will be opened to existing childminders and that consideration will be given to ‘how to widen entry into the scheme to include people who are not already childminders’. The type of care eligible for the childcare credit will also be broadened by expanding the regulation required for eligibility to domiciliary workers and nurses employed through agencies and to providers who offer childcare exclusively to children over the age of 7 (paragraphs 4.59 and 4.60 on page 36 of HM Treasury and Department of Trade and Industry, Balancing Work and Family Life: Enhancing Choice and Support for Parents, January 2003 (www.dti.gov.uk/er/individual/balancing.pdf)). In addition, the government is considering reforms to tax and National Insurance incentives to expand employer-supported childcare (box 1.1 on page 3 of HM Treasury and Department of Trade and Industry, Balancing Work and Family Life: Enhancing Choice and Support for Parents, January 2003 (www.dti.gov.uk/er/individual/balancing.pdf)). 85 Green Budget, January 2003 assumption that childcare and employment behaviour remains unaltered by the changes, but this is followed by a discussion of the possible reactions in family childcare and work choices.4 Section 7.1 briefly reviews the arguments for government subsidies in the childcare market, while Section 7.2 describes the current employment and childcare choices of families. A description of options for expanding the childcare credit is presented in Section 7.3, followed by the estimated potential impacts in Sections 7.4–7.7. Section 7.8 concludes. 7.1 Why subsidise childcare? The case for subsidising childcare is essentially twofold. First, it is argued that mothers should be encouraged to work in formal paid employment: to reduce gender inequalities in the labour market; to make the best use of the potential labour force and thereby improve economic efficiency; and to reduce the dependence of poorer households on the state. Secondly, if pre-school children benefit from childcare (other than that of family), it may be desirable on equity grounds to ensure that it is available to poorer families. In the absence of government intervention, families may not make the best employment and childcare choices, for several reasons: the benefits may be social as well as private; parents may lack complete information or be shortsighted; or parents may be unable to afford adequate childcare. For these reasons, it may be desirable for government policies to help families with the cost of care.5 The design of the subsidy may depend upon the particular rationale and potential cost. 4 Budget costs of different childcare subsidies have been estimated previously in A. Duncan, C. Giles and S. Webb, The Impact of Subsidising Childcare, Research Discussion Series no.13, Equal Opportunities Commission, Manchester, 1995, and in A. Duncan and C. Giles, ‘Should we subsidise pre-school childcare, and if so, how?’, Fiscal Studies, 1996, vol. 17, no. 3, pp. 39–61. These publications use data from the Family Resources Survey from the early 1990s together with childcare information from the 1991–92 General Household Survey. They include potential labour supply responses, but only consider formal types of childcare for preschool children and limit changes in childcare choices to those related to employment responses. The budget cost of a particular childcare tax credit has also been analysed using aggregate statistics in Ernst & Young, ‘Potential cost of the childcare tax credit’, Tax Policy Discussion Paper, 2001. 5 In addition, there may be supply constraints in the provision of childcare due to inefficiencies in the childcare market. This problem may be addressed by more direct measures to improve the supply of childcare, such as those included in the government’s National Childcare Strategy and financed by the combined budgets for Sure Start, childcare and early years programmes (paragraph 2.2 on page 1 of HM Treasury and Department of Trade and Industry, Balancing Work and Family Life: Enhancing Choice and Support for Parents, January 2003 (www.dti.gov.uk/er/individual/balancing.pdf)). 86 Childcare subsidies 7.2 Families’ employment and childcare use This section outlines the current employment status of parents and the patterns of childcare use by working families. These tables and the analysis below use a sample of families with dependent children (those aged under 16, or under 19 and in full-time education) from three years of the Family Resources Survey (1998–99 to 2000–01).6 Over three-quarters of families (78%) have at least one parent working in paid employment for 16 or more hours each week. Some 39% of all families have two working adults, while single parents working 16 or more hours each week constitute 10% of all families. But, as Table 7.1 shows, the likelihood that a parent is in paid employment depends considerably on whether there is a partner present and on the age and number of children in the family. Single parents (predominantly single mothers) are much less likely to be working than mothers with a partner. Mothers are less likely to be in employment if at least one child is of pre-school age or if there is more than one child. Table 7.1. Employment patterns among families with children Percentage of families with weekly hours of work: no one works 16+ only mother works 16+ only father works 16+ both parents work 16+ single parent works 16+ Couples Pre-school Only school children children 1 2+ 1 2+ Single parents Pre-school Only school children children 1 2+ 1 2+ All 7 2 38 53 – 73 – – – 27 22 3 26 39 10 10 2 53 35 – 9 5 23 62 – 9 4 31 56 – 83 – – – 17 48 – – – 52 59 – – – 41 Number of families (1,000s) 679 1,207 1,344 1,977 255 316 615 559 6,952 Notes: The category ‘pre-school children’ includes families with at least one pre-school child. The symbol ‘–’ denotes a cell that is not applicable to the family group. The numbers of families have been grossed to the national level. Source: Family Resources Survey (1998–99, 1999–2000 and 2000–01) To be eligible for the childcare credit in the current working families’ tax credit (and also for the childcare credit to be introduced in April 2003), both parents in a couple and single parents must be in employment for at least 16 hours each week (with certain exceptions for incapacitated parents). Table 7.2 presents the current use of childcare for families fulfilling this requirement. When asked whether ‘anyone else normally looks after the children because you or your partner are working’, 44% of working families (defined as those where all parents are in employment at least 16 hours each week) respond that 6 A full description of the survey and extensive analysis of the childcare information can be found in G. Paull and J. Taylor with A. Duncan, Mothers’ Employment and Childcare Use in Britain, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2002. 87 Green Budget, January 2003 they use childcare and only 23% report that they pay for the care. Given that almost three-quarters (73%) of the families with no parent working less than 16 hours each week contain only school-age children, this is not surprising as parents may be able to fit work around school hours or the children may be old enough to look after themselves. Indeed, Table 7.2 shows that the majority of working families with pre-school children do use childcare, while around half pay for it. Table 7.2. Childcare use for families with no parent working less than 16 hours each week Any type of non-parental care: % using care % paying for care Average weekly cost Formal care: % using care % paying for care Average weekly cost Informal care: % using care % paying for care Average weekly cost Couples Pre-school Only school children children 1 2+ 1 2+ Single parents Pre-school Only school children children 1 2+ 1 2+ All 77 50 £76 72 49 £90 23 10 £33 34 15 £42 85 51 £63 90 51 £68 38 16 £33 47 20 £37 44 23 £62 42 41 £80 40 39 £97 7 7 £35 10 10 £46 43 40 £68 39 37 £71 11 10 £35 12 11 £44 18 17 £69 47 19 £52 45 19 £49 18 5 £28 26 8 £33 56 24 £46 68 25 £48 31 9 £28 39 12 £25 31 11 £38 Number of families (1,000s) 361 419 830 1,112 70 54 320 229 3,394 Notes: The category ‘pre-school children’ includes families with at least one pre-school child. The average weekly cost is the total cost for all children and is averaged over those paying for care. All monetary values are in approximate April 2003 prices. Formal care includes nurseries, crèches, school clubs, childminders, nannies and au pairs. Informal care is that provided by relatives and friends. The numbers of families have been grossed to the national level. Source: Family Resources Survey (1998–99, 1999–2000 and 2000–01). Childcare can be divided into two types: formal care, provided in a market setting by nurseries, crèches, school clubs, childminders, nannies and au pairs; and informal care, provided by relatives and friends. Childcare subsidies have typically covered only the costs of formal care. Even so, only 18% of the working families report using formal care, while 31% have used informal care (the use of each type is not mutually exclusive, so the proportions sum to slightly more than the total for ‘any type of childcare’). Almost all formal care, but only about one-third of informal care, is paid for. The average weekly cost (for those who pay) is higher for formal than for informal care. Hence, families using formal childcare tend to spend more than users of informal care, both because they are more likely to pay for it and because, if they do pay, they pay more. Working single parents use informal care more than working couples with children. Families with only school children are also more likely to rely on informal sources of care than families with at least one pre-school child. Families with more than one child tend to pay less per child for care than those with a lone child. 88 Childcare subsidies These patterns in childcare use and the differences across different types of families will have important implications for the effects of various kinds of childcare subsidies. In particular, the substantial proportions of working families not using care or using only informal care suggest that there might be room for considerable expansion in the use of childcare by these families. 7.3 Options for subsidising childcare This section reviews the current system of support for the childcare costs of working families and how this will change from April 2003. It then describes some modifications to the childcare credit that would increase the generosity of the childcare subsidy. Current programmes: the working families’ tax credit The current childcare subsidy available in the working families’ tax credit has the following features: • The subsidy is 70% of actual childcare expenditure, subject to a fixed upper limit (a maximum credit of £94.50 for £135 of expenditure each week for families with one child and £140 for an expenditure of £200 for families with more than one child). • Only approved formal care is covered – namely: registered childminders, play schemes or out-of-school clubs, other childcare schemes that do not need to be registered and providers of care that are approved by specifically accredited organisations. • To receive the care subsidy, all parents in the family are required to be in paid employment at least 16 hours each week (with some exceptions for incapacitated parents). • The subsidy is subject to a means test based on family net earnings. Working tax and childcare credits to be introduced in April 2003 The working tax credit and child tax credit, which replace the WFTC and children’s tax credit in April 2003, will basically replicate the current system for families with children.7 There will be some adjustments: • The means test will be based on gross family income rather than net earnings. • Some of the rates will be slightly adjusted. • The 30-hour premium in the WTC will be given to families where the combined work hours of all parents are at least 30 each week (rather than one parent being required to work at least 30 hours each week as in the WFTC). 7 See Chapter 4 for further details on the new tax credits. 89 Green Budget, January 2003 • The credits will be divided into a working tax credit (paid through the employer), a childcare credit and a child tax credit (both paid directly to the ‘prime carer’). • The childcare credit will benefit some families further up the income distribution. In considering alternative ways to subsidise childcare, the baseline WTC scheme is subjected to several variations in three main dimensions. Changing the amount of childcare expenditure covered by the subsidy Under the WTC, 70% of expenditure on formal types of childcare will be refunded by the credit, up to ceilings of £94.50 (for £135 of expenditure) each week for families with one child and £140 (for £200 of expenditure) for families with more than one child. We consider two options that would allow the amount of expenditure covered to be expanded: 1) Doubling the ceilings for the childcare credit to £189 for families with one child and £280 for families with more than one child 2) Raising the eligible proportion of childcare costs to 100 percent Options that extend the type of care covered by the credit are also considered. Expanding coverage to informal care has been the subject of much discussion. The Interdepartmental Childcare Review of November 2002 recognised the importance of informal care for working families but expressed concern that more evidence was required on ‘the outcomes of informal care for the child and for parents using it; the extent to which the cost of informal care is a barrier to parental employment; and whether paying informal carers would lead to an overall growth in available childcare’8 before it could be decided whether the government should intervene in the informal market. It might also be desirable to know the potential cost. So the third option considered is: 3) Including informal care, such as that provided by friends and relatives, as eligible for the credit One difficulty with allowing the credit to cover informal care is the question of how the price of care might be set. In particular, the 30% of the cost not covered by the subsidy may not be a constraint on the price paid by the parent if the money is going to a friend or relative. One way to address this would be to set a maximum hourly rate. This would be equivalent to issuing vouchers that could be cashed by the carer for each hour provided. Two variants of a fourth option are therefore considered: 4a) A voucher scheme of £1.80 per child for each hour of care (formal or informal), with a maximum number of eligible care hours equal to the prime carer’s work hours (the prime carer in a couple being the parent working the shortest hours, which is typically the mother) 8 Page 25 of Department for Education and Skills, Department for Work and Pensions, HM Treasury and Women & Equality Unit, Delivering for Children and Families, London, 2002 (www.strategy.gov.uk/2002/childcare/report/downloads/su-children.pdf). 90 Childcare subsidies 4b) As for (4a) with a voucher value of £2.67 per child per hour The figure of £1.80 is the average hourly amount spent on paid informal sources of care, while £2.67 is the average hourly amount spent on care for children in formal childcare. The voucher value could, in practice, be any desired level of subsidy. It should be noted that the maximum value of the subsidy under the voucher scheme depends not only on the number of children in the family, but also on the work hours of the prime carer. Changing the work requirements Eligibility for the WTC requires that one parent be working at least 16 hours each week, while eligibility for the childcare credit requires that no parent be working less than 16 hours each week. It has been argued that it might be desirable to offer the WTC and childcare credit to parents working less than 16 hours each week in order to encourage them to have at least some involvement in formal employment, be it at very low hours. Hence, the fifth option is: 5) Weakening the work requirement for the childcare credit from 16 hours each week to any hours of employment Such a modification could affect a considerable proportion of families. Some 12% of couples with children have one partner working at least 16 hours each week and the other in formal employment at less than 16 hours each week, while 6% of single parents are in paid employment but working less than 16 hours each week. Changing the means-testing Entitlement to WTC and the childcare credit will be means-tested on gross family income. But limiting support for childcare costs only to mothers in low-income families may not be desirable if the objective is to encourage all mothers to work for reasons of economic efficiency or gender equity. Three options are considered for extending eligibility for the childcare credit to mothers in higher-income households: 6) Doubling the income threshold for means-testing the childcare credit from £94.50 to £189 each week 7) Means-testing on the prime carer’s gross earnings for the childcare credit, where the prime carer in a couple is the parent working the shortest hours (typically the mother)9 8) Removing all means-testing for the childcare credit 9 In the estimation below, option 7 is implemented by removing the couple element from the maximum credit entitlement so that the prime carer is effectively treated as a single person. In addition, the 30-hour addition to the credit is only included if the prime carer is working at least 30 hours each week. 91 Green Budget, January 2003 7.4 Potential numbers of eligible families and budget costs, holding childcare and employment constant The impacts on the number of families eligible to benefit from the childcare credit and the potential budget cost for each option described above are presented in this section. It is assumed that employment and childcare behaviour do not alter from current choices. The possible impacts of responses in childcare and employment choices are discussed in the following sections. The estimated numbers of eligible families and annual budget costs for the baseline case of WTC and the options for modifications to the childcare credit are presented in Table 7.3. It should be noted that the estimated numbers of ‘eligible families’ include not only those directly entitled to receive the childcare credit, but all families that benefit indirectly because their WFTC/WTC or child tax credit payment is higher on account of the fact that they pay for childcare. The annual budget cost is the additional cost of the WFTC/WTC and child tax credit programmes arising from the childcare credit. It should also be recognised that the results are presented in terms of the number of families eligible to benefit rather than the actual number who receive any benefit. In reality, the number actually receiving any subsidy may be considerably smaller, as take-up of the WFTC is far from complete. Recent estimates suggest that take-up rates are in the range of 62–65% among those eligible, with considerably lower rates for couples with children (49–53%) than for lone parents (77–83%).10 The estimated annual budget costs are based on 100% take-up and will be smaller if not all eligible families claim the credit to which they are entitled. Just over 1.5 million families are estimated to be eligible for WFTC, with 115,000 benefiting from the childcare credit.11 Only a small proportion of those eligible for WFTC are also eligible to benefit from the childcare credit both because many couples have one parent (typically the mother) working less than 16 hours and because many recipient families do not have any 10 Table 1 on page 4 of Inland Revenue, Working Families’ Tax Credit: Estimates of Take-Up Rates in 2000–01, 2002. The take-up of the childcare tax credit has not been estimated. 11 The official statistics for the WFTC caseload as of August 2002 are 1,307,000 recipients of WFTC and 170,200 recipients benefiting from the childcare tax credit (tables 1.1 and 1.3 of Inland Revenue, Working Families’ Tax Credit Statistics: Quarterly Enquiry: United Kingdom: August 2002, January 2003). The number of eligible families reported here may be higher than the official number of recipients due to incomplete take-up, while the estimated numbers eligible for the childcare credit may be lower than the official figure because of under-reporting of childcare use in the Family Resources Survey data. Additional sources of these discrepancies could be the differences in the time period considered or the sampling and weighting procedures used in this analysis. 92 Childcare subsidies eligible childcare costs. The average benefit from the childcare credit for families receiving it is £30 each week,12 at an annual cost of £179 million. Under WTC, 124,000 families will be eligible for the childcare credit, a modest rise due to the adjustments listed above in the replacement of WFTC with the WTC and child tax credit. The value of the average weekly care subsidy for each family in receipt is estimated not to change from what it is under WFTC, but the total budget cost of the care subsidy is estimated to rise to £195 million. Table 7.3. Number of eligible families and costs of the childcare credit: childcare unchanged Baselines: WFTC WTC Options affecting eligible childcare expenditure: (1) Double ceilings for eligible childcare expenditure (2) Raise eligible proportion of childcare costs to 100% (3) Include informal childcare as eligible for childcare credit Voucher scheme for all types of care: (4a) £1.80 per child per hour of care (4b) £2.67 per child per hour of care Number of families eligible to benefit (1,000s) Average weekly benefit per family Annual budget cost 115 124 £30 £30 £179m £195m 125 £32 £205m 146 £42 £317m 188 £27 £263m 198 210 £30 £35 £305m £382m Option affecting work requirements: (5) Reduce work requirement to any hours 135 £30 £208m Options affecting means-testing for childcare credit: (6) Double income thresholds 169 £31 £270m (7) Means test on prime carer’s earnings 425 £33 £739m (8) Remove means-testing 584 £45 £1,370m Notes: Families are eligible to benefit from the childcare credit if the WFTC/WTC or child tax credit payment is higher on account of the fact that they pay for childcare. The average weekly benefit is averaged over those entitled to benefit from childcare credit. The annual budget cost is the additional cost of the WFTC/WTC and child tax credit programmes on account of the childcare credit. All monetary values are in approximate April 2003 prices. The numbers of families have been grossed to the national level. Source: Author’s calculations using the Family Resources Survey (1998–99, 1999–2000 and 2000–01) and the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN. 12 Official statistics indicate that families benefiting from the childcare tax credit receive an additional £41 on average (table 8.1 of Inland Revenue, Working Families’ Tax Credit Statistics: Quarterly Enquiry: United Kingdom: August 2002, January 2003). The lower amount reported here may be due to incomplete take-up if families with a smaller childcare credit claim are less likely to claim it. 93 Green Budget, January 2003 Options 1–4 show the impacts of modifying the amount of childcare expenditure that is eligible for the childcare credit. Doubling the ceilings on the amount of eligible childcare expenditure has little impact on the number of eligible families and only a slightly larger impact on the annual cost. This is because the vast majority of families spend less than the ceilings, although the few who spend more could push the annual budget cost up by £10 million if the ceilings were doubled. The second option – of raising the eligible proportion of childcare costs from 70% to 100% – has a much greater impact on the budget cost. It increases the number of eligible families to 146,000, as some new families now pass the means test for the care credit, and raises the estimated annual cost to £317 million, as all families currently eligible benefit from a 43% rise in the childcare credit.13 The average childcare credit rises from £30 per week for each family to £42 per week. Making spending on informal care eligible for the credit (option 3) increases the number of eligible families considerably, to 188,000, but has a more modest impact on the annual budget cost, raising the annual tally to £263 million. Those using informal care spend less, on average, than those using formal sources, and the average childcare credit for each family declines from £30 each week to £27. The most generous voucher scheme, considered in option 4b, is the most expansionary of this group of options, raising the number of families eligible for the childcare credit to 210,000 and the annual cost to £382 million. This is a mixture of options 2 and 3. It is similar to option 2 because the hourly price of £2.67 is, by construction, greater than 70% of the average informal costs and allows a greater proportion of the costs to be covered. It is also similar to option 3 in that the voucher can be used for both formal and informal care. It is not surprising, therefore, that this voucher scheme raises the number of eligible families by an amount slightly greater than option 3 and increases the annual cost by an amount somewhat greater than option 2. The lower annual budget cost (£305 million) and slightly lower number of eligible families (198,000) under the less generous voucher scheme (option 4a) highlight how limiting the voucher value can reduce the budget cost. Reducing the work requirement from 16 hours each week to any hours (option 5) has moderate impacts. This may reflect the fact that families with a parent in paid employment but working less than 16 hours each week are not likely to be using childcare or spending large amounts on it. The final three options in Table 7.3 (options 6–8) consider the effects of modifying the means-testing for the childcare credit. Simply doubling the thresholds for the means-testing has a moderate impact, increasing the number of eligible families to 169,000 and raising the estimated annual cost to £270 million. On the other hand, moving to means-testing on the basis of the prime carer’s earnings has substantial effects, raising the number of families eligible for the childcare credit over three times to 425,000 and increasing the annual budget cost by almost a factor of four, to £739 million. This is not surprising, given that mothers in couples with both partners working at least 16 hours each week are often considerably ‘poorer’ than their partners: on average, such 13 The rise is 30/70 (43%) corresponding to the movement from 70% to 100% of expenditure. 94 Childcare subsidies mothers contribute only 38% to total family earnings, partly because 43% work less than 30 hours each week. They are therefore likely to be eligible for the credit as individuals if not as couples. The rise in annual cost is proportionally greater than the rise in the number of eligible families because families further up the income distribution tend to spend more on formal childcare.14 Removing all means-testing for the childcare credit (option 8) would increase the number of eligible families even further (to 584,000) and would have a very large effect on the estimated annual cost. Indeed, the annual cost would increase more than seven times from the baseline WTC case, to well over £1 billion. Not only would the removal of all means-testing increase the size of the eligible group, but the average value of the childcare credit would rise considerably from the baseline of £30 per week per family to £45. Overall, assuming no response in employment or childcare choices, the options that alter the amount of eligible childcare expenditure, including extending coverage to informal care, have moderate effects on the potential number of families that benefit and on budget costs. Altering the meanstesting has more substantial effects, particularly any movement towards means-testing on an individual rather than family basis. However, the next section shows that if families respond to changes in policy by expanding their childcare use, these conclusions need to be modified. 7.5 Allowing childcare responses (holding employment constant) Will childcare use and expenditure expand? Modifying the childcare credit would create incentives for parents to alter childcare choices even in the absence of any change in employment. In particular, options that effectively reduce the price of childcare may lead to an expansion in childcare use and expenditure. Parents may see greater use of childcare as a way to work longer hours, to have more time free of their children or to give their children the benefit of different types of care. However, there are two important reasons why childcare use might not expand in response to an increase in the generosity of the childcare credit: • Parents may feel that more time in paid-for childcare would be bad for their children, even if it were effectively costless. • Sufficient formal childcare places or informal sources of childcare may simply not be available to meet all the extra demand. Yet even if the numbers of hours of childcare do not change, the amount spent on care might rise: 14 Section 6.6.3 of G. Paull and J. Taylor with A. Duncan, Mothers’ Employment and Childcare Use in Britain, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2002. 95 Green Budget, January 2003 • Parents may spend more money on childcare by choosing care options of higher quality at a higher price.15 • If the supply of formal childcare places is slow to respond to any increases in demand, providers may raise their prices. The incidence of the care subsidy is then said to fall in part on the providers because they gain part of the benefit rather than the direct recipients.16 In the longer term and in the absence of any barriers to new entry, new suppliers should enter the market and bid down the price and parents should then receive the full benefit of the subsidy. • The non-market nature of the provision of informal care generates large incentives to expand the cost of this type of care without altering the hours of care. In the informal arrangement, the amount of monetary transfers between the parent and carer may be of no relevance, either because the transfers can be returned in some other way (monetary or non-financial) or because the parent and carer care sufficiently about each other that they effectively operate as one household. Indeed, the provision of a large proportion of informal care at no cost is evidence that financial payment for care is not relevant for many parents and informal carers.17 Any childcare subsidy for this type of care creates an incentive for both parent and carer to report the greatest possible cost of the care (either through a high hourly cost or through long hours) in order to maximise the amount of the childcare credit that can be shared between them. For these reasons, it is likely that any increase in the generosity of the childcare credit would generate an expansion in the expenditure on childcare. Whether there would also be an increase in the use and hours of care would depend upon how much the demand for care and the supply of formal childcare places and informal sources of care react to changes in the effective price. Scenarios for childcare expansion How childcare use might respond to the modifications in the childcare credit is not estimated here. Instead, the impacts of several scenarios for different childcare reactions are explored. Many of these scenarios consider the upper limits on the responses in childcare use and thereby provide approximate upper bounds to the potential changes in the numbers eligible and budget costs. These scenarios for childcare expansions are applied to the four options that would have the greatest potential impact on the use and cost of care: options 2–4b. Option 2 reduces the effective price of formal care from 30% of the cost to zero. Option 3 includes informal care as eligible for the subsidy and 15 G. Paull and J. Taylor with A. Duncan, Mothers’ Employment and Childcare Use in Britain, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2002, find in chapter 7 that quality responses to variation in the price of childcare may indeed be greater than quantity reactions. 16 A discussion of incidence is contained in Chapter 9. 17 An alternative explanation is that the carer actually enjoys caring for the child and does not require financial compensation for doing so. 96 Childcare subsidies generates the incentives described above to expand the cost and use of such care. Options 4a and 4b contain incentives for both formal and informal care to expand by reducing the effective price to zero for costs at or below £1.80 and £2.67 per hour for both types of care respectively. It is initially assumed that families do not alter the type of care that they use, but only increase the hourly cost or hours of care. This means that any expansion is initially limited to those currently using formal care for option 2 and currently using formal or informal care for options 3, 4a and 4b. However, it is obviously unrealistic to assume that parents would not alter the type of care that they use in response to greater subsidies. It is particularly likely that parents who do not currently use care may begin to do so. Therefore, three progressively more expansionary scenarios are applied, first, only to current users of childcare and, second, to all families fulfilling the work requirements for the childcare credit: a) The hourly cost rises to £2.67 (the current average for formal care) b) The hourly cost rises to £2.67 and the hours of care per child rise to equal the prime carer’s work hours c) Total care expenditure rises to equal the ceiling on eligible expenditure through any combination of increasing hourly price or weekly hours As the expansion in scenario a is dependent upon some current usage of care, it has identical impacts whether applied only to current users or to all working families. Scenarios b and c are identical for the voucher schemes, as scenario b implies the same maximum benefit as scenario c in these cases. Scenario c, when applied to all families fulfilling the work requirement to be eligible for the childcare credit, generates an upper limit on the costs of the childcare credit assuming that no new families become eligible for the childcare credit through changes in employment or family income. It should be stressed again that these are upper limits and actual childcare use and expenditure are very unlikely to approach these levels. Potential eligibility and budget costs with an expansion in childcare The impacts on the number of eligible families and the annual budget cost from each of these options and childcare expansion scenarios are presented in Table 7.4. These estimates continue to assume that families do not alter their employment choices in response to modifications in the childcare credit. It should be noted, not least as a hint towards the conclusions, that the annual budget costs are now presented in billions of pounds in contrast to the millions of pounds in Table 7.3. Option 2 increases the proportion of formal care costs that are covered by the childcare credit from 70% to 100%. If those using formal care react to this by expanding their hourly cost to £2.67, there would only be a moderate impact on the number of eligible families and annual cost (scenario a). This is because average hourly care costs are already quite high for this group. If, in addition, current formal care users expand care hours to match the prime carer’s work hours (scenario b), there would be a further moderate impact on the numbers 97 Green Budget, January 2003 eligible but a dramatic rise in the estimated annual budget cost, to £1.2 billion. Allowing expansion by formal care users to reach the ceilings for eligible care costs in the credit (scenario c) increases the number of eligible families to over 300,000 and would raise the estimated budget cost by over five times, to £1.8 billion. Table 7.4. Number of eligible families and costs of the childcare credit: with potential childcare responses Number of families eligible to benefit (1,000s) Expansion scenario: (a) (b) (c) Annual budget cost Expansion scenario: (a) (b) (c) (2) Raise eligible proportion of No expansion: 146 No expansion: £0.3bn childcare costs to 100% formal users expand care 185 270 319 £0.5bn £1.2bn £1.8bn all working families use care 185 1,849 2,163 £0.5bn £8.9bn £13.6bn (3) Include informal childcare as No expansion: 188 No expansion: £0.3bn eligible for childcare credit all current users expand care 607 742 871 £1.7bn £2.6bn £3.9bn all working families use care 607 1,567 1,840 £1.7bn £5.4bn £8.2bn (4a) Voucher scheme of £1.80 No expansion: 198 No expansion: £0.3bn per child per hour of care all current users expand care 526 746 746 £1.1bn £2.9bn £2.9bn all working families use care 526 1,579 1,579 £1.1bn £5.9bn £5.9bn (4b) Voucher scheme of £2.67 No expansion: 210 No expansion: £0.4bn per child per hour of care all current users expand care 609 898 898 £1.8bn £5.0bn £5.0bn all working families use care 609 1,887 1,887 £1.8bn £10.3bn £10.3bn Notes: Families are eligible to benefit from the childcare credit if the WFTC/WTC or child tax credit payment is higher on account of the fact that they pay for childcare. The annual budget cost is the additional cost of the WFTC/WTC and child tax credit programmes on account of the childcare credit. All monetary values are in approximate April 2003 prices. The numbers of families have been grossed to the national level. Expansion scenario a expands the hourly cost to £2.67; scenario b expands the hourly cost to £2.67 and care hours to equal the prime carer’s hours; and scenario c expands care expenditure to the ceiling on eligible expenditure. Source: Author’s calculations using the Family Resources Survey (1998–99, 1999–2000 and 2000–01) and the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN. Any modification to the childcare credit that enticed those not currently using care to begin to do so could have very large effects: more than half (56%) of families fulfilling the work requirement report that they do not currently use any childcare and 82% do not use any formal care. It is not surprising that the scenarios where new working families may begin to use paid childcare in response to the subsidy generate much larger impacts, raising the estimated number of families eligible to benefit to around 2 million in the case of option 2. The annual budget costs are estimated to increase dramatically, to almost £9 billion if hourly cost rises to £2.67 and hours of care rise to equal the prime carer’s work hours (scenario b) and to over £13 billion if expenditure by all rises to the maximum amount covered by the childcare credit (scenario c). Returning to the cases where the care expansion is limited to current users, the impacts are more dramatic if eligible care costs are extended to informal care (option 3). Because initial hourly costs are so low (and a substantial proportion free) for informal care, even increasing the hourly cost (scenario a) would 98 Childcare subsidies increase the number of eligible families from 188,000 to 607,000 and the estimated annual cost from under £0.3 billion to £1.7 billion. Because the hours used also tend to be low, expanding the hours to match the prime carer’s work hours (scenario b) would have a further substantial impact, particularly on the annual budget cost, which is estimated to rise to well over £2½ billion. Allowing expenditure to reach the ceilings for current users (scenario c) would increase the number of eligible families to 871,000 and raise budget costs to approach £4 billion. Assuming all working families use childcare creates moderately lower numbers of eligible families and annual budget costs under option 3 than option 2, because option 3 provides a maximum credit that is only 70% of that in option 2. The increase in potential costs by assuming that new families use paid childcare over expansion only by current users is of a much smaller magnitude when eligible childcare costs are limited in this way. The less generous voucher scheme (option 4a) has very similar effects to the WTC extended to include informal care (option 3) when expansions are limited to an hourly cost of £2.67 and hours equal to the prime carer’s work hours (scenario b). Yet the advantage of the voucher scheme is that there would be no further impact on the annual budget cost if childcare expanded beyond this point, because childcare expenditure under this scenario has already exceeded the maximum eligible amounts for the voucher scheme. If current users expanded their use further to the ceiling on eligible expenditure (scenario c), the weekly ceilings from the current system used in option 3 mean that option 3 is estimated to cost £1 billion more than the voucher scheme (option 4a) (£3.9 billion compared with £2.9 billion). If all working families used care to the ceiling on eligible expenditure, option 3 is estimated to cost over £2 billion more than the voucher scheme (£8.2 billion compared with £5.9 billion). However, the more generous voucher scheme (option 4b) has implicit ceilings on expenditure that are, on average, far higher than those in the current system. Consequently, the annual budget costs are considerably greater for this voucher scheme than for option 3 under both expansion scenarios b and c. This emphasises the point that if childcare subsidies contain incentives for substantial expansions in childcare use, the ceilings on the subsidy may play an important role in determining the budget cost. Indeed, given the extremely large magnitude of the estimated costs, political acceptability for consideration of some of these options is likely to require more stringent ceilings on eligible care expenditure to ensure that potential costs would be contained to reasonable levels. Yet it should also be stressed that these estimated impacts of childcare responses are upper bounds on potential claimant numbers and costs. In the short term, lack of availability is likely to constrain the effects to much more limited rises, while less than complete take-up of the credit and consideration of the desirability of greater use of childcare for the children may mean that the costs do not reach these levels even in the longer run. The estimates in Tables 7.3 and 7.4 are also premised on the assumption that families do not alter their employment behaviour. Relaxation of this assumption is discussed in the following section. 99 Green Budget, January 2003 7.6 Considering employment responses With the exception of option 5,18 the modifications to the childcare credit affect employment choices indirectly by reducing the effective cost of childcare for working families. If childcare is required to facilitate employment, a reduction in the effective hourly price of care is analogous to an increase in the hourly wage rate for the prime carer. It therefore has the same two opposing effects on labour supply: • A substitution effect: if the effective hourly price of childcare falls, the financial return to each hour of work rises and parents may choose to work more. • An income effect: a fall in the cost of childcare makes any current use of care less expensive, raising the effective income of parents, which may lead them to feel that they can afford to reduce their hours of work. Which of these effects is likely to dominate the overall labour supply response cannot be predicted without additional empirical estimation. Nevertheless, several points can be noted: • The childcare credit only applies to parents working more than 16 hours each week. Any increase in its generosity cannot entice parents to leave employment or reduce hours below 16 each week through the income effect because parents would then not benefit from the subsidy. Hence, an increase in generosity in the childcare credit can potentially raise, but not reduce, the proportion of parents who are working 16 or more hours each week. Families enticed to enter employment must do so at hours and earnings levels that make them eligible for the childcare credit. • The positive substitution effect on work hours can only operate if additional childcare is both required and available to facilitate an expansion in work hours. For example, parents of older school children may not need additional childcare to work longer and therefore would not react to a change in the effective childcare price. • The positive substitution effect on work hours will not operate for families already receiving the maximum level of care subsidy. However, if the maximum value of the subsidy is directly linked to the work hours of the prime carer (as in the voucher schemes described above), there will be a positive substitution incentive for all families. • Given the relative lack of responsiveness in men’s working hours to changes in the wage rate,19 any employment response is more likely to be 18 Option 5 reduces the work requirements for the WTC and childcare credit from 16 hours each week to any hours of employment. This encourages parents either to reduce their work hours to below 16 each week or to enter employment in order to work the shorter hours. Hence, this modification has incentives both to reduce weekly hours for those already working and to increase the proportion of parents in employment. 19 For example, see R. Blundell and T. MaCurdy, ‘Labor supply: a review of alternative approaches’, chapter 27 of Handbook of Labor Economics, Elsevier Science, 1999. 100 Childcare subsidies seen in changes in the work choices of the mother than in alterations in the father’s hours of work. • Any reduction in hours of employment due to the income effect could lead to a decline in the number of childcare hours. If employment does increase (or fall), it is likely, although not automatic, that childcare use would also move in the same direction in line with the change in working hours. In terms of the maximum potential budget costs (where all working families purchase care to the credit ceilings) presented in Table 7.4, employment responses may raise these costs to the degree that families enter employment or increase their weekly working hours to 16 or more. Given that approximately half of all families do not currently fulfil the work requirements for the childcare credit, the impacts could be large if a substantial proportion of these families increased their labour supply in response to a more generous childcare credit. But past empirical evidence suggests that labour supply responses are likely to be much more modest. For example, simulations of the impact of the introduction of the WFTC estimated that the employment participation rate for single mothers would rise by only 2 to 3 percentage points.20 Yet even if subsidy costs did increase substantially as a result of increased work hours or employment participation, this would be directly paying for achieving the objective of improving the labour market involvement of parents. 7.7 Impacts across families As highlighted in the initial discussion of the employment choices of families and the use of childcare by working families (Section 7.2), expansions in the childcare subsidy could have diverse impacts for different types of families. In this section, the main distributional consequences of the childcare subsidy modifications are briefly summarised.21 The childcare credit in the WTC will benefit different types of families to varying degrees: • Single parents are much more likely to be eligible to benefit from the childcare credit than couples with children: single parents are estimated to constitute some 67% of the families who are eligible for the childcare credit. • Families with a pre-school child are more likely to be eligible to benefit from the childcare credit than those with only school children: over half of the eligible families are estimated to have at least one pre-school child. • Families with more than one child are slightly less likely to be eligible to benefit than those with a single child. 20 R. Blundell, A. Duncan, J. McCrae and C. Meghir, ‘The labour market impact of the working families’ tax credit’, Fiscal Studies, 2000, vol. 21, pp. 75–103, and A. Duncan, G. Paull and J. Taylor, ‘Mother’s employment and the use of childcare in the UK’, Institute for Fiscal Studies, Working Paper no. 01/23, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/workingpapers/wp0123.pdf). 21 The tables and figures for this summary are available on request from the author. 101 Green Budget, January 2003 • Most families who are eligible to benefit from the childcare credit have income levels in the middle of the income distribution.22 The options for expansion would distribute benefits unevenly across family types. In terms of the percentage change in each type who would become eligible to benefit from the childcare credit: • Expanding the proportion of formal care that is covered by the subsidy (option 2) would generate moderately greater benefits for couples over single parents, for those with pre-school children and for those above median incomes. • Expanding the credit to include informal care (options 3, 4a and 4b) would generate greater benefits for couples, families with only school children and families with more than one child if the use of care expands. • Expanding the credit to include informal care (options 3, 4a and 4b) would exaggerate the greater benefits drawn by those in the middle of the income distribution, particularly if the use of care expands. • Those at the very bottom of the distribution would be most likely to benefit if working families not currently using care began to do so if the credit were expanded to include informal care (options 3, 4a and 4b). • Those in the top of the income distribution would benefit the most if working families not currently using care began to do so if either (i) the proportion of formal care covered by the subsidy were expanded to 100% (option 2) or (ii) the more generous voucher scheme were introduced (option 4b). • Modifications to the means-testing (options 6 to 8) would generate greater benefits for couples. • Means-testing on the prime carer’s earnings (option 7) would have the greatest benefits for those around the eighth decile in the income distribution, but complete removal of means-testing (option 8) would generate substantial benefits to those at the very top of the income distribution. 7.8 Conclusions Government support for childcare costs for working families has increased considerably over the past decade, and recent initiatives continue to move gradually in the direction of more generous subsidies. Yet the more radical possibilities for changes in the scope of support, such as covering informal care or increasing support further up the income distribution, remain on the fringes of policy consideration. Concern for a sudden explosion in the budget cost of the more sweeping reforms may be one reason for hesitation. In 22 This is due, in part, to the fact that eligibility for the childcare credit requires all parents to be in employment for a minimum of 16 hours each week, generating a reasonably high level of family earnings. It is also due to the fact that the likelihood of using formal childcare is greater for families with higher incomes. 102 Childcare subsidies particular, some proposals contain incentives for an unknown and potentially large reaction in the childcare choices of parents that could prove very expensive to subsidise. This chapter has considered the potential costs of several options for increasing the generosity of the childcare credit. It has included an analysis of some of the most expensive scenarios for an expansion in childcare use and expenditure. It is likely that the corresponding cost estimates overstate the likely outcomes because: • it is very unlikely that any reforms to the childcare credit would invoke such extreme changes in behaviour, especially in light of reports of a shortage of childcare places; • the cost estimates assume complete take-up of the credit, while actual takeup rates are currently much lower. Yet consideration of such upper bounds has shown that whether the potential costs fall within the realms of an affordable policy depends to a large degree on how parents react in their childcare choices: • Expanding the coverage of the childcare credit to a greater proportion of formal care costs or to include informal care does not have a substantial impact on budget costs if childcare choices remain unchanged. • But if childcare choices responded to extreme levels, the budget costs of the childcare credit could escalate enormously to well beyond what is likely to be deemed affordable. • Modifications to the means-testing for the childcare credit are less likely to alter childcare behaviour substantially and are likely to impose large, but perhaps feasible, increases in budget cost. In addition, the desired objectives of enhancing childcare use and employment rates among parents may not accompany a rise in budget costs: • There are good reasons to believe that expenditure on both formal and informal care could rise in response to increases in the childcare credit’s generosity without any substantial change in childcare use or hours. • The employment incentives of increasing the level of the care subsidy are mixed: some parents could be encouraged to enter employment or extend their hours, while others might react by reducing hours. Therefore, consideration of any expansion in the childcare credit may require modifications in the current design in order to ensure that the costs cannot spiral beyond acceptable levels and to enhance the effectiveness of the subsidy in achieving childcare and employment objectives. Such modifications could include: • lowering the current weekly ceilings on childcare expenditure; • relating the value of the credit to childcare hours (as in an hourly voucher) to ensure that the more substantial potential rises in costs are matched by increases in the use and hours of care; 103 Green Budget, January 2003 • relating the maximum number of eligible care hours to the prime carer’s hours of employment in order both to target resources to those with greatest need in terms of facilitating employment and to improve the incentives to work longer hours; • relating eligibility for the credit to the employment and earnings of the prime carer (typically the mother) in order to maximise the positive employment incentives for the parent most likely to be responsive. As it currently stands, the childcare credit does not cost much simply because it does not help many families. Providing greater support for childcare costs for working parents to such an extent that it might encourage more parents into paid employment would inevitably increase the size of the financial burden of the subsidy. If such an objective is desired, a careful redesign of the childcare credit and consideration of the reactions in childcare use and expenditure may be required to ensure that the costs are contained to an affordable level that would make greater support politically feasible. Gillian Paull 104 8. Measuring public sector efficiency The government has staked its political credibility on delivering significant and noticeable improvements to public services. Over the period from April 1999 to March 2006, the resources allocated to public services are set to increase substantially: NHS spending is forecast to increase by 7.3% per year in real terms, spending on transport by 6.3% and spending on education by 5.9%.1 The extent to which these increased resources are translated into improved outcomes for users will depend on the efficiency, or productivity, of public service providers. In addition, the extent to which public sector productivity improvements materialise will have implications for the government’s aim of increasing the rate of productivity growth of the UK economy. The 2002 Spending Review set out around 130 Public Service Agreement (PSA) performance targets covering areas such as health, education and crime. The PSA targets cover both outcomes, such as NHS waiting times, and the efficiency with which those outcomes are delivered. For example, Department of Health objective 12 states that ‘value for money in the NHS and personal social services will improve by at least 2% per annum, with annual improvements of 1% in both cost efficiency and service effectiveness’ and Home Office objective 10 aims to ‘ensure annual efficiency gains by the police of at least 2%’.2 These targets raise issues about how the efficiency of individual service providers is measured, and also about whether the set of efficiency measures produced can be used to give service providers incentives for improved performance. Reliable measures of both outcomes and provider efficiency are particularly important if they are to be used to target resources to more efficient providers, to act as a motivational tool or to detect failing providers. In April 2000, HM Treasury’s Public Services Productivity Panel published a report detailing a new approach to measuring the efficiency of the police.3 The wider aim was to use the efficiency measures as part of an incentive system to 1 HM Treasury, 2002 Spending Review, Cm. 5570, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Spending_Review/spend_sr02/spend_sr02_index.cfm?); HM Treasury, Public Expenditure Statistical Analyses 2002–03, Cm. 5401, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/pesa_2002to2003.pdf); authors’ calculations. For comparable historical figures, see table 3.4 in A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/gbfiles/gb2002.shtml). 2 ‘Public Spending and Services: Links to Departmental Performance Documents’, www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/Documents/Public_Spending_and_Services/publicservice_performance/pss_p erf_table.cfm. 3 C. Spottiswoode, Improving Police Performance: A New Approach to Measuring Police Efficiency, HM Treasury Public Services Productivity Panel, London, 2000 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/231.pdf). 105 Green Budget, January 2003 improve police performance. Police authorities were to be placed in efficiency bands, which would be used to determine future performance targets and inspection and review arrangements. It was also suggested that the proposed efficiency measurement techniques – namely, ‘stochastic frontier analysis’ and ‘data envelopment analysis’ – might have wider applicability within the public sector.4 The Office of the Deputy Prime Minister has also commissioned research into the use of these techniques in measuring the cost-effectiveness of local authorities.5 This chapter outlines the techniques that were proposed and assesses their suitability for measuring the efficiency of public sector organisations. 8.1 Efficiency measurement in the public sector Measuring an organisation’s efficiency is about the relationship between the outputs it produces and the inputs it uses. An efficient organisation would be one that produces the maximum possible outputs given its inputs, or one that produces a certain level of output with the minimum amount of inputs. The process of trying to measure an organisation’s efficiency can therefore be broken down into three steps. First, its inputs and outputs need to be defined and measured. Secondly, it is necessary to define what is feasible – in other words, what outputs could be achieved for any given set of inputs. Finally, the organisation’s actual inputs and outputs are compared with the set of feasible inputs and outputs. At this stage, one of two questions can be asked: ‘Is it feasible to achieve superior outputs, given the set of inputs being used?’ or ‘Is it feasible to use less inputs to achieve the same outputs?’. The way the first two steps are carried out will typically be highly influential on the outcome of the third. Definition and measurement of outputs, inputs and environmental factors Efficiency measurement is relatively straightforward for an organisation producing one type of output with one type of input. But most organisations – public and private – produce a wide range of outputs and use numerous inputs. In the case of a private firm selling its output in a competitive market, different outputs can be aggregated by using the observed prices.6 But public sector organisations usually produce goods that are provided either free at the point of use or at a price that is not determined by market forces. This makes it 4 HM Treasury, ‘Improving Police Performance: A New Approach to Measuring Police Efficiency’, Press Release PSP4, 17 April 2000. 5 Office of the Deputy Prime Minister, Local and Regional Government Research Programme Newsletter 2002–03 (www.local.dtlr.gov.uk/research/02.htm). 6 Under certain assumptions, prices will reflect market or buyers’ valuations of the outputs. They therefore act as a natural set of weights that can be used to aggregate outputs into a single measure. See, for example, W. E. Diewert, ‘Fisher ideal output, input and productivity indexes revisited’, Journal of Productivity Analysis, 1992, vol. 3, no. 3, pp. 211–48. 106 Measuring public sector efficiency very difficult to define the aggregate output of a public service provider such as a school, hospital or police force. Inputs, such as hospital beds, are usually easier to deal with, as prices are more often observed. Another difficulty arises because some inputs are not under the control of an organisation. These can include environmental variables such as the characteristics of individuals using the service – for example, their underlying health – that may have an impact on measured efficiency. It is therefore necessary to find a way to take account of their effects when comparing organisations. Defining what is feasible With an appropriate set of inputs and outputs at hand, the next task is to define the efficient set of inputs and outputs against which an organisation can be compared. This is, however, unknown. The procedure therefore is to compare an organisation with an ideal comparator constructed from information on other organisations operating in the same field (and with similar size and environmental factors etc.).7 In practice, this is often difficult, as similar organisations may be few and far between, especially in the public sector. Environmental differences are particularly difficult to control for in this respect. For example, schools will differ in the average ability of children in their catchment area and ambulance service response times will vary according to population density. If these environmental factors are taken into account when selecting the comparison group, then the group will often be rather small or even empty. If they are not, then any efficiency measurements that emerge may simply reflect differences in these environmental factors. Measuring efficiency Setting the difficulties of finding comparable organisations aside, two particular technical methods were put forward in the Public Services Productivity Panel report as useful ways of deriving efficiency measures for a group of ‘similar’ organisations. The two methods that have been proposed are stochastic frontier analysis (SFA) and data envelopment analysis (DEA). It is important to ascertain whether these techniques are really robust and general enough to achieve the purposes for which it has been suggested they are used.8 To look at this, we begin by describing the two techniques. Consider Figure 8.1. The dots represent observed input and output combinations for six organisations. The two sets of lines (the solid curved line and the dotted line made up of lots of straight segments) are ‘frontiers’ and show the maximum output that could be 7 Of course, given the information available, this comparator may in itself be inefficient compared with what is possible. 8 For a discussion of these issues with particular reference to the Spottiswoode Report, see M. Stone, ‘How not to measure the efficiency of public services (and how one might)’, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A, 2002, vol. 165, issue 3, pp. 405–34, and the discussion in the same volume. 107 Green Budget, January 2003 produced for each level of input. The two frontiers represent the outcomes of the two methods of measuring efficiency, SFA and DEA. Figure 8.1. SFA and DEA Output SFA frontier DEA frontier E } noise { B noise inefficiency { D F C A Input Stochastic frontier analysis Stochastic frontier analysis uses statistical methods to fit a frontier like the solid curve in Figure 8.1. The idea is to identify the relationship between output and input(s) whilst allowing for two types of deviation from this relationship. One is statistical ‘noise’ – in other words, random variations in the data caused by inaccuracy in the measurement of output and by other errors. This first type of deviation is assumed to be zero on average, so that, on average, output is measured accurately.9 The second type of deviation is a measure of inefficiency. It is one-sided: if a firm were fully efficient, it would be zero, and the more inefficient the organisation is, the more negative the deviation. These two types of deviation from the efficient frontier are shown in the figure by the curly brackets for organisations D and E. In this case, organisations B and E are classed as efficient as they lie above the frontier and organisations A, C, D and F are inefficient to some degree. The extent to which an organisation’s total deviation from the frontier is designated to be noise versus inefficiency depends on the choices made about the joint distributions of the two components. Data envelopment analysis Data envelopment analysis is a non-statistical approach to the problem of efficiency measurement. Put simply, it takes data on organisations’ outputs and inputs, and measures the efficiency of a particular organisation by its distance from the ‘outer envelope’ of the data. This outer envelope is shown in Figure 8.1 by the dashed line for the case where there are assumed to be 9 As long as this noise is not correlated with either the inputs or the second type of deviation, it is of no particular interest. 108 Measuring public sector efficiency variable returns to scale. With this technique, all deviations from the efficient frontier are classed entirely as inefficiency. In the figure, the solid arrow represents a measure of organisation D’s inefficiency. Organisations A, B and E are measured as efficient and organisations C, D, and F as inefficient. It is worth noting that this procedure (and this variable-returns-to-scale version of it in particular) can designate an organisation as completely efficient simply because it produces more of a particular output than other organisations. In this single-output example, the organisation that produces the most will find itself on the efficient frontier simply because there is no larger organisation with which to compare it. Measurement error and the form of the frontier Stochastic frontier analysis requires a great deal of knowledge, both about the shape of the frontier and the distributions of the two types of deviation, if it is to yield a useful answer. The choice that is made about the shape of the frontier and the distributions of the deviation components can have significant effects on the efficiency rankings and absolute efficiency measures generated. These choices can be pretty much arbitrary: economic theory often provides little information about the shape of the frontier, and the data can be uninformative about the distributions of the two types of deviation. Failing to measure the inputs accurately can further complicate the task of correctly identifying organisations’ relative efficiency.10 Data envelopment analysis does not require any assumptions about the shape of the frontier or about statistical distributions. But as the whole approach, by definition, focuses on extreme observations, it is very sensitive to mismeasurement. For example, in Figure 8.1, if the output of organisation E were inaccurately recorded and overstated, inclusion of E in the frontier would mean that the frontier was mismeasured and that the inefficiency of organisations such as F would be overstated. Furthermore, actual organisations are generally compared with hypothetical organisations (for example, the point on the DEA frontier with which organisation D is compared is a hypothetical organisation), which can mean that results are fragile if there are few real observations from which to determine the potential performance of these hypothetical organisations. How many inputs and outputs to include Both approaches will give results that depend upon the choice of inputs and outputs considered. An important issue is how many to include. As the number of inputs and outputs measured increases, the task of measuring efficiency becomes rapidly more difficult. In the SFA approach, one problem is trying to choose appropriate forms for the frontier where the data are very sparse and are barely informative about the appropriate choice. Another is specifying how the many noise and inefficiency components are distributed. 10 More generally, the problem is one of measurement error in the explanatory variables. See P. W. Bauer, ‘Recent developments in the econometric estimation of frontiers’, Journal of Econometrics, 1990, vol. 46, pp. 39–56. 109 Green Budget, January 2003 In the DEA context, as the number of outputs increases, it turns out that the measured efficiency of the organisations cannot go down and, in the extreme, all organisations will end up being regarded as 100% efficient.11 The intuition for this is quite straightforward: if you specify outputs very finely, you will eventually end up defining one output unique to each organisation, which – not surprisingly – it is uniquely efficient at producing. Choosing the level of aggregation of inputs and outputs is therefore an essential aspect of the exercise. There is no really good way of knowing how far or how little to disaggregate, yet the results will be heavily influenced by this choice. In order for these methods to yield useful results, the number of dimensions must be kept fairly moderate, and rules of thumb abound – for example, ‘the number of organisations must be more than three times the combined number of inputs and outputs’. Decisions must therefore be made about which inputs and outputs to ignore, which to include and which to aggregate. SFA and DEA in practice Applications of these techniques have illustrated the sensitivity of results to the methods used to measure efficiency. A relatively recent application of statistical methods in measuring public sector efficiency can be seen in The World Health Report 2000 – Health Systems: Improving Performance,12 which compares the efficiency of different countries’ health systems. A scientific peer-group report on the methods employed in the paper was commissioned.13 The report raised a number of the general issues discussed above, as well as a large number of reservations specific to the World Health Organisation’s application of the methods. In particular, the group questioned the publication of league tables (page 123) based on the methods and data used. Another application is work comparing the efficiency of hospital trusts,14 in which the authors highlight the sensitivity of the results to the efficiency measurement techniques used. 8.2 Conclusions The obvious practical question arises of how concentrating on a subset of performance or input indicators might affect organisations’ incentives. Clearly, formulaic application of these methods could have implications for providers’ resource allocation, leading to the underprovision of outputs that are not included in the efficiency measurement exercise. Similarly, if certain organisations find it relatively expensive to produce certain outputs, they may 11 T. Nunamaker, ‘Using data envelopment analysis to measure the efficiency of non-profit organizations: a critical evaluation – reply’, Managerial and Decision Economics, 1985, vol. 6, pp. 50–8. 12 World Health Organisation, The World Health Report 2000 – Health Systems: Improving Performance, Geneva, 2000 (www.who.int/health-systems-performance/whr2000.htm). 13 ‘World Health Report 2000 Consultation and Peer Review’, www.who.int/health-systemsperformance/consultation.htm. 14 D. Dawson, R. Jacobs and A. Street, ‘Comparing the Efficiency of NHS Hospital Trusts’, www.niesr.ac.uk/event/jacobs.pdf. 110 Measuring public sector efficiency tend to redirect resources to other outputs. This has obvious implications for universal service obligations.15 More generally, trade-offs exist between having large numbers of targets or a few, in terms of accurate performance measurement, the costs of gathering and analysing performance information, the incentives given to public service providers, and transparency and accountability in public service provision. The outcomes of DEA and SFA exercises, in the form of rankings or league tables of organisations or other efficiency scores, are sometimes used in a second-stage analysis that tries to uncover the reasons for these measured differences in performance. Typically, the DEA or SFA efficiency scores are regressed on factors that may affect performance – for example, environmental factors that are thought to be under the organisations’ control. Of course, this presupposes that the efficiency scores are correct and, for the reasons discussed above and others specific to any particular application, they may not be. Ultimately, very many auxiliary technical judgements are required when implementing either SFA or DEA techniques. While the methods are potentially useful, the results need to be treated with caution, as should their application as a motivational tool. Ian Crawford, Alexander Klemm and Helen Simpson 15 See A. Chesher, ‘Discussion on the paper by Stone’, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society A, 2002, vol. 165, issue 3, pp. 423–4. 111 9. The distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 The government has carried out many reforms to the tax and benefit system since coming to power in May 1997. We estimate that the overall effect of the changes enacted or announced to date will be an annual cost to the exchequer of around £1.6 billion in 2003–04. This is the difference between a large set of revenue-raising reforms and a slightly larger set of costly changes. These reforms will not have affected all groups in the population equally. Rather, the gains or losses of different people will depend on individual characteristics such as income level, age and family circumstances. The aim of this chapter is to gain a deeper understanding of how tax and benefit reforms have affected different groups in the population. The discussion will also cover the issue of how the burden of ‘taxes on businesses’ has changed. But, in considering this, it is important to remember that individuals ultimately pay all taxes. So our main focus is how the reforms have affected people at different points in the income distribution. After a first section that lists the main reforms made since 1997, Section 9.2 begins the detailed distributional analyses. There, we mainly consider ‘direct’ taxes on labour income and unearned income and ‘indirect’ taxes on expenditure – the payment of which can be allocated relatively straightforwardly to households according to their earnings and their expenditures – as well as receipt of benefits, credits and tax credits.1 We then discuss, in Section 9.3, some of the limitations of this analysis. These include both conceptual limitations (in terms of how we allocate tax payments to particular groups in the population) and data limitations (which constrain the range of taxes we can consider). Section 9.4 looks at ‘taxes on business’, while Section 9.5 considers the distributional consequences of changes to stamp duty on domestic property. Section 9.6 concludes. 9.1 What fiscal reforms? A helpful benchmark when considering the distributional effects of the fiscal reforms made since Labour came to power is their overall impact on the government’s finances. Table 9.1 reports an estimate of the effect on revenues in 2003–04 of the reforms, compared with the revenues that would have been expected if the tax system implied by the November 1996 Budget had been retained (with benefit rates and expenditure taxes uprated in line with inflation 1 This section updates previous IFS work: M. Myck, Fiscal Reforms Since 1997, Briefing Note no. 14, IFS, London, 2000 (www.ifs.org.uk/taxben/fiscalreform.pdf), and T. Clark, M. Myck and Z. Smith, ‘Fiscal reforms affecting households, 1997–2001’, chapter 5 of T. Clark and A. Dilnot (eds), Election Briefing 2001 IFS, London, 2001 (www.ifs.org.uk/election/ebn5.pdf). 112 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 Table 9.1. Revenue effects in 2003–04 of changes to taxes and benefits made since 1997 Net revenue raised for exchequer Total income tax Of which: Married couple’s allowance Income tax rates and personal allowances Dividend tax credits Net revenue cost to exchequer £0.3bn £3.3bn £10.4bn £6.5bn Total National Insurance Of which: Employee contributions Employer contributions Self-employed contributions £5.2bn Total indirect taxes Of which: VAT Tobacco taxation Road fuel duties Alcohol taxation Insurance premium tax Vehicle excise duty £8.3bn Total stamp duties Of which: Changes to rates for properties £2.1bn £2.0bn £1.5bn £0.6bn £0.0bn £2.6bn £4.9bn £0.2bn £1.2bn £1.1bn £2.0bn Total corporation tax Of which: Changes to rate structure Other corporation tax changes £2.8bn £4.4bn £1.6bn Total change in cost of benefits / credits / tax credits Of which: Mortgage interest relief at source Working families’ tax credit (TC) + Disabled persons’ TC + Working TC + Child TC Child benefit (and non-attributable child-based reforms) Pensioners’ package (winter allowance, basic pension and minimum income guarantee increases) Overall total £14.3bn £3.4bn £8.6bn £1.7bn £6.1bn £ 1.6bn Notes: All costings have been deflated to 2003–04 using nominal GDP growth published by the Office for National Statistics and (for projections) HM Treasury. The totals include all measures, not just the taxes and benefits costed in detail in the table. Some taxes and benefits have been reformed more than once since 1996–97, which means that they may score as both exchequer gains and exchequer losses. The figures in the detailed breakdowns in this table are approximate. In some instances, it is not possible to break down the cost of measures introduced into the categories given in the table. For example, increases to child premiums in both income support and WFTC are often grouped together in costings published by the Treasury. In such cases, the effect of the changes is either attributed to the category deemed likely to be responsible for the greater part of the cost, or added to child benefit (and nonattributable child-based reforms). The difficulty with separating the effects of some measures also explains why the WFTC, DPTC, WTC and child TC are considered as one category. Sources: HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report and Pre-Budget Report, various years. 113 Green Budget, January 2003 and the parameters of the income tax system uprated in line with statutory rules). The table also lists the costs or revenues raised by certain specific measures that had large effects on the government budget. The measures considered include some that were announced by the Conservative government before May 1997 and which Labour chose to implement, such as the tobacco and fuel duty escalators, which were originally announced in the Budgets of 1993. The table shows that the net effect of all policy changes in the tax and benefit systems will have been a small fiscal loosening of around £1.6 billion compared with what the government’s budgetary position would have been had the system implied by the November 1996 Budget been retained. This figure is actually the difference between a large set of revenue-raising measures (around £51.7 billion) and a slightly larger set of costly reforms (around £53.3 billion). For example, Table 9.1 shows that costly changes to income tax, such as the introduction of the 10p starting rate and reduction of the basic rate, have been almost entirely offset by revenue-raising changes to the same tax. In contrast, by next year, the exchequer will have gained significant net revenues from changes to National Insurance2 and indirect taxes (such as road fuel duties), plus a smaller amount from stamp duties. The tax changes overall raise around £12.7 billion, in effect paying most of the £14.3 billion projected net cost of benefit increases and the creation of new credits and tax credits. The reforms listed in Table 9.1 only include fiscal changes that involve direct financial transfers to or from the state. In the second half of its first term in office, the Labour government also began to devote significant funds to extra spending on the National Health Service, and on education and other public services. Much of this spending was financed from extra tax revenues that have not been due to the discretionary policy changes considered in Table 9.1. Taxes as a share of national income in 2003–04 are forecast by the Treasury to be 39.3%, compared with 37.4% in 1996–97.3 This increase of 1.9 percentage points is equivalent to £20.8 billion in 2003–04 terms. Analysis of the increase to 2001–02 shows that much of it is increased income tax receipts as a share of national income. Likely causes of the overall increase include changes in the composition of national income, and the level of the oil price.4 In this chapter, we will not attempt to consider the distributional effects of spending on public services, nor the impact of changes in tax take or benefit expenditure that are not due to policy changes: we focus our attention on the effects of discretionary changes in financial transfers. In the next section, we consider the distributional effects of those reforms where the financial transfer can most straightforwardly be allocated to particular households. The latter 2 For details of the changes to National Insurance, see Chapter 5. 3 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 4 For a fuller discussion, see chapter 2 of A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2001, Commentary no. 83, IFS, London, 2001, and chapter 3 of T. Clark and A. Dilnot (eds), IFS Election Commentary, Commentary no. 84, IFS, London, 2001. 114 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 part of the chapter discusses some of the reasons why it is more difficult to model the distributional effects of changes in ‘business taxes’ and stamp duties. 9.2 The distributional impact of reforms directly affecting households In the previous section, we listed the main reforms to taxes and benefits that have occurred since 1997. In this section, we use TAXBEN, the IFS simulation model of the tax and benefit system, to assess the distributional impact that followed from some of them. The taxes and benefits that we include in the analysis are those levied directly on incomes or on personal expenditures. We can allocate the payment of these taxes and benefits to households using data on the incomes and expenditures of household members. The direct taxes we model include payments of income tax due on labour income and benefit income, but not all of those that are levied on other incomes (so we do not model the effect of the abolition of dividend tax credits). We also model both employer and employee National Insurance contributions. Employers’ National Insurance is sometimes thought of as a tax on businesses, but, like income tax and employee contributions, it is levied on wages and salaries, and so it is consistent with our methodology to include it as a tax on labour income (see also Section 9.4). Reforms to the benefit system are also analysed,5 and the expenditure taxes that we model include VAT and most excise duties, but not stamp duty on house purchases. Table 9.1 indicated that amongst the changes we analyse, reforms to income tax, National Insurance and excise duties (notably including road fuel duty) all had significant revenue effects. Many households also benefited from increased transfers via benefits or credits and tax credits. The net modelled effect of the changes considered here is to increase household incomes6 and therefore loosen the government’s fiscal position next year by £9.8 billion,7 which is approximately £8 per household per week.8 Given that we calculated the overall net effect of Labour’s reforms to be a fiscal loosening next year of just £1.6 billion – nearer £1.50 per household per week – it is clear that by focusing only on the subset of measures that directly affect households, we show a much more generous average ‘giveaway’ than we would do if we included all the tax and benefit changes. For example, we do not capture the 5 With the exception of some reforms to bereavement and incapacity benefits, which we cannot model due to data limitations. 6 Net of direct taxes and benefits, credits and tax credits. 7 Cash changes are expressed in October 2002 prices. 8 The modelling that underlies these numbers and Figure 9.1 compares a world with the tax system that will exist once all the reforms announced by January 2003 have been enacted, and a hypothetical world in which the 1996–97 tax system had been retained and benefit rates and expenditure taxes had been uprated in line with inflation whilst the parameters of the income tax system were uprated in line with statutory rules. This means that we do include changes to National Insurance and the new credits and tax credits that will come into force during 2003. 115 Green Budget, January 2003 relatively large tax revenues from dividend tax changes or increases in stamp duties, although neither do we capture the more modest cuts in corporation tax. Another reason for the discrepancy in the estimated budgetary effects is that payments of (for example) expenditure taxes that are levied on institutions other than households will not show up in the analysis presented here.9 Figure 9.1 shows how the gains from our relatively generous subset of tax and benefit changes are spread across the income distribution. In the figure, the population of households is ranked according to income and then split into 10 equally sized groups or ‘deciles’. For each decile, the figure plots the estimated average percentage change in net incomes resulting from the reforms modelled. Figure 9.1. Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997 Percentage change in income 20 15 10 5 0 -5 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income deciles Notes: Deciles are constructed by ranking households according to their income – measured before housing costs and adjusted for family size – and then splitting the population into 10 equally sized groups. The bars show the modelled impact on real incomes (measured in October 2002 prices) of the majority of changes to direct and indirect taxes and to benefits and credits that have occurred since 1997. Source: Authors’ calculations based on results from the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using Family Resources Survey 2000–01 and Family Expenditure Survey 1999–2000. We can see that the reforms are progressive. Whilst net incomes across the population increase by around 2% on average (shown by the black line), incomes in the poorest group increase by slightly more than 15%. Increases get steadily smaller as income rises and are almost exactly zero in decile 8. There are small losses in decile 9, and the richest group experiences a loss of almost 3% of its net income. In cash, rather than proportional, terms, average gains are found to be £20 or more per week in each of the bottom three 9 In part, the discrepancy may also be due to undercounting of revenues from some expenditure taxes in our model because the data available to us tend to under-report some types of household expenditures. 116 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 deciles, whilst average losses are around £6 per week in decile 9 and around £28 per week in the richest group. As well as looking at how changes vary across the income distribution, we can also look at which types of family have gained from the reforms that we model. This is of interest because, as well as targeting benefit increases and tax cuts towards those with low incomes, Labour has also given special priority to reducing poverty among children and among pensioners.10 It is not surprising to find that pensioners and low-income families with children were the biggest gainers from the package of reforms that we model. No-earner couples with children are found to gain around £40 a week, on average, and the figure is around £28 for single parents. Pensioner households also gain more than £20 per week, on average. For groups containing working-age adults with no children, average changes were of a smaller magnitude than the gains amongst the elderly and those with children. 9.3 Limitations of the distributional analysis The above analysis measures the distributional impact of changes to taxes and benefits where the payment can relatively easily be allocated to households according to the personal incomes or expenditures of household members. It therefore encompasses the majority of those taxes that are levied on the earnings or spending of private individuals, plus the majority of transfer payments made through the benefit system. The ‘tax payment’11 that we allocate to each household is the sum of the tax levied on all spending by household members and that levied on the incomes received for the labour supplied by household members, minus any benefit payments that they receive. To make comparisons between the distributional effects of the tax system as it existed at different points in time, we assume that (gross) incomes and expenditures (inclusive of tax payments) are not affected by the tax system. In other words, for each household in the data, we compare the tax payment implied by each tax system, given their observed expenditure and labour income. Using this notion of ‘tax payment’ is not the same thing as considering who makes the cash transfer to the state: much of income tax and VAT is administered via cash transfers between companies and the relevant authority. Nor does it capture the economic notion of effective incidence – in other words, who is ultimately made financially worse off as a result of a particular tax being imposed rather than collecting the same revenue (and financing the 10 The different ways that Labour has used social security and direct tax reforms to target support towards particular groups are discussed in M. Brewer, T. Clark and M. Wakefield, ‘Social security in the UK under new Labour: what did the third way mean for welfare reform?’, Fiscal Studies, 2002, vol. 23, pp. 505–37 (see especially section VI). 11 This terminology and many of the ideas here are due to A. Dilnot, J. Kay and M. Keen, ‘Allocating taxes to households: a methodology’, Oxford Economic Papers, 1990, vol. 42, pp. 210–30. 117 Green Budget, January 2003 same pattern of government expenditure) from some other source. The effective incidence of a tax depends on how prices charged and quantities traded are affected by this tax, and we do not model these. Since the welfare of households will also ultimately depend on the amount that they consume and the number of hours that they work, we also do not capture the welfare effects of tax changes. Figure 9.2. Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997 Percentage change in income 20 Base case 15 Extra allocated as constant proportion 10 5 0 -5 -10 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Income decile Notes: See notes to Figure 9.1. Source: Authors’ calculations based on the numbers in Table 9.1 (see sources there) and results from the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using Family Resources Survey 2000–01 and Family Expenditure Survey 1999–2000. Nonetheless, our methodology does yield a first approximation to how the tax system affects households. Accepting the usefulness of such an approximation, the biggest weakness in the analysis is that, while we have acknowledged that all taxes and benefits are ultimately paid to or by people, we also omit a large set of reforms. We estimated that the reforms that we are able to model would increase household incomes in 2003–04 by around £8.2 billion more than will the full set of tax and benefit reforms since 1997. A crude way to generate a comprehensive picture of the distributional implications of all of these tax and benefit reforms would be to assume that those changes that were omitted had an equal proportionate impact on all households, reducing disposable incomes by approximately 1.7%.12 This is equivalent to taking £2.25 per week, on average, from households in the poorest decile and almost £17 per week, on average, from those in the richest tenth. Allocating extra changes in this proportional way will not affect the progressive shape of the distribution of proportional changes in incomes due 12 In allocating the full £8.2 billion to the UK household sector, we ignore the fact that some taxes may be levied on the incomes or expenditures of individuals who are not UK residents. 118 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 to the reforms modelled.13 This is shown in Figure 9.2, which compares the results of Figure 9.1 with the results as they would look if the package modelled did take an extra 1.7% from the incomes of all households. The assumption of equal proportional changes is unlikely to reflect accurately who would actually pay extra tax due to the measures omitted in Section 9.2. An important set of taxes that were omitted are those levied on incomes that derive from company profits or from the ownership of property. For example, tax-raising changes to stamp duties and dividend tax credits, and cuts in corporation tax, were not modelled. It is unlikely that these taxes have a constant proportional impact on incomes across the income distribution. Their omission was largely due to inadequate data rather than due to these taxes not being amenable to analysis within the framework of ‘tax payments’. To help clarify the conceptual framework, and to see how misleading the benchmark case of a constant proportional impact is, in the next two sections we consider ‘taxes on business’ and stamp duty on residential property transactions. 9.4 Taxes on business How much have taxes on business increased? The answer depends, to a large extent, on what we think should be included under the heading of ‘taxes on business’. At one extreme, we might start with the idea of all taxes paid to the government by firms. This would include not only corporation tax and business rates, but also most of VAT, all of income tax collected under the PAYE system and all National Insurance contributions levied on the earnings of employed workers, regardless of whether these are labelled as employer or employee contributions. Most observers would agree that this definition would be much too broad. At the other extreme, we might classify taxes according to who feels their ‘effective incidence’, or who is ultimately made worse off by their imposition. Unfortunately, this would lead us to the conclusion that there are no taxes on business, as companies have a legal identity only and cannot be made worse off in any meaningful sense. A reasonable intermediate position might be to consider those taxes whose effective incidence falls on the owners of companies. This does not produce a neat, operational classification of taxes into those on business and those not on business, and may suggest rather surprising results in some cases. For example, in a small, perfectly competitive, open economy with a high degree of international capital mobility but limited international mobility of labour, it can reasonably be argued that much of the effective incidence of a sourcebased corporate income tax will ultimately fall on domestic workers rather than on shareholders. With mobile capital, investors – regardless of where they live – will only finance investment projects that generate a given post-tax rate of return – regardless of where the activity is located. If a country imposes a corporation tax that reduces the post-tax return on investment located in its territory, the result will be that investors finance fewer investment projects in 13 Indeed, allocating changes in this fashion is equivalent to shifting the axis marking a zero proportional change up by 1.7 percentage points on the bars showing the changes for each decile. 119 Green Budget, January 2003 that country – only those projects with a pre-tax return high enough to pay the required post-tax return after corporation tax will continue to be viable. Workers in that country will then operate with less capital per worker, be less productive and earn lower wages as a result. Assuming that migration is insufficient to equalise wages across countries, it is workers rather than shareholders in the country imposing the corporation tax who will ultimately be worse off.14 Interesting as this may be, it does not accord well with popular perceptions of what are considered as taxes on business. A more pragmatic and more common approach focuses on rights to the sources of income on which different taxes are levied. This is very similar to the way in which we allocated tax payments in Section 9.2. There we allocated the payment of labour taxes to the individual on whose labour income the tax is levied. A natural extension would be to allocate taxes on incomes derived from company profits to the owners of the company who have the right to the income stream on which the tax is levied. Applying this idea suggests that taxes that are levied on company profits, or on some component of company profits (e.g. dividends), can be classed as a category of ‘taxes on (the owners of) business’. This may be considered too narrow, but it is unclear what general principles would lead to a satisfactory, broader definition. Following this approach, corporation tax, which is levied on company profits that are ultimately paid to the owners of companies, is classified as a business tax. Income tax on wages and salaries is not classified as a tax on business, since wages and salaries are paid to workers, not to shareholders. Income tax on company dividends is however classed as a business tax, since dividends are distributed profits, and are clearly paid to the owners of companies. By the same principle, National Insurance contributions are classed as a tax on individuals, regardless of whether these are nominally employer or employee contributions. Like income tax, all National Insurance contributions are levied on a base of wages and salaries (albeit with different rates structures), and it is hard to think of any reasonable principle that would result in employer and employee National Insurance contributions being treated differently. There may be disagreement as to whether their effective incidence is mainly on workers or mainly on the owners of firms, but a basic principle of public economics is that the effective incidence of a tax should not depend, at least in the long run, on whether it is levied on the buyer or the seller of a good or service. Thus the effective incidence of employer National Insurance contributions may be on employers, to the extent that it is not shifted onto workers in the form of lower wages. But if this is so, the effective incidence of employee National Insurance contributions would also fall on employers, as higher wages would then need to be paid to attract the same workforce. In this case, the effective incidence argument would quickly lead to personal income 14 Shareholders continue to earn the same post-tax rate of return on their investments, though the companies they own may be locating less activity at home and more activity overseas. Under these conditions, owners of companies can only be made worse off in the long run by residence-based taxes levied on their worldwide investment income from all sources. Since relatively little revenue is collected from such taxes, this approach would not classify most taxes as ‘business taxes’. 120 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 tax on wages and salaries also being classed as a business tax, which does not seem a satisfactory result. By how much have ‘business taxes’ changed since 1997? Notwithstanding the limitations of this approach, we focus here on the extent to which taxes levied on company profits have increased under Labour governments since 1997. A broader approach might also include taxes levied on some components of business expenditure – for example, business rates levied on the occupation of non-domestic property and environmental taxes such as the climate change levy and the aggregates tax. As it happens, extending our analysis to include these taxes would have little impact on the discussion in this section. Business rates have generally been increased in line with inflation under Labour, as they were under the previous Conservative administration. The introduction of the climate change levy and the aggregates tax was intended to be revenue-neutral for the business sector overall, with a corresponding reduction in employer National Insurance contributions.15 Even restricting our attention to taxes on company profits, there has been no shortage of tax changes since 1997, with somewhat offsetting effects on overall tax revenues. The principal changes are summarised in Table 9.2. The biggest single increase was brought about by the abolition of repayable tax credits on dividend income for pension funds and some other tax-exempt shareholders, introduced in July 1997. This was, in effect, an increase in tax levied on distributed profits for those shareholders. At the time, this was estimated to raise upwards of £5 billion per annum for the exchequer by 1999– 2000, although, so far as we are aware, estimates for later tax years have not been published.16 The second major increase was temporary, resulting from the introduction of quarterly instalment payments of corporation tax for large companies. The effect of the new system was to accelerate tax payments compared with the old system of advance corporation tax (ACT). This brought in substantial revenues over the four financial years up to 2002–03: it was estimated to increase corporation tax receipts by, on average, around £2 billion in each of those years. It should be noted that this reform has a major effect on tax revenues if figures are presented on a cumulative basis for the period from 1997 onwards, but has little impact if figures are presented for individual years from 2003–04 onwards.17 Immediately prior to this temporary rise in 15 Note that the offsetting reduction in employer NICs would not be classed as a reduction in business taxes, following the general approach of this section. However, the extent to which the effective incidence of these environmental taxes falls on the owners of companies, or is shifted onto consumers in the form of higher product prices, is also unclear. Without further analysis of such issues, it would seem unduly harsh to treat this revenue-neutral policy as imposing an increase in taxes on business. 16 Our estimates for later years simply uprate the initial £5.4 billion in line with nominal GDP growth. 17 Actually, there is a small negative effect of this reform from 2003–04 onwards. This comes mainly from the loss of revenue from ‘surplus ACT’. ACT only affected the timing of tax payments for most firms, but had the effect of increasing total tax payments for firms in a 121 Green Budget, January 2003 corporation tax payments, there was a temporary contribution to government revenues of a similar amount in 1997–98 and 1998–99 from the windfall levy imposed on privatised utilities. More recently, there is a small increase in tax revenue resulting from changes to the taxation of North Sea oil and gas production. Table 9.2. Revenue effects of major changes in ‘business taxes’ (£ billion) 1997–98 1998–99 1999–2000 2000–01 2001–02 2002–03 2003–04 Corporation tax rate cuts: July 1997 –1.6 –2.2 –2.3 –2.4 –2.5 –2.6 March 1998 –0.8 –1.1 –1.2 –1.2 March 1999 –0.1 –0.1 –0.1 April 2002 –0.0 –0.3 Total –1.6 –2.2 –3.1 –3.6 –3.8 –4.3a R&D tax credits –0.1 –0.5 –0.6 ACT replaced by 0.1 1.6 2.0 3.1 2.2 –0.5 quarterly instalments Dividend tax credits 2.3 4.0 5.4 5.7 5.9 6.2 6.5 North Sea taxation: Introduction of 10% 0.1 0.5 supplementary charge and 100% capital allowances Abolition of licence royalties –0.2 Windfall levy 2.6 2.6 Total revenue effect 4.9 5.1 4.8 4.6 5.3 4.1 1.4a a Differences between these figures and those in Table 9.1 arise from the fact that here we only consider reforms that were announced by Labour after the party was elected in 1997, whereas Table 9.1 includes costings for all measures enacted since 1997. Table 9.1 is also more comprehensive and includes the estimated effects of a number of technical changes and antiavoidance measures that are excluded from this table of major reforms. Notes: Tax rate cuts include the revenue effects of cuts in the small companies’ rate and the introduction and subsequent reduction in the starting rate. Initial costings come from Budget and Pre-Budget Reports, and where necessary these have been uprated to later years using the index of nominal GDP growth published by the Office for National Statistics and (for projections) HM Treasury. Sources: HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, various years; HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report, 2002; Inland Revenue Press Release 2, 2 July 1997; Inland Revenue Press Release 8, 17 March 1998; Inland Revenue Press Release 9, 17 March 1998. These increases in taxes on company profits have been offset by cuts in the main rate of corporation tax, which was reduced from 33% to 31% in the July 1997 Budget at a cost of around £2 billion per annum, and to 30% in the March 1998 Budget at a cost of around £1 billion per annum. Corresponding reductions in the small companies’ corporation tax rate are costing the exchequer around £0.5 billion per annum. Further tax cuts include the introduction of a 10% starting rate of corporation tax in the March 1999 Budget, which was reduced to 0% in the April 2002 Budget, and the introduction of new tax credits for research and development. ‘surplus’ ACT position, which could not fully offset their ACT payments against mainstream corporation tax liabilities. 122 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 An accurate estimate of the overall effect of these changes is difficult to produce, as official costings of different reforms have covered different time periods and some are now rather outdated. A ballpark figure for 2002–03 would suggest an increase in the region of £4 billion, reflecting around £8 billion extra revenue from dividend taxation and quarterly instalments, offset by around £4 billion from rate cuts and other changes. For 2003–04, we estimate a smaller increase, in the region of £1–£2 billion, as the effect of the transition to quarterly payments is no longer present. Much then depends on the particular year for which any estimates are reported, and, as noted earlier, the effect of the switch from ACT to quarterly instalments appears much more significant if measured cumulatively over this period rather than for the final year that we consider. Our discussion here also excludes the effect of a host of technical changes and anti-avoidance measures,18 the costs of which are inherently difficult to estimate accurately, and a number of measures limited to smaller firms.19 We conclude by reiterating that there is no compelling way of classifying particular taxes as ‘taxes on business’. In our distributional analysis, we have followed an approach that allocates ‘tax payments’ to the individual who has the right to the income stream on which a tax is levied, or whose resources are used to fund an expenditure on which a tax is levied. Largely due to limitations of data, taxes levied on incomes derived from company profits were not allocated to households. These taxes on company profits have been higher over the period 1997–98 to 2002–03 as a result of changes introduced by Gordon Brown. The government’s emphasis on changes to corporation tax rates does not tell the full story here. On the other hand, estimates of the scale of the increase in ‘business taxes’ can easily be exaggerated. Moreover, some of these effects are explicitly temporary, and it is expected that revenues from these taxes in 2003–04 will be only around £1–£2 billion greater than would have been the case had Labour not introduced any of these reforms. This is small compared with the net giveaway of £9.8 billion modelled in Section 9.2, and so allocating the payment of ‘business taxes’ to individuals according to their ownership shares in companies would not significantly affect the distributional results found there. Further, since share ownership tends to be concentrated in the upper reaches of the income distribution,20 allocating these taxes might add to the progressive overall effect of reforms since 1997. 18 Examples include stricter limits on the carry-back of losses, changes to the taxation of insurance companies and changes to the rules affecting controlled foreign companies. 19 Examples include higher capital allowances for investment in plant and machinery, and tax relief for venture capital trusts. 20 The pattern of share ownership in the UK, and how little data we have on the amount of wealth individuals have in pension funds, are discussed in J. Banks and M. Wakefield, ‘Stockholding in the United Kingdom’, chapter 8 of L. Guiso, M. Haliassos and T. Jappelli (eds), Stockholding in Europe, Palgrave Macmillan, Hampshire, 2003. 123 Green Budget, January 2003 9.5 Stamp duty on residential properties Although stamp duty is paid on transactions of both residential and nonresidential properties, here we only consider sales of residential properties. We restrict our focus in this way because it is easier to allocate payments within the income distribution when the buyer is an individual or a family, rather than a company. In the analysis of Section 9.2, revenues are deemed to have been raised from expenditure taxes if there have been increases in the rate of the tax or expansion of the tax base (i.e. the total value of the transactions on which the tax is levied). Considered in this way, stamp duty on residential properties would have raised money since 1997 for two reasons: first, the threshold house price at which tax payments begin has been fixed in nominal terms, which means that some revenues have been due to the fact that house price inflation has moved more property transactions into the stamp duty tax base; secondly, a graduated structure has been added to what was previously a tax with only one positive tax rate. In this section, we discuss only the revenues raised from the introduction of the graduated structure.21 When Labour came to power in 1997, stamp duty was paid at a rate of 1% on the value of property transactions that exceeded £60,000. Transactions of £60,000 or less were not liable for the tax. Since 1997, a graduated structure has been introduced via a series of reforms, as shown in Table 9.3. Table 9.3. Rate of stamp duty on property, 1997 to present day Transaction value (£000) 0–60 60–250 250–500 500+ Before 8 July 1997 8 July 1997 – 23 March 1998 0% 1% 1% 1% 0% 1% 1.5% 2% 24 March 1998 – 15 March 1999 0% 1% 2% 3% 16 March 1999 – 27 March 2000 0% 1% 2.5% 3.5% 28 March 2000 to date 0% 1% 3% 4% To summarise, the rate of stamp duty on any residential property that sells for more than £250,000 has increased since 1997. It has increased from 1% to 3% for properties that sell for between £250,001 and £500,000, and from 1% to 4% for properties that sell for more than £500,000. Labour has not changed the fact that stamp duty operates as an average rate tax. This means that if a property transaction falls into the top stamp-duty band, then the tax is paid at 4% on the full value of the sale, not just the value exceeding £500,000. Similarly, if a transaction falls into one of the lower bands, then 1% or 3% tax will be levied on the entire transaction value. To take an example, a £300,000 property transaction will be liable for £9,000 of stamp duty, which is 3% of £300,000. 21 Although some of these revenues are themselves due to the fact that since the graduated structure was first created in 1997, the thresholds for higher-rate bands have not been increased to allow for inflation. 124 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 The data in Table 9.1 indicate that £2.1 billion extra revenue has been raised from stamp duties since 1997, but they do not isolate how much of this has come from the introduction of a graduated system for residential properties. We approximate for this figure by using data published by the Inland Revenue that give the yield of stamp duty on residential properties by the price band of property transactions. For example, in 2001–02, when the increases to 3% and 4% had been fully implemented, we know that yields were as given in the first column of Table 9.4. Table 9.4. Yield of stamp duty on residential property, 2001–02 Stamp duty band Yield £ million Proportion due Estimated £millions to change in due to change in rates rates 965 â…” 643 £250,001–£500,000 715 ¾ 536 £500,001+ 1,680 n/a 1,180 Total Sources: Inland Revenue Statistics, www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/stats; authors’ calculations. If the structure of stamp duty had not been changed after 1996–97, then for property transactions exceeding £60,000 in value, the tax yield would have been 1% of transaction values. Due to changes in the tax structure, the tax yield for transactions in the £250,001–£500,000 price range in 2001–02 was actually 3% of transaction values. If we assume that property prices in 2001– 02 were not affected by the changes in the structure of stamp duty after 1997,22 then we can state that the extra stamp duty paid on property transactions in this price range due to increases in the tax rate was 2% of transaction values (the excess of 3% over 1%). In other words, two-thirds of the tax yield for these transactions was due to the reforms. By similar reasoning, we can argue that three-quarters of the yield on transactions of £500,001 or more was due to increases in the tax rate. Applying this reasoning, Table 9.4 shows that we estimate the amount of extra tax paid to be around £1.18 billion. In other words, if we had included this change in stamp duty in our distributional analysis in Section 9.2, then the total cost to the exchequer of the reforms considered would have been around £8.6 billion (or £7 per family per week, on average) rather than £9.8 billion (or around £8 per family per week). We now consider how payments of this stamp duty might be spread across the income distribution. Our analysis of this issue will be conducted in a slightly different way from that in which we allocated payments of expenditure taxes in Section 9.2, but it might give a reasonable approximation for how we would have allocated these duties. As we now explain, the results might also be of interest if the financial cost of stamp duty actually falls on house-sellers rather than house-buyers. Throughout this chapter, in allocating tax payments we have assumed that total expenditures remain unaltered after a reform and that the extra tax is paid out of these expenditures. We then allocate the tax payment to the household 22 This is unlikely to be the case, as we would expect to observe spikes in the distribution of sale values just below the thresholds. 125 Green Budget, January 2003 containing the person who made the particular expenditure (that is, to the buyers of goods and services). In order to allocate payments of stamp duty on properties in this way, we would need to know the incomes of house-buyers and the amount that they paid for their new homes. But data of this kind are not easily available. We can, though, observe the incomes and estimated property values for homeowners in the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS) for 2000. We will allocate the cost of stamp duty across the income distribution according to these data. To the extent that house-buyers have different characteristics from homeowners, allocating payments of stamp duty according to the values of the stock of properties owned and the characteristics of owners will give us different results from allocating according to the values of properties that are traded and the characteristics of buyers. First-time buyers are perhaps especially likely to fall into different age and income groups from typical homeowners. Also, the approximation will only be accurate to the extent to which homeowners tend to stay within the same stamp-duty band when they move home. The results of our method are also of interest in themselves because they tell us who loses out from an increase in stamp duty if the tax change results in a fall in the price that owners can expect to receive for their properties. Table 9.5. Distribution of the value of homes worth more than £250,000, across the income distribution Decile of total population income Percentage of value of total stock of distribution homes worth £250,000+ Poorest 6.4 2 1.3 3 3.1 4 4.8 5 6.3 6 7.7 7 5.0 8 14.6 9 14.8 Richest 36.0 Total 100.0 Notes: Deciles are constructed by ranking households according to their income adjusted for family size and then splitting the population into 10 equally sized groups. Also, see footnote 23. Sources: British Household Panel Survey 2000; authors’ calculations. For each income decile, we will allocate a proportion of the cost of the extra stamp duty paid that is equal to the proportion of the total value of the stock of all properties in each stamp-duty band that is owned by people in that income group. For a sample of 4,824 households from the 2000 BHPS, Table 9.5 reports percentages of the value of the stock of all properties worth more than £250,000 that were owned by households in each income decile. In the table, we do not split properties according to whether or not they are worth more or 126 Distributional effects of fiscal reforms since 1997 less than the upper £500,000 stamp-duty threshold because there were too few very valuable homes in the data to make such a split interesting.23 We have estimated that, in total, the changes to stamp duty that we are considering raised around £1.18 billion for the exchequer, or slightly less than £1 per household per week on average. Allocating the stamp duty payment in line with the values of homes owned at different points in the income distribution in our sample, we find that approximately £825 million of the increase would be paid by the richest 30% of the population. Of this, almost £450 million would be allocated to the richest tenth. This implies households in the richest tenth paying extra tax worth approximately £3.50 per week (or 0.4% of their income), on average, due to these stamp duty reforms. This is small compared with net losses of around £28 per week (or 3% of income) that we estimated to be taken, on average, from those in the richest income group by the package of reforms considered in Section 9.2. Figure 9.3. Impact of direct personal tax, benefit and expenditure tax changes since 1997, with and without effect of stamp duty Percentage change in income 20 No stamp duty 15 With stamp duty 10 5 0 -5 Poorest 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Richest Decile Notes: See Figure 9.1. Source: Authors’ calculations using the British Household Panel Survey for 2000 and results from the IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, run using Family Resources Survey 2000–01 and Family Expenditure Survey 1999–2000. The effect of stamp duty is small relative to the package considered in Section 9.2. Figure 9.3 shows that it also does not affect the progressive shape of the results we found there. The figure reproduces the results of Figure 9.1 and compares them with a set of results that include the distributional effects of stamp duty as modelled here. If anything, the stamp duty reform tends to add 23 There were actually 187 households with homes worth more than £250,000, but only 15 of these homes were valued at more than £500,000. We do use information on whether or not a home falls into the top stamp-duty band when calculating how much extra tax households in each decile would pay. 127 Green Budget, January 2003 to the progressive shape of the package since, as modelled (and with the exception of a relatively large proportionate income loss in the poorest tenth), it tends to take proportionally slightly more from those in higher income deciles. Raising money from stamp duties is certainly progressive in the sense that it takes the largest cash amounts from people towards the top of the income distribution. 9.6 Conclusion In this chapter, we have looked at the distributional impact of reforms to taxes and benefits that have been implemented since 1997. Amongst the reforms we model in Section 9.2, the pattern has generally been progressive. Many of the reforms that we do not model are tax increases. This means that if we could include the distributional impact of all these reforms, we would be assessing a package that is less generous to households than the package considered in Section 9.2. We have seen that attempting to model the reforms that were omitted raises a series of difficult conceptual questions and problems of data availability. Some of the taxes that are omitted are levied on incomes derived from company profits or from owning property. It is likely that the payment of these taxes falls relatively heavily on those high up the income distribution, and so it seems safe to assume that, in a more comprehensive distributional analysis, the progressive nature of the package of reforms made since 1997 would not be compromised. Stephen Bond and Matthew Wakefield 128 Appendix A: Forecasting public finances This appendix describes the techniques used for our public finance forecasts. It starts by comparing the forecasts made for borrowing in 2001–02 in last year’s Green Budget and the November 2001 Pre-Budget Report with the eventual out-turn. It then goes on to provide more background information to the shortterm and medium-term public finance forecasts that are set out in Chapter 3. A.1 The accuracy of our previous forecasts The November 2002 Pre-Budget Report1 gave an out-turn figure for a balance of £0.0 billion on public sector net borrowing in 2001–02 (excluding spending associated with the windfall tax). This was almost exactly halfway between the £1.4 billion deficit expected by the Treasury in the November 2001 PreBudget Report2 and the £1.6 billion surplus forecast in the January 2002 IFS Green Budget.3 Table A.1 shows both forecasts alongside the estimated outturn for 2001–02 from the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report.4 Both the Treasury and IFS forecast higher current receipts than were realised. Both of these forecasts for receipts were reasonably accurate, being within 1% of the final out-turn. Table A.2 shows the breakdown of both the Treasury’s and IFS’s main errors in forecasting tax receipts for 2001–02. Although the overall effect was an overestimate of receipts, both sets of predictions underestimated both income tax and council tax, with income tax presenting the greatest deviation in any direction. The November 2001 Pre-Budget Report underestimated income tax receipts by £6.0 billion, while the IFS forecast was £4.6 billion too low. The most significant overestimates were for corporation tax and social security 1 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). 2 HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2001, London, 2001 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr01/prebud_pbr01_index.cfm). 3 A. Dilnot, C. Emmerson and H. Simpson (eds), The IFS Green Budget: January 2002, Commentary no. 87, Institute for Fiscal Studies, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/gbfiles/gb2002.shtml). 4 More recent information on the out-turn for 2001–02 suggests that current receipts were £390.4 billion, that total managed expenditure was £389.7 billion and that therefore there was a surplus on public sector net borrowing (including spending associated with the windfall tax) of £0.7 billion. This suggests that receipts were closer to the Treasury forecast, and that spending and public sector net borrowing were closer to the January 2002 IFS Green Budget forecast, than is suggested by the PBR out-turn figures discussed here. Source: Office for National Statistics Press Release, ‘Public Sector Accounts: 3rd Quarter 2002’, 23 December 2002 (www.statistics.gov.uk/pdfdir/psa1202.pdf). In this appendix, we examine the PBR outturn rather than the latest available figures since no breakdown by type of expenditure or tax is currently available for the latest figures. 129 Green Budget, January 2003 contributions. The November 2001 Pre-Budget Report overestimated their yields by £0.9 billion and £1.1 billion respectively, while the IFS forecasts were £0.9 billion and £0.3 billion too high respectively. Table A.1. A comparison of last year’s IFS Green Budget forecast and the Treasury November 2001 Pre-Budget Report forecast with the estimated out-turn for 2001–02 from the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report (£ billion) HM Treasury Pre-Budget Report forecast, November 2001 391.2 393.7 IFS Green Budget forecast, January 2002 Current receipts Total managed expenditure Of which: Departmental expenditure limits 212.5 Annually managed expenditure 181.1 PSNBa 1.4 a PSNB excludes spending financed by the windfall tax. 391.4 391.1 Estimate, Pre-Budget Report, November 2002 390.7 391.8 210.0 181.1 –1.6 212.1 179.7 0.0 Table A.2. IFS Green Budget and Treasury main errors in forecasting tax receipts, 2001–02 (£ billion) Pre-Budget Report forecast, November 2001 –6.0 0.9 0.3 0.3 1.1 –0.5 4.4 0.5 IFS Green Budget forecast, January 2002 –4.6 0.9 0.3 0.2 0.3 –0.5 4.1 0.7 Income taxa Corporation tax Value added tax Fuel duties Social security contributions Council tax Other taxes and receipts Total a Net of tax credits. Source: Out-turn figures for 2001–02 from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). A.2 Techniques used in our forecasts For the current financial year, three different sources of information are examined before coming to a judgement for each element of government revenue. In addition to the latest Treasury forecast from the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report, we use information from the revenues implied by a current receipts method, and the IFS modelled approach.5 5 For a more detailed explanation of both these techniques, see C. Giles and J. Hall, ‘Forecasting the PSBR outside government: the IFS perspective’, Fiscal Studies, 1998, vol. 19, pp. 83–100. 130 Appendix A 1. Information from current receipts. The current receipts method uses the information on receipts received in the current financial year compared with those received up to the same point in the previous financial year. An estimate for the current year’s receipts is then calculated using the following formula: 2002–03 forecast = Receipts received so far this year × 2001–02 receipts. Receipts received to the same point last year While this is useful when forecasting revenues in the current financial year, it cannot provide projections for borrowing in future years. Also, caution should be used when revenues are cyclical or changes have been made that may affect the timing of payments – for example, the effect of moving to a quarterly system of corporation tax payments. 2. The IFS modelled receipts approach. This estimates growth in each of the taxes using forecasts for the growth in the tax base relevant to each tax, combined with an estimate of the elasticity of revenue with respect to the growth in the tax base. Information on the revenue effects of preannounced tax changes from previous Budgets is then added in order to reach a forecast. Hence, modelled receipts can be summarised by the following formula: 2002–03 forecast = (2001–02 receipts × Tax-base change × Elasticity) + Tax changes. This technique enables forecasts to be made for future years, given the expected structure of the tax system. It should be noted that these forecasts become considerably less accurate for later years, since forecasts for changes in tax bases, estimates of elasticities and the impact of tax changes all become less accurate. The elasticities are largely estimated from TAXBEN, the IFS tax and benefit model. The estimates for income tax elasticities are supplemented by a model of the responsiveness of income tax revenues to changes in employment and wages. For fuel, an elasticity calculated from previous IFS research is used.6 Elasticities for beer, spirit, wine and tobacco duties are taken from the median elasticity found in a range of UK studies.7 A.3 Forecasts for 2002–03 The Green Budget forecast is a judgement based on the Treasury’s latest forecast contained in the November 2002 Pre-Budget Report, the current receipts method and the IFS modelled approach. Each of these is presented in Table A.3. Overall, we expect lower receipts than the Treasury, leading to higher borrowing and a larger deficit on current budget. 6 L. Blow and I. Crawford, The Distributional Effects of Taxes on Private Motoring, Commentary no. 65, IFS, London, 1997. 7 M. Chambers, ‘Consumers’ demand and excise duty receipts equations for alcohol, tobacco, petrol and derv’, Government Economic Service, Working Paper no. 138, August 1999. 131 Green Budget, January 2003 Table A.3. Forecasts for government borrowing in 2002–03 (£ billion) Pre-Budget Report Nov. 2002 Current receipts IFS forecasting model IFS forecast judgement Inland Revenue Income tax (gross of tax credits) 114.1 111.9h,i 111.9h 110.0h a h h Corporation tax (CT) 29.3 28.3 33.4 28.5h b Tax credits –3.5 n/a n/a n/a Petroleum revenue tax 1.1 0.8 1.3 1.1 Capital gains tax 2.0 n/a 3.1 2.0 Inheritance tax 2.4 2.4 2.4 2.4 Stamp duties 8.2 7.6 7.6 7.8 Social security contributions 65.5 63.9 64.9 65.0 Total Inland Revenue (net of tax credits) 219.1 214.9 224.5 216.8 Customs and Excise Value added tax (VAT) 64.5 63.7 64.5 63.7 Fuel duties 22.4 22.2 22.5 22.4 Tobacco duties 8.2 8.4 8.1 8.2 Spirit duties 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.2 Wine duties 1.9 2.0 2.1 1.9 Beer and cider duties 3.1 3.2 3.2 3.1 Betting and gaming duties 1.3 1.2 1.4 1.3 Air passenger duty 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.8 Insurance premium tax 2.1 2.2 2.0 2.1 Landfill tax 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.5 Climate change levy 0.9 0.9 0.9 0.9 Aggregates levy 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 Customs duties and levies 2.0 1.9 2.0 2.0 Total Customs and Excise 110.1 109.4 110.5 109.3 Vehicle excise duties 4.4 4.4 4.3 4.4 Oil royalties 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 Business ratesc 18.0 18.0 18.3 18.0 Council tax 16.6 16.6 16.0 16.6 Other taxes and royaltiesd 10.9 10.9 10.4 10.9 Total taxes and social security contribnse 379.6 374.8 384.5 376.5 Accruals adjustments on taxes –0.6 –0.6 –0.6 –0.6 Less Own resources contribution to EU –3.0 –3.0 –3.0 –3.0 Less Public corporations’ CT payments –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 –0.2 Tax creditsf 1.2 1.2 1.2 1.2 Interest and dividends 4.1 4.1 4.1 4.1 Other receipts 18.6 18.6 18.6 18.6 Current receipts 399.7 394.9 404.6 396.6 Current spending 405.5 405.4 405.4 405.4 Current balanceg –5.7 –10.6 –0.8 –8.8 Net investment 14.3 13.3 13.3 13.3 Public sector net borrowingg 20.1 23.9 14.1 22.1 a National accounts measure: gross of enhanced and payable tax credits. b Includes enhanced and payable company tax credits. c Includes district council rates in Northern Ireland. d Includes money paid into the National Lottery Distribution Fund. e Includes VAT and ‘traditional own resources’ contributions to EC budget. Cash basis. f Excludes children’s tax credit and other tax credits that score as a tax repayment in the National Accounts. g Includes expenditure associated with the windfall tax. h Net of tax credits. i Includes capital gains tax. Sources: Treasury forecasts from HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm) – this table is similar to table B12 on page 197); information on current receipts from ONS / HM Treasury, ‘Public Sector Finances: December 2002’, Press Release, 21 January 2003 (www.statistics.gov.uk/pdfdir/psf0103.pdf); IFS calculations. 132 Appendix A Inland Revenue receipts For income tax (net of tax credits), we forecast £110.0 billion, which is lower than the PBR forecast, since the Treasury forecasts gross receipts of £114.1 billion with tax credits accounting for around £3 billion. Our estimate takes into account the fact that the current receipts estimate is for £109.9 billion (assuming capital gains tax of £2.0 billion), but allows for a slight improvement in the strength of income tax receipts towards the end of the financial year. Our forecast for corporation tax is £28.5 billion, which is £0.8 billion below the Treasury forecast of £29.3 billion. This is due to the current receipts forecast suggesting that receipts will be just £28.3 billion. No weight is given to the IFS modelled forecast since this does not take into account any decline in company profits associated with the fall in the stock market. While the current receipts forecast for corporate tax receipts has not been useful in the past due to the change in timing of corporation tax receipts, our calculations suggest that this should no longer be a problem, as there is no longer a timingof-receipts issue arising from the transition from the old corporation tax system to the new one. Our forecast for stamp duties is receipts of £7.8 billion this year. This is slightly higher than the current receipts forecast and the IFS modelled forecast, both of which are for £7.6 billion of receipts, but still £0.4 billion below the PBR forecast of £8.2 billion. With social security contributions, we forecast £65.0 billion, which is £0.5 billion below the Treasury’s forecast of £65.5 billion. This is due to evidence from both the IFS forecasting model (£64.9 billion) and the current receipts method (£63.9 billion), which suggests that the Treasury’s forecast might not be met. Customs and Excise taxes We forecast VAT receipts of £63.7 billion, lower than the Treasury’s forecast of £64.5 billion. This is due to the information from current receipts, which suggests revenues will be lower than the Treasury’s forecast. We forecast that fuel duties will yield £22.4 billion, which is the same as the Treasury’s forecast. This is because both current receipts and the IFS forecasting model give very similar forecasts. Other government receipts For all other receipts, we take the Treasury’s forecast. Government expenditure We forecast current spending to equal £405.4 billion, which is just £0.1 billion lower than the Treasury’s forecast. This is because we assume that the £0.1 billion left in the AME (annually managed expenditure) margin from the Pre-Budget Report is not used. We also assume that the special reserve addition of £1 billion, which has been allocated to finance the potential conflict in Iraq, is spent in 2002–03. While some or all of this might be carried forward into 2003–04, the timing of the expenditure will not have any direct 133 Green Budget, January 2003 impact on the public finances or the interpretation of whether the fiscal rules have been breached. Our forecasts allow for a £1 billion underspend on public sector net investment in 2002–03. This is due to the growth in public sector net investment seen so far this year being lower than that forecast by the Treasury for the year as a whole. Government borrowing As a result of lower government revenues (offset very slightly by lower current expenditure), we forecast a deficit on current budget of £8.8 billion for 2002–03. This is some £3.1 billion lower than the £5.7 billion forecast by the Treasury. We forecast that public sector net borrowing will be £22.1 billion, which is £2.0 billion more than the £20.1 billion forecast by the Treasury. A.4 Medium-term forecasts Any assessment of the fiscal stance, and whether the Chancellor is going to be successful in meeting his two fiscal ‘rules’, should be judged over the economic cycle. Table A.4 presents the macroeconomic forecasts underlying the baseline IFS forecast for government borrowing. For our central forecast, we use the Treasury’s ‘cautious’ forecast for GDP growth of 2% in 2002–03, 2¾% in 2003–04, 3% in 2004–05 and 2¾% in 2005–06. In 2006–07 and 2007–08, we expect growth to be in line with the Treasury’s lower-bound forecast for trend growth in those years of 2½% and 2¼% respectively. Table A.4. Main macroeconomic assumptions used in the baseline forecast (% growth in variable) 2002–03 2003–04 2004–05 2005–06 2006–07 2007–08 Gross domestic product (GDP) 2 2¾ 3 2¾ 2½ 2¼ Real consumers’ expenditure 3¼ 2½ 2¾ 2¼ 2¼ 2 Employment 0 ¼ ¼ ¼ ¼ ¼ Real wages 2 2½ 2¾ 2½ 2¼ 2 GDP deflator 2½ 2¼ 2½ 2½ 2½ 2½ Sources: GDP forecasts and GDP deflator from table B3 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, Cm. 5664, London, 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/pre_budget_report/prebud_pbr02/prebud_pbr02_index.cfm). Consumers’ expenditure based on table A8 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002, until 2004–05; following GDP growth thereafter. Employment growth: IFS estimates consistent with table A3 of HM Treasury, Pre-Budget Report 2002. Real wages growth: IFS estimates based on GDP growth. The IFS model also requires forecasts for growth in consumers’ expenditure, employment and wages. These are set out in Table A.4 too. Where possible, published Treasury forecasts are used. The model also requires a forecast of growth in corporate profits. Due to the difficulties in forecasting this, particularly in the present climate, we instead assume that, in the medium term, corporation tax receipts rise back to the average level seen in recent years. 134 Appendix B: Distributional effects of pre-announced direct tax and benefit reforms due in 2003–04 This appendix considers the distributional impact of reforms to direct taxes and benefits that were announced in Pre-Budget Report 2001 and Budget 2002 but that do not take effect until 2003–04. The fact that these reforms will have a significant effect on the incomes of many families at the beginning of the new financial year in April (with further changes affecting those aged 65 or over in October) will doubtless be in the Chancellor’s mind as he decides what measures to announce in Budget 2003 and when they should take effect. Our analysis shows that just over 60% of the money raised by the tax rises due in the coming financial year will be offset by extra spending on benefits and tax credits, leaving a net increase in personal taxes less benefits of around £3 billion a year.1 On average, those aged 60 or over gain from the increases in the minimum income guarantee (MIG), the basic state pension and the pension credit and they pay little extra tax. Families without children pay more tax with few compensating gains, while families with children lie somewhere in between. The overall impact will be progressive, with families gaining, on average, at the bottom of the income distribution and losing, on average, at the top. This is in line with the impact of Labour’s other changes to direct taxes and benefits since 1997.2 B.1 What reforms do we consider? The complete list of tax and benefit reforms taking effect in 2003–04 can be derived from the 2002 Budget.3 Those considered in this analysis are listed below. All are effective from April 2003, except the pension credit.4 1 All figures in this appendix are in 2002 prices. Our estimates are that the tax rises will raise £7.9 billion, that the benefit and credit changes in April 2003 will cost £3.8 billion and that the pension credit will have a full-year cost of £2.1 billion. However, the pension credit starts in October 2003, halving its estimated cost in 2003–04; if we counted the full-year cost of the pension credit, then the changes in 2003–04 would only raise £2 billion. 2 See Chapter 9. 3 Chapter A of HM Treasury, Financial Statement and Budget Report, HC592, Stationery Office, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/budget/bud_index.cfm). Benefit rates taking effect from April 2003 were confirmed in Department for Work and Pensions, ‘Pensioners and New Mothers Set to Gain from Cash Gains’, Press Release, 18 November 2002, www.dwp.gov.uk/mediacentre/pressreleases/2002/nov/cfd1811-uprt.htm. 4 There are other, more minor, changes to benefits and personal taxes due which are not considered in our model, such as increases in statutory maternity pay and the maternity allowance. Taxes and benefits that have been increased in line with inflation do not count as changes. Chapter 5 analyses the changes to National Insurance; HM Treasury, The Child and 135 Green Budget, January 2003 • A freeze in the personal allowance for income tax for those aged under 65, equivalent to a real reduction of 1.7%.5 • A freeze in the thresholds beyond which employers, employees and the self-employed pay National Insurance (NI) contributions, again equivalent to a real reduction of 1.7%. • A 1 percentage point increase in employee NI contributions, paid on all earnings above the primary threshold. • A 1 percentage point increase in employer NI contributions, paid on all earnings above the secondary threshold. • A 1 percentage point increase in self-employed NI contributions, paid on all profits above the lower profits limit. • Overindexation of the personal allowance for those aged 65 or over. • Introduction of the child tax credit and the working tax credit, and abolition of the children’s tax credit and the working families’ tax credit.6 • Abolition of child dependency increases in non-means-tested benefits.7 • An above-inflation increase in the basic state pension for pensioners (and linked benefits), and an increase in the MIG for those aged 60 or over. • Introduction of the pension credit for those aged 65 or over (October 2003). B.2 Distributional impacts of the reforms In the tables in this appendix, we show the distributional impacts of the following: Working Tax Credits, The Modernisation of Britain’s Tax and Benefit System no. 10, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/new_tax_credits.pdf), explains how the new tax credits will work; Department for Work and Pensions, Pension Credit: The Government’s Proposals, London, 2001 (www.dwp.gov.uk/publications/dwp/2001/pencred/pencred.pdf), and T. Clark, Rewarding Saving and Alleviating Poverty? The Final Pension Credit Proposals, Briefing Note no. 22, IFS, London, 2002 (www.ifs.org.uk/pensions/bn22.pdf), explain the details of the pension credit; for details of all benefit rates from April 2003, see Department for Work and Pensions, ‘Pensioners and New Mothers Set to Gain from Cash Gains’, Press Release, 18 November 2002, www.dwp.gov.uk/mediacentre/pressreleases/2002/nov/cfd1811-uprt.htm. 5 1.7% was the headline rate of inflation (RPI) in September 2002, which is the rate usually used to adjust tax allowances and thresholds. 6 Families with children on income support will not be affected by the child tax credit until April 2004: see Chapter 4. 7 This reform only applies to new claimants, but we model the long-run impact of this change by abolishing the increases for existing claimants. 136 Appendix B (1) the direct tax rises that take effect in April 2003 (i.e. the freeze in income tax personal allowances, the rises in NI rates and the freeze in the thresholds for NI); (2) all reforms that take effect in April 2003 (i.e. the tax rises in (1), plus the increases in benefits and tax credits other than the pension credit); (3) all reforms that take effect in 2003–04 (i.e. the tax rises in (1), plus the benefit and tax credit increases in (2), plus the new pension credit). In line with usual practice, we assume that the increase in NI paid by employers is passed on to the employee in the form of lower earnings, and that it therefore has the same impact as a rise in employee NI.8 But in some tables, we show separately the impact of the rise in employer NI rates and the freezing of the secondary threshold, in case readers wish to subtract it. Tables B.1 and B.2 show the average impact on each decile of the population, as a proportion of disposable income and in cash terms.9 Tables B.3 and B.4 show the average impact on a number of different family types. Table B.5 shows how many families gain and lose from the reforms. Tables B.1 and B.2 show the following: • The tax rises are progressive: the rich, on average, lose a greater proportion of their income than the poor. • Just under half the approximately £8 billion raised by the NI and income tax increases is offset by the extra spending on benefits and tax credits in April 2003, rising to over 60% once the pension credit is included. • In the top two income deciles, the change in employer NI accounts for around half of the average loss. • All but the richest tenth of families will see noticeable average gains from the new tax credits and other benefit changes, but the impact is greater in the lower income deciles. • The combined impact of a tax rise that hurts the rich more than the poor, and new credits that benefit the poor more than the rich, is clearly progressive. This is in keeping with the distributional impact of personal tax and benefit changes since 1997.10 On average, the bottom five deciles gain and the top five deciles lose, with decile 2 gaining the most.11 8 This assumption is discussed in more detail in Chapter 9. 9 Gains and losses are shown per week; the difference between full-year and part-year changes discussed in footnote 1 is therefore not an issue. See Table B.6 for the income bands corresponding to each decile. 10 See figure 3 in M. Brewer, T. Clark and M. Wakefield, ‘Social security in the UK under New Labour: what did the third way mean for welfare reform?’, Fiscal Studies, 2002, vol. 23, pp. 505–37. 11 If we do not consider the impact of raising employer NI, the bottom six income deciles gain on average and the top four deciles lose on average. 137 Green Budget, January 2003 Table B.1. Percentage gains across the income distribution from reforms in 2003–04 Direct tax All changes in All changes in Employer NI changes in April 2003 2003–04 only April 2003 Poorest –0.08 3.43 3.94 –0.02 Decile 2 –0.14 3.24 5.62 –0.06 Decile 3 –0.43 2.65 4.08 –0.22 Decile 4 –0.73 1.32 2.52 –0.35 Decile 5 –1.04 –0.02 0.79 –0.50 Decile 6 –1.38 –0.71 –0.23 –0.67 Decile 7 –1.58 –1.11 –0.87 –0.77 Decile 8 –1.89 –1.60 –1.55 –0.94 Decile 9 –2.10 –1.99 –1.98 –1.06 Richest –2.35 –2.35 –2.35 –1.13 –1.62 –0.84 –0.42 –0.78 Overall Notes: The first three columns include the effects of employer NI; this is given separately in the final column and can be subtracted if required. Income deciles are derived by dividing all families (with and without children) into 10 equally sized groups according to income adjusted for family size using the McClements equivalence scale. Decile 1 contains the poorest tenth of the population, decile 2 the second poorest and so on, up to decile 10, which contains the richest tenth. Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. Table B.2. Weekly cash gains across the income distribution from reforms in 2003–04 (2002 prices) Direct tax changes in April 2003 Poorest –0.06 Decile 2 –0.21 Decile 3 –0.77 Decile 4 –1.48 Decile 5 –2.41 Decile 6 –3.71 Decile 7 –4.97 Decile 8 –7.10 Decile 9 –9.78 Richest –19.95 –5.04 Overall Notes: As for Table B.1. Source: As for Table B.1. All changes in April 2003 All changes in 2003–04 Employer NI only 2.46 4.77 4.82 2.68 –0.05 –1.92 –3.47 –6.03 –9.27 –19.96 –2.60 2.83 8.28 7.40 5.12 1.82 –0.63 –2.74 –5.82 –9.23 –19.95 –1.29 –0.01 –0.09 –0.40 –0.69 –1.09 –1.68 –2.25 –3.26 –4.49 –8.53 –2.25 Tables B.3 and B.4 show the following: • On average, families with someone in work are net losers, with pensioners and those not working gaining. • On average, families with children fare better than those without. For example, single-earner couples with children will lose an average of £9.81 a week from the tax rises, but gain an average of £6.70 a week from the new tax credits. This will leave them an average of £3.11 a week worse off, compared with an average loss of £4.33 for single-earner couples without children, who tend to gain less from the new tax credits. 138 Appendix B Table B.3. Percentage gains from reforms in 2003–04, by family type Direct tax All changes in All changes in Employer NI changes in April 2003 2003–04 only April 2003 Single, not working –0.05 0.08 0.14 0.00 Single, employed –2.25 –1.89 –1.89 –1.14 Single-parent family –0.61 4.14 4.15 –0.33 0-earner couple w/o kids –0.10 0.27 0.69 –0.01 0-earner couple with kids –0.03 5.16 5.19 0.00 1-earner couple w/o kids –1.87 –1.21 –1.18 –0.90 1-earner couple with kids –2.06 –0.65 –0.65 –1.01 2-earner couple w/o kids –2.32 –2.24 –2.24 –1.13 2-earner couple with kids –2.22 –1.64 –1.64 –1.10 Single pensioner –0.03 1.06 3.99 –0.02 Couple pensioner –0.09 0.67 2.59 –0.05 –1.62 –0.84 –0.42 –0.78 Overall Notes: The first three columns include the effects of employer NI; this is given separately in the final column and can be subtracted if required. Families are classified as pensioners if either adult is a pensioner (male: 65 or over; female: 60 or over). Some of these families also contain children; some male recipients of the MIG can therefore be found in non-pensioner families. See Table B.7 for the number of families of each type. Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. Table B.4. Weekly cash gains from reforms in 2003–04, by family type (2002 prices) Direct tax changes in April 2003 Single, not working –0.04 Single, employed –5.29 Single-parent family –1.46 0-earner couple w/o kids –0.25 0-earner couple with kids –0.07 1-earner couple w/o kids –6.86 1-earner couple with kids –9.81 2-earner couple w/o kids –12.55 2-earner couple with kids –12.53 Single pensioner –0.06 Couple pensioner –0.27 –5.04 Overall Notes: As for Table B.3. Source: As for Table B.3. All changes in April 2003 All changes in 2003–04 Employer NI only 0.08 –4.45 9.91 0.70 13.90 –4.45 –3.11 –12.15 –9.26 1.88 2.12 –2.60 0.13 –4.44 9.94 1.78 13.98 –4.33 –3.11 –12.12 –9.26 7.07 8.24 –1.29 0.00 –2.41 –0.77 –0.02 0.00 –3.00 –4.33 –5.51 –5.59 –0.03 –0.15 –2.25 Table B.5 shows the following: • The new tax credits sharply reduce the number of lone parents who would otherwise have suffered significant income losses as a result of the tax increases – the number of lone parents more than £1 a week worse off falls from 540,000 to 130,000, and 1.6 million will be net gainers. The number of couples with children losing more than £1 a week is reduced proportionately less by the tax credits – from 4.5 million to 3.4 million – with 1.6 million couples with children ending up net gainers. 139 Green Budget, January 2003 Table B.5. Numbers of winners and losers, by family type Number of families (thousands) Single, no children losing >£10 per week losing £1–£10 per week staying within +/–£1 gaining £1–£10 per week gaining >£10 per week Direct tax changes in April 2003 All changes in April 2003 All changes in 2003–04 725 5,335 4,294 0 0 725 5,061 4,138 233 197 725 5,055 4,132 238 203 Single with children losing >£10 per week losing £1–£10 per week staying within +/–£1 gaining £1–£10 per week gaining >£10 per week 36 507 1,239 0 0 26 103 37 1,052 565 26 103 37 1,050 567 Couple, no children losing >£10 per week losing £1–£10 per week staying within +/–£1 gaining £1–£10 per week gaining >£10 per week 2,093 2,748 1,215 0 0 2,085 2,547 997 283 145 2,085 2,543 953 296 179 Couple with children losing >£10 per week losing £1–£10 per week staying within +/–£1 gaining £1–£10 per week gaining >£10 per week 2,121 2,332 728 0 0 1,817 1,608 138 935 684 1,817 1,608 138 934 685 Pensioners losing >£10 per week 8 7 losing £1–£10 per week 190 109 staying within +/–£1 6,622 635 gaining £1–£10 per week 0 6,055 gaining >£10 per week 0 15 Total losing >£10 per week 4,984 4,661 losing £1–£10 per week 11,113 9,427 staying within +/–£1 14,098 5,943 gaining £1–£10 per week 0 8,559 gaining >£10 per week 0 1,608 Notes: As for Table B.3. Totals may not sum due to rounding. Source: As for Table B.3. • 7 109 501 4,139 2,065 4,661 9,418 5,760 6,658 3,700 Of the 1.6 million lone parents who gain overall from the changes, 1.2 million earn too little to be affected by the tax rises. Amongst the 1.6 million couples with children who gain overall from the changes, between 0.6 million and 0.7 million earn too little to be affected by the tax rises. This means that just over a fifth of couples with children affected by the tax rises will gain more in tax credits than they lose in extra tax payments. 140 Appendix B • Around 90% of pensioner families (6 million) will gain by at least £1 a week from the pension credit and the overindexation of the state pension and income tax allowance. • A small number of working-age families without children – mostly older workers – gain from the introduction of the new working tax credit, with around 380,000 gaining more than £10 a week. • Across the whole population, around 16 million families will lose by £1 a week or more from the tax rises due in April 2003. Accounting for all the changes due in 2003–04, around 14 million families will lose by £1 a week or more, and 10 million families will gain by £1 a week or more, with 6 million families relatively unaffected. Of the 10 million families that gain, at least 8 million (mostly pensioners) are unaffected by the tax rises; this again shows that the changes to benefits and credits are playing a small role in compensating families that will be paying more tax. Table B.6. Income bands for each decile for different family types (net household income in £ per year, 2002 prices, after direct taxes and benefits) Single, no children Couple, no children Couple, two children Poorest 0–5,400 0–8,800 0–12,600 Decile 2 5,400–6,500 8,800–10,700 12,600–15,300 Decile 3 6,500–7,600 10,700–12,500 15,300–17,900 Decile 4 7,600–8,800 12,500–14,400 17,900–20,600 Decile 5 8,800–10,100 14,400–16,600 20,600–23,700 Decile 6 10,100–11,700 16,600–19,100 23,700–27,300 Decile 7 11,700–13,500 19,100–22,200 27,300–31,800 Decile 8 13,500–16,100 22,200–26,400 31,800–37,800 Decile 9 16,100–20,400 26,400–33,400 37,800–47,800 Richest 20,400– 33,400– 47,800– Note: There are 3,020,000 families in each decile. Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. Table B.7. Estimated number of families in Great Britain, by family type Number of families (millions) Single, not working 3.3 Single, employed 7.1 Single-parent family (working or not working) 1.8 0-earner couple w/o kids 0.9 0-earner couple with kids 0.4 1-earner couple w/o kids 1.6 1-earner couple with kids 1.6 2-earner couple w/o kids 3.5 2-earner couple with kids 3.2 Single pensioner 4.2 Couple pensioner 2.7 Total 30.2 Source: IFS tax and benefit model, TAXBEN, based on 2000–01 Family Resources Survey. 141 Appendix C: Budgets since 1979 This appendix summarises the main tax measures introduced in each Budget since 1979. Statutory indexation of thresholds and limits is not included. 1979 Budget, Geoffrey Howe Income tax Basic rate cut from 33% to 30%. Top rate cut from 83% to 60% on earned income and from 98% to 75% on unearned income. VAT Two-tier rates of 8% and 12.5% replaced by single 15% rate. Excise duties Alcohol and tobacco duties reduced; petrol duty increased. Company taxes Petroleum revenue tax rate increased from 45% to 60%. 1980 Budget, Geoffrey Howe Income tax Reduced rate of 25% abolished. National Insurance Employee rate increased from 6.5% to 6.75% (contracted in). Employer rate increased from 10% to 10.2% (contracted in). Capital taxes Stamp duty threshold on property increased from £15,000 to £20,000. Capital transfer tax threshold doubled from £25,000 to £50,000. Company taxes Petroleum revenue tax rate increased from 60% to 70%. 1981 Budget, Geoffrey Howe Income tax Personal allowances frozen in cash terms, implying a cut in real terms. National Insurance Employee rate increased from 6.75% to 7.75% (contracted in). Excise duties Sharp increases (beer and petrol up 24%, cigarettes up 16%). 1982 Budget, Geoffrey Howe Income tax Personal allowances increased in real terms. National Insurance Employee rate increased from 7.75% to 8.75% (contracted in). Employer National Insurance surcharge reduced from 3.5% to 2%, and to 1.5% from April 1983. Capital taxes Indexation provisions introduced for capital gains tax. Stamp duty threshold on property increased from £20,000 to £25,000. Company taxes Petroleum revenue tax rate increased from 70% to 75%. 1983 Budget, Geoffrey Howe Income tax Personal allowances increased in real terms. Mortgage interest relief ceiling raised from £25,000 to £30,000. National Insurance Employee rate increased from 8.75% to 9% (contracted in). Employer National Insurance surcharge cut from 1.5% to 1%. Company taxes Licence royalties abolished for all new oilfields. 1984 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Personal allowances increased in real terms. Investment income surcharge abolished. Relief on life assurance premiums abolished for new policies. National Insurance Employer National Insurance surcharge abolished. Excise duties Duty on wine cut sharply; increases on beer and cigarettes. Capital taxes Stamp duty threshold on property increased from £25,000 to £30,000. Highest rate of stamp duty reduced from 2% to 1%. Top rate of capital transfer tax cut from 75% to 60%. Company taxes Corporation tax rate to be reduced from 52% in 1982–83 to 50% in 1983–84, 45% in 1984–85, 40% in 1985–86 and 35% in 1986–87. Stock relief abolished. First-year allowances to be phased out and replaced by 25% writing-down allowances. 142 Appendix C 1985 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Personal allowances increased in real terms. National Insurance Employee and employer contributions restructured, with reduced rates for lower earners. Upper ceiling on employer contributions abolished. Company taxes Development land tax abolished. 1986 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Basic rate reduced from 30% to 29%. Announcement of the introduction of tax relief for profit-related pay (PRP) schemes in 1987. Tax relief for Personal Equity Plans (PEPs) introduced. Capital taxes Capital transfer tax replaced with inheritance tax. Stamp duty for shares reduced from 1% to 0.5%. 1987 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Basic rate reduced from 29% to 27%. Excise duties Duties held constant in cash terms, implying a real cut. Capital taxes Inheritance tax threshold increased from £71,000 to £90,000. Number of inheritance tax rates cut from seven to four. New arrangements to encourage personal pensions. 1988 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Personal allowances increased in real terms. Basic rate reduced from 27% to 25%. All rates above 40% abolished. Announcement of separate taxation of husband and wife from 1990. Company car scale charges doubled. Capital taxes Capital gains accruing before 1982 written off for capital gains tax purposes. Capital gains tax rates changed to equal marginal income tax rates. Inheritance tax threshold increased from £90,000 to £110,000. Inheritance tax rates reduced to a single rate of 40%. 1989 Budget, Nigel Lawson Income tax Limit for higher age relief reduced to 75. Age allowance taper reduced to 50%. Pensioner ‘earnings rule’ abolished. PEPs extended. National Insurance Employee 5% and 7% bands abolished. Lower 2% rate for employees introduced on earnings below lower earnings limit. Excise duties Petrol duties adjusted to favour unleaded fuel. 1990 Budget, John Major Income tax Basic-rate limit frozen. Employer-provided work-place nurseries exempted from tax. Introduction of Tax-Exempt Special Savings Accounts (TESSAs). Abolition of composite rate of tax announced. Capital taxes Plans for abolition of stamp duty on shares announced. Company taxes Corporation tax rate cut from 35% to 34%. 1991 Budget, Norman Lamont Income tax Married couple’s allowance frozen. Mortgage interest relief restricted to the basic rate of tax. PEPs extended. Company car scale charges raised by 20%. National Insurance Employer contributions to be charged on company cars and free fuel from 1992–93. VAT Standard rate of VAT raised from 15% to 17.5%. Company taxes Corporation tax rate cut from 34% to 33%. 143 Green Budget, January 2003 Local taxes Community charge bills subsidised by £140 per adult. 1992 Budget, Norman Lamont Income tax Reduced rate of 20% introduced on first £2,000 of taxable income. Married couple’s allowance frozen. Basic-rate limit frozen. PEPs limit on investment and unit trusts raised from £3,000 to the overall limit, £6,000. Excise duties Further widening in leaded–unleaded petrol duty differential. Car tax halved from 10% to 5% and abolished from November 1992. 1993 Spring Budget, Norman Lamont Income tax 20% band widened to £3,000 by April 1994. Personal allowances and basic-rate limit frozen. Married couple’s allowance and mortgage interest relief restricted to 20% from April 1994. National Insurance Contribution rates for employees and self-employed up 1 percentage point from April 1994. VAT Extended to domestic fuel at 8% from April 1994 and at 17.5% from April 1995. Excise duties Duties increased above inflation, except spirits (frozen). Announced commitment to increase duties on road fuel by at least 3% p.a. in real terms. Capital taxes Stamp duty threshold doubled to £60,000. Company taxes Advance corporation tax (ACT) rate reduced to 22.5% from April 1993 and to 20% from April 1994. Dividend ‘tax credit’ down to 20%. Basic rate of tax on dividends reduced to 20%. Local taxes Community charge abolished, council tax introduced. 1993 Autumn Budget, Kenneth Clarke Income tax Personal allowances and basic-rate limit frozen. Married couple’s allowance and mortgage interest relief restricted to 15% from April 1995. National Insurance Main rate for employer contributions reduced by 0.2 of a percentage point to 10.2%. Lower rates of employer contributions reduced by 1 percentage point. Excise duties No increase on spirits and beer. Most other duties increased above indexation. Commitment to raise tobacco duties by at least 3% p.a. in real terms. Commitment to raise road fuel duties by at least 3% p.a. in real terms increased to 5% p.a. in real terms. Insurance premium tax and air passenger duty introduced. 1994 Budget, Kenneth Clarke Income tax All age-related personal allowances increased above inflation. VAT Abandonment of second stage of VAT on domestic fuel – rate to stay at 8%. Excise duties Alcohol duties raised by an average of 4%. Tobacco duties increased by more than inflation. Duties on road fuel increased above inflation; diesel duties brought in line with duties on unleaded petrol. Other Landfill tax planned for 1996 and businesses to be compensated through lower employer National Insurance contributions. 1995 Budget, Kenneth Clarke Income tax Basic rate of income tax reduced from 25% to 24%. Personal allowances increased above inflation. Lower-rate band and basic-rate limit increased by more than indexation. Tax on savings income cut from 25% to 20% for basic-rate taxpayers. 144 Appendix C National Insurance Excise duties Capital taxes Company taxes Other taxes Tax relief on Class 4 National Insurance contributions withdrawn. Main rate for employers cut from 10.2% to 10% from April 1997. Rate of Class 4 contributions reduced from 7.3% to 6%. Beer, wine and most cider duties frozen; spirits cut by 4%. Most tobacco duties up by 3% in real terms. Petrol and diesel tax (duty and VAT) raised by 3.5p per litre, or 5% real increase. Inheritance tax threshold raised to £200,000, £40,000 more than indexation. Small companies’ rate cut from 25% to 24%. Landfill tax introduced at two rates, of £2 and £7 per tonne. 1996 Budget, Kenneth Clarke Income tax Personal allowances increased by more than inflation. Basic-rate limit and married couple’s allowance indexed. Basic rate cut to 23%. Tax relief for profit-related pay phased out from 1998–99. Excise duties Beer, wine and cider duties frozen; duty on spirits cut by 4%. Air passenger duty doubled, insurance premium tax up to 4%. Tobacco up by 5% in real terms, hand-rolling tobacco indexed. Petrol and diesel up by 5% in real terms. Company taxes Small companies’ rate cut to 23%. Capital allowances cut for long-lived assets. Local taxes Transitional relief for small companies extended. 1997 Summer Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Mortgage interest relief cut to 10% from April 1998. VAT Rate on domestic fuel cut from 8% to 5%. Excise duties Road fuel duties commitment raised from 5% p.a. to 6% p.a. real increase. Tobacco duty commitment raised from 3% p.a. to 5% p.a. real increase. Capital taxes Graduated stamp duty introduced: 1% for properties between £60,000 and £250,000; 1.5% between £250,000 and £500,000; 2% over £500,000. Company taxes Windfall tax on privatised utilities. Main corporation tax rate cut from 33% to 31% from April 1997. Small companies’ rate cut from 23% to 21% from April 1997. Dividend tax credits for pension funds and other companies abolished immediately, for all others from April 1999. 1998 Spring Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Working families’ tax credit from October 1999. Married couple’s allowance restricted to 10% from April 1999. Individual Savings Accounts (ISAs) from April 1999. Tax on company cars increased. National Insurance ‘Entry fee’ abolished for employees from April 1999. Excise duties Differential widened between diesel and unleaded petrol. Capital taxes Personal capital gains tax reformed: indexation abolished and taper introduced. Stamp duty raised to 2% on properties between £250,000 and £500,000, 3% on properties over £500,000. Company taxes ACT abolished from April 1999 and quarterly payments system introduced. Main rate cut to 30%, small companies’ rate to 20% from April 1999. 1999 Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Basic rate cut from 23% to 22% from April 2000. New 10% starting rate from April 1999; 20% rate abolished. Married couple’s allowance abolished from 2000 for under-65s. Children’s tax credit announced from April 2001. Mortgage interest relief abolished from April 2000. High mileage discounts for company cars reduced. 145 Green Budget, January 2003 National Insurance Capital taxes Company taxes Starting point for payment of employee National Insurance contributions aligned with income tax by April 2001. Upper earnings limit raised above inflation in both April 2000 and April 2001. Self-employed structure reformed from April 2000. Employer contributions on all benefits in kind. Employer rate cut by 0.5 of a percentage point from April 2001. Stamp duty raised to 2.5% on properties between £250,000 and £500,000, 3.5% on properties over £500,000. Climate change levy from 2001–02. 2000 Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Working families’ tax credit and child premiums in children’s tax credit increased. National Insurance Employer rate to be cut by 0.3 of a percentage point from April 2001, instead of 0.5 of a percentage point, to reflect reduction in climate change levy. Further cut in employer rate by 0.1 of a percentage point from April 2002, to balance introduction of aggregates levy. Excise duties Road fuel duty frozen in real terms. Cigarettes increased by 5% in real terms. Capital taxes Stamp duty raised to 3% on properties between £250,000 and £500,000, 4% on properties over £500,000. Company taxes Climate change levy cut by £0.7 billion from introduction in April 2001. Aggregates levy introduced from April 2002. 2001 Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Working families’ tax credit and child premiums in children’s tax credit increased. Overindexation of starting-rate band. ISA limit extended to £7,000 p.a. until April 2006. Excise duties Duties for ultra-low sulphur petrol cut by 2p and for ultra-low sulphur diesel cut by 3p. Tobacco duties increased with inflation; alcohol duties frozen. Company taxes Abolition of withholding tax on intra-UK corporate interest. 2002 Budget, Gordon Brown Income tax Child tax credit introduced to replace various income-related payments for children. Working tax credit introduced for both families with and families without children; working families’ tax credit abolished. Personal allowances for those aged under 65 to be frozen in cash terms in April 2003. National Insurance Uncapped 1 percentage point increase in employee, employer and selfemployed rates from April 2003. Primary and secondary thresholds and lower profits limit to be frozen in cash terms in April 2003. Excise duties Fuel duties frozen in cash terms. Company taxes Small companies’ rate cut from 20% to 19%. Starting rate of corporation tax reduced from 10% to 0%. Research and development tax credit introduced for larger companies at 25% rate. Reform to North Sea taxation. 146 Appendix D: Headline tax and benefit rates and thresholds 2002–03 level 2003–04 levela Income tax Personal allowance: under age 65 aged 65–74 aged 75 and over Married couple’s allowance, restricted to 10%: aged 65 or over on 6 April 2000 aged 75 or over Lower rate Basic rate Higher rate Lower-rate limit Basic-rate limit Pension earnings cap Tax rates on interest income Tax rates on dividend income Children’s tax creditb Children’s tax credit for first year of a child’s lifeb £4,615 p.a. £6,100 p.a. £6,370 p.a. £4,615 p.a. £6,610 p.a. £6,720 p.a. £5,465 p.a. £5,535 p.a. 10% 22% 40% £1,920 p.a. £29,900 p.a. £97,200 p.a. 10%, 20%, 40% 10%, 32.5% £5,290 p.a. £10,490 p.a. £5,565 p.a. £5,635 p.a. 10% 22% 40% £1,960 p.a. £30,500 p.a. £98,900 p.a. 10%, 20%, 40% 10%, 32.5% Replaced by child tax credit National Insurance Lower earnings limit (LEL) Upper earnings limit (UEL) Earnings threshold (employee and employer) Class 1 contracted-in rate: employee – below UEL – above UEL employer – below UEL – above UEL Class 1 contracted-out rate: employee – below UEL (salary-related schemes) – above UEL employer – below UEL – above UEL £75 p.w. £585 p.w. £89 p.w. 10% zero 11.8% 11.8% 8.4% zero 8.3% 11.8% £77 p.w. £595 p.w. £89 p.w. 11% 1% 12.8% 12.8% 9.4% 1% 9.3% 12.8% zero 19% 30% zero 19% 30% £7,700 p.a. £3,850 p.a. 24%–40% 12%–20% 10%–40% 5%–20% £7,900 p.a. £3,950 p.a. 24%–40% 12%–20% 10%–40% 5%–20% £250,000 40% £255,000 40% 17.5% 5% 17.5% 5% Corporation tax Rates: lower rate small companies’ rate standard rate Capital gains tax Annual exemption limit: individuals trusts Non-business assets: top-rate taxpayers basic-rate taxpayers Business assets: top-rate taxpayers basic-rate taxpayers Inheritance tax Threshold Rate for transfer at or near death Value added tax Standard rate Reduced rate Continues 147 Green Budget, January 2003 Continued 2002–03 level 2003–04 levela Excise duties Beer (pint) Wine (75cl bottle) Spirits (70cl bottle) 20 cigarettes: specific duty ad valorem (22% of retail price) Ultra-low sulphur petrol (litre) Ultra-low sulphur diesel (litre) 26p 116p 548p 188p 92p 46p 46p 27p 118p 556p 191p 93p 47p 47p Air passenger duty Destinations within the EU: economy club/first class Destinations outside the EU: economy club/first class £5 £10 £20 £40 £5 £10 £20 £40 Betting and gaming duty Gross profits tax Spread betting rate: financial bets other bets 15% 3% 10% 15% 3% 10% 5% 17.5% 5% 17.5% £60,000 p.a. 0% 1% 3% 4% 0.5% £60,000 p.a. 0% 1% 3% 4% 0.5% Insurance premium tax Standard rate Higher rate (for insurance sold accompanying certain goods and services) Stamp duty Land and buildings: threshold rate: up to £60,000 £60,000–£250,000 £250,000–£500,000 above £500,000 Stocks and shares: rate Vehicle excise duty Graduated system for new cars from 1 March 2001 Standard rate Small-car rate (engines up to 1,549cc) Heavy goods vehicles (varies according to vehicle type and weight) Landfill levy Standard rate Low rate (inactive waste only) £60–£160 p.a. £160 p.a. £105 p.a. £160–£1,850 p.a. £13 per tonne £2 per tonne Local taxes Average rate band D council tax: England £14 per tonne £2 per tonne £976 Income support / income-based jobseeker’s allowance Single (aged 25 or over) Couple (both aged 18 or over) Family premium Child allowance: aged under 16 aged 16–18 Minimum income guarantee for those aged 60 or over: single couple Pension credit taper (from October 2003) Winter fuel payment for those aged 60 or over 148 £53.95 p.w. £84.65 p.w. £14.75 p.w. £37.00 p.w. £37.80 p.w. £54.65 p.w. £85.75 p.w. £15.75 p.w. £38.50 p.w. £38.50 p.w. £98.15 p.w. £149.80 p.w. n/a £200 £102.10 p.w. £155.80 p.w. 40% £200 Continues Appendix D Continued 2002–03 level 2003–04 levela Child benefit First child Other children £15.75 p.w. £10.55 p.w. £16.05 p.w. £10.75 p.w. Basic state pension Single Couple £75.50 p.w. £120.70 p.w. £77.45 p.w. £123.80 p.w. Working families’ tax credit Basic (adult) credit 30-hour credit Child credit: aged under 16 aged 16–18 Disabled child credit Applicable amount (i.e. threshold or earnings disregard) Childcare tax credit: maximum eligible cost for one child maximum eligible cost for two or more children proportion of eligible costs covered Child tax credit Family element Family element for first year of a child’s life Child element Disabled child element Working tax credit Basic element Couples and lone-parent element 30-hour element Disabled worker element Childcare element: maximum eligible cost for one child maximum eligible cost for two or more children proportion of eligible costs covered Features common to child and working tax credits First income threshold First income threshold if entitled to child tax credit only First withdrawal rate Second income threshold Second withdrawal rate £62.50 p.w. £11.65 p.w. £26.45 p.w. £27.20 p.w. £35.50 p.w. £94.50 p.w. Replaced by child tax credit and working tax credit £135.00 p.w. £200.00 p.w. 70% n/a n/a n/a n/a £545 p.a. £1,090 p.a. £1,445 p.a. £2,155 p.a. n/a n/a n/a n/a £1,525 p.a. £1,500 p.a. £620 p.a. £2,040 p.a. n/a n/a n/a £135.00 p.w. £200.00 p.w. 70% n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a £5,060 p.a. £13,230 p.a. 37% £50,000 p.a. 1 in 15 Maternity benefits Sure Start maternity grant £500 £500 Statutory maternity pay: weeks 1–6 90% earnings 90% earnings weeks 7–18 £75.00 p.w. £100.00 p.w. weeks 19–26 zero £100.00 p.w. Maternity allowance: weeks 1–18 £75.00 p.w. £100.00 p.w. weeks 19–26 zero £100.00 p.w. a 2003–04 figures assume no discretionary changes apart from pre-announced measures and statutory indexation where appropriate. b Allowance is available at a flat rate of 10% and is tapered away from families that include a higherrate taxpayer. Sources: Various HM Treasury, Inland Revenue and HM Customs and Excise Press Releases, April 2002 and November 2002; HM Treasury, Tax Ready Reckoner and Tax Reliefs, London, 2002 (www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media//DB8B5/adtrr02.pdf); www.inlandrevenue.gov.uk/rates; www.hmce.gov.uk/business/othertaxes/othertaxes.htm; www.dwp.gov.uk/lifeevent/benefits/index.htm; www.local.dtlr.gov.uk/finance/ctax/ctax023.htm; Tolley, Tolley’s Tax Data 2002–03, London, 2002. 149 Appendix E: Tax revenues ready reckoner Table E.1. Direct effects of illustrative changes in taxation to take effect April 2003 Cost/yield (non-indexed base) 2003–04 (£m) Income tax Rates Change starting rate by 1pa Change basic rate by 1pb Change higher rate by 1p Change basic rate in Scotland by 1p 560 3,250 1,120 260 Allowances Change personal allowance by £100 620 Starting-rate limit Change starting-rate limit by £100 320 Basic-rate limit Change basic-rate limit by 1% Change basic-rate limit by 10%: increase (cost) decrease (yield) 1,700 2,100 Allowances and limits Change all main allowances, starting- and basic-rate limits: increase/decrease by 1% increase by 10% (cost) decrease by 10% (yield) 590 5,600 6,300 190 National Insurance Rates Change Class 1 employee rate between entry threshold and upper earnings limit by 1 percentage point Change Class 1 employee rate above upper earnings limit by 1 percentage point Change Class 1 employer rate by 1 percentage point Change Class 2 (self-employed) rate by £1 a week Change Class 4 (self-employed) rate by 1 percentage point Allowances Change employee entry threshold by £2 per week Change employer entry threshold by £2 per week Change upper earnings limit by £10 per week a Including savings income taxable at the starting rate, but excluding dividend income. b Covering savings income (but not the starting rate), and excluding dividends. 3,150 655 3,950 130 290 245 290 125 Continues 150 Appendix E Continued Cost/yield (non-indexed base) 2003–04 (£m) Corporation tax Change main rate by 1 percentage point Change small companies’ rate by 1 percentage point 1,150 240 Capital gains tax Increase annual exempt amount by £500 for individuals and £250 for trustees 10 Inheritance tax Change rate by 1 percentage point Increase threshold by £5,000 75 65 Excise dutiesc Beer up 0.3p a pint Wine up 1.4p a bottle (75cl) Spirits up 6.4p a bottle (70cl) Cigarettes up 3.6p a packet (20 king-size) Petrol up 0.5p a litre Diesel (ultra-low sulphur) up 0.5p a litre Change insurance premium tax (both standard and higher rates) by 1 percentage point 35 15 5 65 120 110 315 VAT Change both standard and reduced rates by 1 percentage point 3,840 2002–03 Extend VAT to: 9,350 food 3,400 construction of new homes 1,750 domestic and international (UK portion) passenger transport 1,450 books, newspapers and magazines 950 water and sewerage services 800 children’s clothing 800 drugs and supplies on prescription c Figures are calculated given the price and tax charged on a typical item. All changes are assumed to be implemented in April 2003. Note: The revenue effect is computed for changes to the 2003–04 tax system and relates to the full-year effect, except for changes to the coverage of VAT which refer to 2002–03 Source: HM Treasury, Tax Ready Reckoner and Tax Reliefs, London, November 2002 (www.hmtreasury.gov.uk/mediastore/otherfiles/adtrr02.pdf). VAT coverage 151