Environmental Taxation Arun Advani arun.advani@ifs.org.uk © Institute for Fiscal Studies Outline • Objectives for Policy. • Theory. • Current policy in the UK. • An improving reform to household policy. • Distributional effects. • Potential compensation package. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Objectives for policy © Institute for Fiscal Studies Key objective for environmental taxation • Reduce CO2e emissions in line with our targets. – Target to reduce emissions by 80% relative to 1990 levels by 2050. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Getting to the 2050 target – UK carbon budgets 800 Total emissions (mtCO2e) 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 Source Advani et al. (2013a), Figure 2.1 © Institute for Fiscal Studies 2050 2045 2040 2035 2030 2025 2020 2015 2010 2005 2000 1995 1990 0 Key objective for environmental taxation • Reduce CO2e emissions in line with our targets. – Target to reduce emissions by 80% relative to 1990 levels by 2050. • Want to achieve this whilst: – Maintaining energy security. – Avoiding negative distributional consequences. – Minimising “carbon leakage”. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distribution of energy budget shares 18% Average budget share 16% Other fuels 14% Gas 12% Electricity 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 9 Richest Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 Poorest 0% Source Advani et al. (2013b), Figure 3.6 • Energy makes up 16% of spending for poorest 10%; 3% of spending for richest 10%. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Theory © Institute for Fiscal Studies Correcting Externalities (1) • Externalities. – Costs or benefits from an activity borne by third parties which are not reflected in prices. – Lead to misallocation of resources e.g. overconsumption of a ‘bad’. • Pricing the externality can internalise these costs. – Decentralised way to achieve the optimal allocation. – Can lead to a welfare gain. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Correcting Externalities (2) Costs Marginal Social Cost of Pollution t Marginal Private Cost of Pollution Marginal Cost of Abatement Pollution © Institute for Fiscal Studies Other imperfections • Principle of Targeting. – If we have other objectives or constraints, where possible it is better to tackle them through well-targeted instruments. – If you use one instrument to target two objectives, may not achieve either... • Lots of policy options for dealing with other objectives and constraints. – Taxes. – Permits. – Regulation. – Subsidising abatement or alternatives. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Current policy in the UK © Institute for Fiscal Studies Current UK policy • These can be broadly defined in four categories: 1. Policies to price carbon. 2. Policies to support renewables. 3. Policies to support energy efficiency improvements. 4. Policies to support domestic energy bills. © Institute for Fiscal Studies What do these policies mean for carbon prices? • We calculate implicit carbon prices in 2013 and 2020. • Two fuels: – Electricity. – Gas. • Four end-users: – Households. – Small businesses. – Medium businesses. – Large energy-intensive businesses. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Emissions produced by each end-user in 2012 140 120 Emissions (mtCO2) Gas Electricity 100 80 60 40 20 0 Households Small businesses Medium businesses Large energy intensive businesses Source: Advani et al. (2013a), Figure 6.1 • For comparison, total UK emissions in 2012 were 572MtCO2e. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Which policies affect carbon price for different end-users? Households Small business Medium business Large energyintensive business Electricity EU ETS CPSR RO FITs WHD ECO VAT subsidy EU ETS CPSR RO FITs CCL EU ETS CPSR RO FITs CCL CRC EU ETS CPSR RO FITs CCA Gas WHD ECO VAT subsidy CCL CCL CRC EU ETS CCA © Institute for Fiscal Studies Calculating carbon prices • We take estimates for the impact of each policy on energy prices • These impacts are converted into an implicit price for a tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent • This varies across fuels due to differences in carbon content. – Gas is currently less carbon intensive than electricity • For gas, we use the carbon content of domestic gas • For electricity, we use the long run marginal emissions factor © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 30 CPSR 10 -10 -30 -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business ETS Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 30 FiT 10 -10 RO Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business CPSR ETS -30 -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 30 CRC CCL 10 FiT -10 Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business RO CPSR ETS -30 -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 ECO 30 WHD CRC 10 CCL -10 Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business FiT RO CPSR -30 -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies ETS Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 VAT 30 ECO WHD 10 CRC CCL -10 -30 Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business FiT RO CPSR ETS -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implicit carbon prices for electricity, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 30 10 -10 -30 -50 -70 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Households Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business Implicit carbon prices for electricity and gas, 2013 70 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 50 30 10 -10 Households Small business Medium business -30 Electricity -50 -70 Source Advani et al. (2013a), Figure 6.4 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Gas Large energy intensive business The size of the implicit VAT subsidy • The carbon content of a fuel depends on the quantity burned – Prices on quantity of fuel used can be a reasonable proxy for a carbon price • The size of the VAT discount doesn’t vary with the quantity of fuel, but with the price of the fuel • This makes it hard to predict the size of the subsidy in a given year, as this depends on the retail price of the fuel that year – If prices rise, the rise of the subsidy will also increase • Hence the VAT subsidy adds significant complication and uncertainty to the carbon price, as well as making it uneven © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implicit carbon prices in 2013 and 2020 140 Gas 2020 Gas 2013 Electricity 2020 Electricity 2013 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 -20 -40 Households Small business Medium business Source Advani et al. (2013a), Figure 6.5 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Large energy intensive business Implicit carbon prices in 2013 and 2020 (excluding the VAT subsidy) Gas 2020 Gas 2013 Electricity 2020 Electricity 2013 140 Implicit carbon price (£/tCO2e) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 -20 -40 Households © Institute for Fiscal Studies Small business Medium business Large energy intensive business An improving reform to household policy © Institute for Fiscal Studies Potential reform to carbon prices • DECC publish an estimated “non-traded carbon price” consistent with meeting the government’s carbon emissions reduction targets. – For 2013 this “target price” is £59/tCO2e. • Potential reforms to bring household price close to target: – Introduce a gas tax of 0.8p/kWh (average retail price is 4.8p/kWh). – Introduce full rate VAT on both electricity and gas. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implications - initial • Price rises similar to those seen in recent years... – Electricity prices rose by 15% between August 2011 and May 2013. – Gas prices rose by 33% between November 2010 and May 2013. • ...But, can use the revenue raised to provide compensation. • If one assumes no change in energy demand, this raises £8.3 billion. – For comparison, the OBR estimates energy-related taxes raised £3.0 billion in 2012-13. – This is composed of CCL, EU ETS, CRC, RO, FITs, WHD. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implications – short term • Price rise reduces household demand. – Around 4% for electricity. – Around 10% for gas. • Also raises average bills by £300. • Expect to raise £7.5 billion accounting for this. • Emissions to fall by eight million tonnes of CO2e per year. – 1.4% of total annual UK emissions. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Implications – long term • Over longer horizon people will replace boilers and other appliances. – Some replacement would happen anyway... – ...but higher energy prices encourage both production and take-up of more efficient models than without this. • Expected saving of 22 million tonnes of CO2e per year. – 4% of total annual UK emissions. – Worth around £1 billion a year. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distributional effects © Institute for Fiscal Studies Average effects without compensation Average cost as % of total expenditure Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4 20% VAT Gas tax • Policies add an additional 1.5% to average total expenditure. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distributional effects without compensation Average cost as % of total expenditure Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 20% VAT Gas tax 4 • Combined reform adds around 1.8% to middle of distribution. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distributional effects without compensation Average cost as % of total expenditure Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 20% VAT Gas tax 4 • Combined reform adds around 3.7% to bottom 10% of households. • Energy is large share of budget for these households. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Distributional effects without compensation Average cost as % of total expenditure Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 20% VAT 3.5 4 Gas tax Source Advani et al. (2013b), Figure 6.2 • |n absence of compensation, reform is ‘regressive’ in the sense that poorer households pay more as a share of expenditure. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Potential compensation package © Institute for Fiscal Studies Compensation for inflation • These price increases therefore feed through noticeably to inflation (one-off effect). – CPI inflation rises by 1.2 percentage points. • There is a degree of “automatic compensation” that comes from uprating of tax and benefit thresholds. – Estimated cost of this is £2.6 billion. • Since energy makes up much larger share of budget for poorer households, even after this change they are most likely to be worse off. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Additional compensation for poorer households • We increase the size of some means-tested benefits, to provide compensation. – This reform is illustrative and broadly revenue neutral (spend £7.2 bn). – Many alternatives are available depending on distributional priorities. – We consider a strongly progressive option, to see how well one could compensate poorer households if that were the aim of policy. • Groups targeted: – Poor pensioners. – Unemployed. – Low-income employed. – Individuals receiving disability benefits. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Average effect by decile Relative spending/income impact (%) 10 8 Cost as % of spending 6 4 2 0 -2 -4 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile All Richest 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 Poorest -6 Average effect by decile Relative spending/income impact (%) 10 8 Cost as % of spending 6 Gain as % of spending 4 2 0 -2 -4 © Institute for Fiscal Studies Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile All Richest 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 Poorest -6 Average effect by decile Cost as % of spending 8 Gain as % of spending 6 Net effect 4 2 0 -2 -4 Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile All Richest 9 8 7 6 5 4 Poorest © Institute for Fiscal Studies 3 Source Advani et al. (2013a), Figure 8.1 -6 2 Relative spending/income impact (%) 10 Within-decile variation 100% 90% Households affected 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Equivalised non-housing expenditure decile Loser Broadly unaffected 9 10 Winner Source: Figure 8.2 of “Energy use policies and carbon pricing in the UK” © Institute for Fiscal Studies Potential compensation - conclusions • It is possible to harmonise household carbon prices whilst compensating poorer households on average. • Within poor households there is significant variation. – Those who consume relatively large amounts of energy will still be worse off. • Reform shown is illustrative. – Precise implementation depends on a government’s distributional preferences. – We target poorer households particularly. – Also need to consider the interaction with work incentives. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Conclusion © Institute for Fiscal Studies Conclusion • Energy use policy is currently incoherent, inefficient and unstable. – This comes from having multiple conflicting objectives. – However, not clear we are tackling these in the best way. • Have shown it is possible to introduce reforms which rationalise the price and compensate most of those with low incomes. – Whilst reforms can be progressive on average, can’t ensure every low income household is compensated. • This would reduce emissions substantially at no additional economic cost. © Institute for Fiscal Studies Further Reading • Advani, A., Bassi, S., Bowen, A., Fankhauser, S., Johnson, P., Leicester, A., and Stoye, G. (2013a) Energy use policies and carbon pricing in the UK, IFS Report R84 http://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/6915 • Advani, A., Johnson, P., Leicester, A., and Stoye, G. (2013b) Household energy in Britain: A distributional analysis, IFS Report R85 http://www.ifs.org.uk/publications/6916 • Stern, N., (2006), The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review, Chapter 2 • Fullerton, D., Leicester, A., and Smith S., (2010), Mirlees Review: Dimensions of Tax Design, Chapter 5 Environmental Taxes:// • McKay, D., Sustainable Energy - Without the Hot Air, 2009 http://www.withouthotair.com/ © Institute for Fiscal Studies