Warwick Global Development Society IN THIS ISSUE GLOBALISATION FORUM Introduction AND DEVELOPMENT 2 By Shirin M. Rai Newsletter Vol.3, Special Edition, June 2005 PANEL I: AFRICA – DEVELOPMENT AS A UNIFYING FORCE? Senegal 3 WELCOME! By Abou Fall Tanzania – Looking Back: Lessons Learned 5 By Gloria N. Labarani Zimbabwe 6 By Vulindlela Ndlovu PANEL III: GLOBALISATION IN ASIA – THE CASE OF PAKISTAN, INDIA AND SOUTH KOREA Pakistan: Nationhood under the Conditions of Globalisation 7 By Uzma Hussain PANEL IV: THE GREAT BRITISH PANEL An Alternative Britain: A Radical View 9 By James Duggan The Future of Great Britain 11 By Keith Addenbrooke WORLD MODEL UNITED NATIONS Introduction 12 By Laura Dunbar Considering the Role of the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) 12 By Laura Dunbar Debates in the Sixth Committee (Legal Committee) of the General Assembly in the Harvard World Model of the United Nations (Edinburgh, March, 2005) on the Issue of Standards for Imposing Sanctions and other Coercive Measures 14 This Special Edition of the 2004-2005 Warwick Global Development Society Newsletter is focused on the conferences and events of the latter stages of the taught Masters programme. This Special Edition features revisited presentations from the Globalisation and Development Forum, convened as a concluding chapter to the Globalisation and Development programme, and reports from participants in the 2005 World Model United Nations Conference. It concludes with a brief word from two of the G+D participants, reporting on the path they will be following when their time at Warwick comes to an end. Once again our thanks go to all those who have contributed. Enjoy! By Rossalina Madjirova WHERE TO FROM HERE? Beyond Globalisation and Development 15 By Keith Addenbrooke West African Trade Hub By Abou Fall 16 1 GLOBALISATION AND DEVELOPMENT FORUM The Globalisation and Development Forum was convened on 8th March 2005, a concluding chapter to the taught component of the Globalisation and Development Masters Programme. The Forum was organised into four thematic panels, considering: Africa – Development as a Unifying Force?; Latin America – Past, Present, Future; Globalisation in Asia – The Case of Pakistan, India and South Korea; and The Great British Panel. A small selection of participants have kindly agreed to revisit their presentations for this Newsletter. Introduction Shirin M. Rai Professor of Politics and International Studies Director: MA/Dip Globalization and Development, University of Warwick I would like to express my thanks to all the students who helped organise and participated in the Forum on the 8th of March 2005. The presentations and the discussion that followed gave a real flavour of the complex set of issues that cluster under the umbrella of Globalisation and Development. Several themes emerged from the discussion. First, that there is not one but many globalisations that effect the many nations, nationalities and states that were the focus of the Forum. There is the globalisation of political economy, of culture, of socio-political institutions. There is the globalisation that encompasses all countries but in different ways – the drivers of this globalisation in both senses of the term are different and unequal. There is also the globalisation of discourses – of identities, language and of the politics of alternatives. What is considered feasible and what is not is increasingly confined within a narrow spectrum – the politics of convergence is an aspect of globalisation. Those who presented the case-studies at the Forum, both from the South and the North, reflected upon these many facets of globalisation. The particular concern was with inequalities – that are generated, gendered and institutionalised through the processes that we have come to characterise as globalisation. This concern with inequalities was also historically situated – globalisation is, it was argued, the current form of international political economy; colonialism was the previous form. The panels on Asia and Africa were particularly concerned to reflect upon how the colonial experience has affected the trajectories of development and of engagement with the global 2 political economy of the countries of these regions. The Great British panel too reflected on colonialism from the perspective of the North; of a tired but still powerful economy. The Latin American panel reflected a concern with the growing inequalities of the terms of engagement with the global political economy, which was, as in the case of Mexico, resulting in economic development but also leading to a growing inequality between the countries of the region. Social and political dissonance, resistance and even social conflict was another theme that cut across all the panels. Reference was made to women’s movements in Asia, the Shining Path in Peru and the land movement in Zimbabwe – very different responses from very different contexts to the pressures of globalisation and of development. The overwhelming concern was whether globalisation is leading to opening new avenues for development or is it closing off those that had already been opened. The message was at the same time optimistic and cautionary. The continued high levels of poverty in the world and the different forms that this poverty was taking in the context of the growth of the economy in many parts of the South were discussed. There was also some reflection on the nature of institutionalisation of globalisation – the World Bank, IMF and the WTO on the one hand and the UN on the other. All in all, it was a marvellous event – organised with the enthusiasm and commitment that I have come to expect of those doing the course. The commitment showed in many ways but also in the food that was brought to the common table. It was truly a global cuisine! Panel I: Africa – Development as a Unifying Force Senegal Abou Fall MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick INTRODUCTION A critical evaluation of development as a unifying force, in the Senegalese setting, pushes me to look at the various outcomes of the developmental frameworks throughout Senegal’s social and political history. I argue that the development paths taken by Senegal have created a fragmentation of the Senegalese society, hence the reference to the multiplicity of Senegal. I am interested in identifying how development, as articulated and implemented in Senegal, has led to multiple ‘Senegals’, multiple in the sense that the social fabric is segmented into several groups, each living different socio-economic realities. SENEGAL’S ECONOMIC, SOCIAL AND POLITICAL ARCHITECTURE THROUGHOUT HISTORY With its geographical position, at the westernmost point in Africa, Senegal has been at the crossroads of the trade routes linking Africa, America, Europe and, through the Maghreb, the Arab world. But it was essentially the development of groundnuts in the 1840s as a dominant cash crop that deeply influenced the subsequent economic, political, and social development of Senegal. The early development paradigm driven by the peanut trade drew upon the social organization of the Senegalese society for expansion. Such organization was characterized by authority from a village chief who usually sheltered a marabout, or a Muslim cleric for spiritual protection and guidance. These Muslim guides grew in religious and political influence and were later used by the French to secure trading zones. With independence proclaimed in 1960, it was under the first President Leopold Sedar Senghor that the ruling class tried to set up the political, administrative, and economic framework guided by the doctrine of ‘African socialism’. After independence, the state was seen as the primary player of economic life through the drawing of several four-year plans aimed at stimulating agricultural and industrial development. This experimental phase of interventionism in the farming sector ended in the late 1960s in a climate of discontent and disillusionment with regard to the hopes raised by independence (Berthélemy et al., 1996). The mismanagement and ineffectiveness of the structures designed to intervene in and control farming activities, the withdrawal of the French support for groundnut farming (which entailed a 25 per cent reduction of its price) and the aftermath of the first signs of drought on groundnut production led to an increasing loss of interest in groundnut farming on the part of farmers. The economic slump in the countryside provoked a rural exodus which provoked a tremendous growth of the informal sector. This strained urban development by exerting pressure on the supply of public amenities and on the urban labour market. Unemployment and precarious living conditions became the order of the day; as did claims and 3 protests from an ever-increasing urban youth population. The discontent led to social unrest in 1968 and 1969. This unrest led to a change in strategy in favour of voluntary participation and a type of interventionism more oriented towards industrialization. The economic crisis of the 1970s in Senegal cannot only be confined in the policy choices made by the state, or the mismanagement of resources by a plethoric state. The choices made by the elite and the way in which it fostered particular alliances, in my opinion, contributed to a fragmentation of the population, with certain groups (bureaucrats, the French elite, religious leaders) benefiting immensely from the exploitation of resources, and other groups such as the farmers, paying the burden of mistaken policies. Since 1979, Senegal has undergone several generations of structural adjustment programs directed by the World Bank and the IMF. The primary objectives were to rectify the macroeconomic imbalances and to re-launch the growth of the economy. The level of success of the various adjustment programs is open to appreciation. The latest macroeconomic figures suggest that Senegal is on the road to recovery, but it is still far away from addressing the objectives of the Millennium Development Goals. A CLOSER LOOK AT THE SOCIO-POLITICAL CONTEXT AND THE SEGMENTATION OF THE POPULATION The political and social organization of Senegal has been largely influenced by old administrative and political management traditions from the colonial period. Senegal was governed through a ‘direct administration’ system. The French colonial system eroded the traditional organization of society by disallowing traditional chiefs from keeping their prerogatives. The sovereignty of traditional chiefs was removed and replaced with the colonial administration. The territorial expansion however signified the need to set up a new chieftainship that was less traditional but more administrative. It is in this context, as noted above, that religious brotherhoods (confreries) were used in part to get rid off traditional chiefs. The specificity of ‘confreries’ in Senegal is worth mentioning, as it is through such confreries – particularly the Mourides – that the expansion of groundnut production was possible. By independence, Senegal had a ruling elite capable of running public affairs. The ruling elite adjusted the State apparatus to strengthen its political power, and marginalized or co-opted opposition leaders. It also strengthened the corporate nature of the army, by constantly re-organizing its command structure, and awarding benefits to army personnel. As such, the army has always remained loyal to the government. This may explain why the Senegalese army was not very keen on coups d’etat, unlike some countries in the sub-region. The State dealt with social unrest, particularly from unions, by affiliating them to the ruling party and appointing their leaders to legislative and ministerial positions. For the socialist regime, the reorganization of the state also meant appointing young executives into the ruling party organs. This lead to a patronage system where for example, political supporters could get access to bank loans, and the ‘big growers’ of groundnuts, most of them marabouts (religious leaders) had access to loans which were often not reimbursed. Until the 1970s, the mode of management of the economy and political power rested upon preserving the interests of a heterogeneous coalition of politicians, bureaucrats and religious leaders. At the same time, a new generation of entrepreneurs emerged (named Baol Baol, after the region from whence most them came), which derived influence from their ties with Mouride marabouts, this new generation of entrepreneurs constitute the bulk of the informal sector mentioned above. The failure of the developmental frameworks also brought economic imbalances in the regions, epitomized by the secessionist movement in the southern region of Casamance. The severity of Structural Adjustment programs has also led to a gradual fragmentation of the cohesive social make up in the sense that that the system that relied heavily on the marabouts is currently characterized by the exit of the first generation of religious brotherhoods’ leaders and their replacement by a new generation of marabouts who are more concerned with their own business than their traditional functions. Voting for the majority of rural dwellers and some of the urban population, especially the informal sector entrepreneurs mentioned above, was done through directives given by the marabout. This system has however eroded since 1993 with the contentious Presidential election. CONCLUSION Looking at the political, social and economic history of Senegal, we can identify early on the emergence of key actors, and the brokering of alliances to promote economic development. Throughout Senegal’s history, we have seen the predominant role of religious leaders playing a buffering role, initially with the French colonialists, then later with the ruling elites. These types of alliances have created a specific type of social organization, which do not suggest an egalitarian structure or a social system free of conflicts, but 4 they denote a well-established and accepted structure of power, and a set of social rules. In essence, I argue that the development frameworks undertaken by Senegal has created three ‘Senegals’, the first mainly rural and involved in agricultural production, who are the first to suffer the consequences of economic failures; the second Senegal which is constituted of the educated elite, vested with most of the decisional powers, both political and economic; and the third Senegal characterized by entrepreneurial Senegalese who have mainly come from the region and who constitute the bulk of the informal sector in urban centers. Although distinct, there exists a structure of interrelation between these groups that has so far maintain some form of apparent cohesiveness. This social cohesiveness is however under a lot of strain with Senegal’s liberal framework, and the various social demands that are still not met by the State. Under such conditions, political alliances are changing, both in urban and rural centers. Moreover, the lack of transparency and consultation in the choice of economic policies is going to put further strain on the State as civil society actors are getting more informed. The biggest challenge for the State will be to identify how to defend its legitimacy with the heterogeneous nature of the society that has resulted from failed economic policies. This challenge is more severe with the increase in the number of independent newspapers, the setting up of private radio stations and television channels, the dramatic expansion of new information technologies, all of which play an important role by making available for the population information that concerns not only their daily life but also the management of public affairs. REFERENCES Berthélemy, Jean-Claude; Seck, Abdoulaye; Vourc’h, Ann (1996) Growth in Senegal: A Lost Opportunity? Paris: OECD. Tanzania- Looking Back: Lessons Learned Gloria N. Labarani MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick In 2003, when President Mkapa officially announced the inauguration of the Tanzania Development Forum (inviting civil society, academics, and indeed opposition parties to debate the future of Tanzania and take stock of the past), the thoughts on most if not everyone’s minds was ‘How far had we come since Independence? With Tanzania’s wealth of resources, relatively peaceful history and aid abundance, where is Tanzania today vis-à-vis the Global Political Economy? And the even bigger question is what lessons one can derive from the development process in Tanzania? The socio-political history of Tanzania serves to identify salient factors within the state’s developmental process - factors that can be singled out as ‘lessons to be learnt’ for future reference. The Post - Independence era through to the Ujamaa era of 1967 reinforced state-led social cohesion through equity as a development priority. A special focus was paid to the eradication of poverty and illiteracy – hence the government’s special focus on education and health provisions through not only rhetoric but also in state policies. This was reflected in the villagisation process (in order to facilitate governments ability to provide social care to all). Socialism as a political policy was therefore the only policy capable of reinforcing such social provision. However, whereas the social sector thrived, the state-led economy failed due to inefficiency. The Post-liberalisation period of the 1980’s and the present period is characterised by the Structural Adjustment Programmes and their effects (very little investment in social sectors such as education and health to mention a few so much so that literacy rates that stood at 80 per cent in the first ten years of independence fell to a whopping 63 per cent – a whole generation practically lost out on social services). Politically, this was more catastrophic. The hard earned peace in Tanzania through Swahili as a unifying language is now at stake with party divisions on various levels. The unification of Tanganyika and Zanzibar heralded as a major step in state consolidation in postindependence Tanzania is likewise in jeopardy. As a young adult in contemporary Tanzania, certain factors catch my attention. Development and Democracy are context sensitive concepts .i.e. the needs of a state and its people at different stages differ. The sooner such uniqueness is taken into account, the better for all concerned. Both models of development i.e. post-independence and postliberalisation, contain within them lessons Tanzania and indeed any other country can take into consideration when devising a strategy for Development. Contrary to popular belief, democracy and multipartism are not synonymous. Fragmentation and competition are not necessarily factors for democracy. Unity can serve the purpose just as well. In Tanzania for instance, following IMF/WB pressure for multipartism, at least 80 per cent of the population voted in favour of a one party system. If democracy is to mean the rule of the majority, then surely in this scenario, a single party is the way to 5 go. So many questions, just as many answers!! Ironically, the Tanzanian system of prioritising human capability building and social provision in an equitable fashion is reflected in the lessons being preached in current rhetoric within social justice causes e.g. Oxfam as well as multilateral institutions such as the WB & IMF (whether or not this is put into practice is an issue for another debate). While the prioritising of economic efficiency as suggested by liberalisation would serve to improve growth for poor countries, sidelining government intervention denies poorer people access to the fruits of growth. Possibly, a shrewd combination of the two i.e. the combination of efficient economic growth with prioritised equitable human capability building could serve to pull countries such as Tanzania out of the cycle of poverty, albeit slowly. The current development model that serves to promote economic growth along severe disparities of the magnitude present in modern day Tanzania, in my opinion, is a system that helps to sustain a culture of corruption and this has a potential to jeopardise not only democracy but also the rule of law and the maintenance of hard earned peace. The biggest lesson I learn from Tanzania’s experience is that development, if anything, should be a learning process whereby every policy is assessed for potential benefits and replaced after important lessons have been taken on-board. Without a learning process, regardless of one’s definition, development tends to be fragmented and totally inefficient. Tanzania is a classic example of such a scenario. Zimbabwe Vulindlela Ndlovu MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick When I started thinking about the question ‘development as a unifying force’ in the context of Zimbabwe, recent events involving white Zimbabwean farmers being violently forced off their farms immediately sprung to mind. Zimbabwe’s colonial and postcolonial histories have in many ways been defined by land. It is by no means the only defining issue, but it has been one of the most important. In the short time I have, I hope to give an overview of how land has influenced political, social and economic outcomes in Zimbabwe. The various development models chosen in the course of Zimbabwe’s colonial and post colonial history have played a key role in determining how land has shaped political, social and economic outcomes. In my opinion the outcomes show that the attempts at development in Zimbabwe have not been a unifying force. White Zimbabwean farmers being forcibly and violently removed from their farms is one of the more visible examples. I hope to bring out other less visible, but important outcomes that show Zimbabwe’s attempts at development have failed as a unifying force. I will proceed by outlining four stages in the history of Zimbabwe’s development: the colonial period from the late 19th century to 1980, the immediate post-colonial period from 1981 to 1990, the turn to neo-liberal economics from 1991 to 1999, and finally the post1999 period. The early colonial period was dominated by a settler quest for productive land. The most productive tracts of land were identified and divided into numerous farms and ranches. Indigenous populations were forced off the land onto less productive land where rainfall was low, the soil was poor, and resources were stretched as more and more people were crowded onto a smaller area of land. At independence in 1980 over two-fifths of land in Zimbabwe was occupied by the minority white settler farmers with more than 70 per cent of the best agricultural land owned by about 5,000 white farmers. This distribution of land and the racism inherent in colonial economics and politics meant that the black majority were given few economic and political freedoms. Politically they were denied the right to vote. Economically, they could not own land. To survive, the black population was thus largely restricted to three options: attempting to eke out a living on the poor land they had been forced onto but did not own; providing cheap labour on the white owned farms and ranches; or; providing cheap industrial and service labour in towns and cities. From a dependency theory perspective, the white farmers could thus be seen as the ‘core’ within ‘periphery’ and the black population the ‘periphery.’ But the colonial system did not only create divisions along racial lines, it served to accentuate gender divisions and inequalities. The majority of those employed in towns and cities were men and in most cases they would leave their families in their rural homes and send remittances. Rural women were thus left with the task of raising children, caring for the old and sick, farming where it was possible, and the general maintenance of the household. This unpaid work by women can be seen as subsidising the colonial system. Independence in 1980, after a 13 year nationalistled guerrilla war, was seen as an opportunity to develop the country, economically, socially, and politically, by addressing the imbalances colonialism had created. Dependency theorists might have proposed radical redistribution of land as a form of wealth redistribution to the rural poor. But the peace agreement and the new constitution that paved the way for independence prevented this from happening by including a market based willing-seller clause for the first 10 years of 6 independence (i.e. the government could only redistribute land that white farmers were willing to sell). With few farmers willing to sell, there was little land redistribution and the redistribution that did take place was largely undermined by government corruption and ineptitude. Thus, without significant redistribution of land the ownership of productive land maintained many of the structural relationships that colonialism had created. But the 1980s did see the growth of an urban middle-class. Protectionist and tight regulatory policies meant a growth in Zimbabwean industry and created new jobs in urban areas, allowing the formation and growth of the urban middle class. The growth in urban employment also allowed for the continued flow of urban-rural remittances. The growth of an urban middle-class served to create a significant ruralurban income gap, while the flow of rural-urban remittances maintained a rural dependence on urban incomes. Economic stagnation in the late 1980s forced the government to embark on an IMF and World Bank-sponsored structural adjustment program. The adjustment program resulted in increased unemployment, cuts in education and health, and decreased real wages. The structural adjustment program not only had the effect of significantly reducing living standards for the urban populations, but it also led to a dramatic decline in rural urban remittances and thus substantially increased the already existing burden on rural women. However, the negative social and economic consequences of the structural adjustment program did serve to reawaken Zimbabwean civil society from its postindependence slumber to demand socio-economic and political reform through widespread strikes and demonstrations. The revival of civil society culminated in the formation of a new political party (MDC) that posed a significant challenge to the post-independence dominance of the ruling party (ZANU-PF). The problem with the reinvigorated civil society and new political party was that they were rooted in, and largely driven by an urbanbased trade union movement. Thus, while it was effective in articulating the demands of the urban workers and the urban middle class, there remained little articulation of the demands of the rural poor. Land redistribution was still immensely important to the rural poor, but was largely ignored by the main actors in civil society. And yet by 1999, Zimbabwe was still very much dependent on its agricultural land: agriculture employed over 70 per cent of the workforce and contributed about 47 per cent to the total value of exports. The urban-based civil society and party movement thus undermined its efforts to bring about political reform by paying little attention to the land issue and in so doing, alienated the rural poor. Parliamentary elections in 2000 showed the MDC’s strong appeal to the urban voters, but its failure to replicate that appeal to rural voters possibly prevented it from winning the elections. The deteriorating economic conditions in the late 1990s lost ZANU-PF significant political support. But the MDC’s failure to address the land issue, meant that ZANU-PF has been able to appeal to the impoverished rural poor by proposing radical and rapid redistribution of land. From 1999, ZANU-PF invoked memory of the anti-colonial struggle by using nationalist rhetoric and blaming white farmers for the plight of the rural poor. Thus by using a group of war veterans and impoverished rural poor to the forcibly and violently remove thousands of white farmers from their land, ZANU-PF was able to claim that only it was concerned and could deal with the issue of land. But the land invasions have been chaotic and have only served to plunge Zimbabwe into an economic crisis. The rural poor, including those who took part in the land invasions, are no better off than they were before and they still do not have any rights to ownership of the land. Those in the urban centres have been severely affected by the economic crisis – inflation of more than 300 per cent and unemployment at an estimate 80 per cent has made life extremely difficult. The optimism for change that greeted the new millennium has disappeared as most Zimbabweans have lost faith in the ability of the MDC and civil society to bring about the change so desperately needed. Panel III: Globalisation in Asia – The Case of Pakistan, India and South Korea Pakistan: Nationhood under the Conditions of Globalisation Uzma Hussain MA student in International Political Economy, University of Warwick Conventional accounts, whether domestic or global, have assumed a Westphalian cartography of clear lines and stable identities and a stable, settled social bond. What if we argue that one of the effects of globalisation is the unbundling of territorial boundaries, and the stable social bond deteriorates? The social bond is almost exclusively understood in terms of sovereignty. Strain on the social bond within states is giving rise to a search for newer forms of organization that transcend the sovereign state. The sovereign state is the primary subject of modern 7 international relations – the highest point of authority and decision. The institution of state sovereignty brought with it a social bond (or social contract) which distinguished between the domesticated interior and the anarchical exterior. But “with the passage of time, and the changed milieu in which states exist, it is no longer axiomatic that the sovereign state is practical or adequate as a means of comprehensively organising modern political life and especially providing the array of public goods normally associated with the late twentieth-century welfare state” (Devetak and Higgott, 1999, p.487). Material changes associated with economic globalisation – especially the processes of liberalisation, deregulation and integration of the global political economy in the domains of production, exchange and finance – are affecting the ability of the sovereign state to stabilise the social bond. Globalisation makes it more difficult for states to maintain the stability of the social bond, making it harder for the government to provide the compensatory mechanisms that could underwrite social cohesion in the face of change in employment structures. As it becomes more difficult to tax capital, the burden shifts to labour, making it more difficult to run welfare states. It might be good economic theory but it is poor political theory. Globalisation is a term that has come to be used in recent years increasingly frequently and arguably, increasingly loosely (Scholte, 1997). The logic of modern economics, hyperglobalists would argue, is making the state redundant. Globalisation cannot be reduced to a question of capitalism alone – it should not be a narrow materialist political economy, it needs to be accorded causal significance of structures of identity, community, knowledge and ecology. Discussions of globalisation usually highlight the question of borders – the territorial demarcations of state jurisdictions. Not all states have been affected by and responded to trans-border capitalism in the same way. Individual states have faced globalisation with different levels and kinds of resources, different histories and cultures, different policy options and choices – and different domestic circumstances. States, again, especially the powerful states, have also retained important influence in contemporary global finance. Three problems faced by the postcolonial state in the era of global capitalism: the reconfiguration of the subject citizen, the crisis of sovereign borders, and the depoliticisation of politics. People come to face core contradictions of ‘boundedness’ and belonging. Shifting relationships between Globalisation shifts the distinctive wealth of nations, and so nations need to turn to a redefinition of their identities. Why, at this point in the history of postcolonial nation-states, has the question of boundaries and their transgression, of membership and citizenship, become such an incendiary issue? How, in turn, does the naturalisation of nationality relate to the construction of older identities framed in terms of history, culture, race, ethnicity? The idyll of European styled democracy, the era of postcoloniality has fast had to realise that the promise of growth and autonomy was sundered by the realities of neo-colonialism, which freighted them with an impossible toll of debt and dependency. The struggle to arrive at meaningful terms with which to construct a sense of belonging, in circumstances that privilege difference; into the endeavour to regulate sovereign borders under global conditions that not only encourage that transnational movement of labour and capital, money and goods, but make them a necessary condition for the wealth of nations; into the often bitter controversies that rage as people assert various kinds of identity to make claims of entitlement and interest, into troubled public discourses on the proper reach of twenty-first century constitutions and, especially, their protection of individual rights; into the complicated processes by which government, non-governmental organisations, citizens acting in the name of civil society, and other social fractions, seek to carve out a division of political and social labour; into the implications of angst about the decay of the public order, and crime both organised and random, about corruption and its policing. Nationalism stresses continuity, heroic fabrication of the past, and its link with the inadequacies of the recent past in order to mobilise support for progress and development to a supposedly better future. An important aspect of nationalism’s appeal is the stress on continuity with the past. Nationalism is simultaneously a ‘plan’ for society’s geopolitical organisation and a false consciousness as it presents social constructs such as territorial homeland, nation and nation-state as ‘natural’ and ‘eternal’. Ethno-relations require some recognitions of territorial centralisation. A vital aspect of this international architecture, however, was the premise that its component parts – the sovereign states – were capable of functioning in a ‘Westphalian’ sense, i.e. that they could exercise genuine control over at least the larger part of their territory and population and act as sovereign entities in the sense of cooperating with other states, governing according to the rule of law, respecting international legal obligations, preventing crime etc. Is democracy a pre-requisite for a fully functioning, economically efficient and politically stable nation state? Is the Westphalian order willing to accept other forms of governance? 8 What works for the post-colonial countries? In post-colonial Pakistan we are still talking about nation-building. In South Waziristan there have been military operations to gain control of tribal territory and disarm citizens since US intelligence indicated that there were terrorists operating freely in the region. Citizens do not feel that the state is in their hands – global political economy means that control has been redistributed – there are multiple centres of authority, and domestic public pressure is an increasingly minor interest group. Pakistan's problem is more basic still: like much of Africa, the country makes no geographic or demographic sense. It was founded as a homeland for the Muslims of the subcontinent, yet there are more sub-continental Muslims outside Pakistan than within it. Like Yugoslavia, Pakistan is a patchwork of ethnic groups, increasingly in violent conflict with one another. While the Western media gushes over the fact that the country has a woman Prime Minister, Benazir Bhutto, Karachi is becoming a sub-continental version of Lagos. In eight visits to Pakistan, I have never gotten a sense of a cohesive national identity. With as much as 65 percent of its land dependent on intensive irrigation, with wide-scale deforestation, and with a yearly population growth of 2.7 per cent (which ensures that the amount of cultivated land per rural inhabitant will plummet), Pakistan is becoming a more and more desperate place. As irrigation in the Indus River basin intensifies to serve two growing populations, Muslim-Hindu strife over falling water tables may be unavoidable. In 1971 Pakistan lost Bangladesh which is evidence of the lost capacity of the national narrative to have allowed for a functioning government within the international system. A failed state? Has it been long enough for the state to have established enough domestic legitimacy for it to be able to implement the changes that are demanded of it by the international organisations and the neoliberal dictates? The autonomy of the state came into question from the pressures of globalisation before the autonomy of the state was established domestically. The conception of the state as eternal and natural is not the case for all countries, especially within the postcolonial context, and therefore the Bretton Woods system holds multiple complexities for such countries: crisis of identity, conformity to the world system, functionality of the state offices, and welfare of their populations. While the state is supposed to be the legitimate actor within the international system, in reality you have weak institutions and poor functionality of the state (member of the international organisations). Therefore what you end up with is a crisis of legitimacy for the state within and outside of its territory – a crisis of legitimacy, a crisis of belonging, and, a loss of autonomy in decision making. REFERENCES Devetak, Richard; Higgott, Richard (1999) ‘Justice unbound: Globalization, states and the transformation of the social bond?’, International Affairs, 75(3), pp.483-498. Scholte, Jan Aart (1997) ‘Global Capitalism and the State’, International Affairs, 73(3), pp.427-452. Panel IV: The Great British Panel An Alternative Britain: A Radical View James Duggan MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick Firstly, the task of formulating an alternative social, political and economic system and outlining it in ten minutes is beyond my capabilities… and if it wasn’t, like all the other contemporary original thinkers I’d write the book of my idea and sell it through one of those publishing houses for independent thought at £15.99 a copy and all of you could go and buy it. This in itself demonstrates both how ingrained capitalist behaviours are and how resilient the system of capitalism is. Instead I want to argue against ‘TINA’ – Margaret Thatcher’s acronym that ‘there is no alternative’. Although I don’t have the answer, I believe, an alternative is both possible and necessary. Ideally I would not label my views as a ‘radical’ alternative. ‘Radical’ is politically a negative term, compare it to, for example, the way ‘pragmatic’ is used. We are living in a time when ‘radical’ means fundamentalism and there are no alternatives. Myopically or optimistically, Fukuyama claimed that it was the ‘end of history’. Apparently radicalism is dead and there is no alternative. However, I would define my position as an alternative to the radical, albeit the current orthodox neo-liberal radicalism. In False Dawn, John Gray (2002) demonstrates that capitalism at the moment is engaged on a utopian project of social engineering, the outcome of which we can know in advance. Free markets exacerbate social and economic conflict, which leads to political response – protectionism – and then war (e.g. WWI and WWII). Indeed attempting to 9 reproduce globally something that occurred in extremely favourable circumstances in 19th Century Great Britain is an undoubtedly radical project. So what is the alternative? This is the question asked of the anti-globalisation movement. Although I recognise the fundamental importance of the question, I do doubt its sincerity. Also, as Chomsky notes, capitalism formed gradually. Capitalism wasn’t born fully-fledged and flying, it took time and thought to develop. I want to look at two typical rebuttals to alternative socio-economic orders: that Communism failed – thus, there is no alternative – and, capitalism is based on self-interest and thus human nature – TINA. Sklair (2002) reminds us that the failure of Stalinism was conflated to the failure of Communism and with it any alternative to neo-liberal global capitalism. Singer (1999) informs us that the failure of the Soviet Union was taken as proof of Capitalism’s eternal bond to humanity. As Chomsky reminds us, we should remember the vastly different starting positions and the ignored similarities of the two systems. Therefore we should remember that there are different temporal, cultural and economic contexts in which alternatives may be developed and implemented. I think we should be sceptical of the claim that capitalism is the true manifestation of human nature. Human’s had natures before capitalism and hopefully will afterwards. Looking at the development of this idea, briefly put, it can be traced to Social Darwinism and, in the words of Herbert Spencer, the ‘survival of the fittest’. Without drawing any exact parallels this vein of thought produced the eugenics movement. What is of note is that Social Darwinism was adopted in Capitalist ideology because it justified colonialism and Victorian expansionism. At the time other proposals, such as Kropotkin’s, that focussed on the co-operative nature of human social interactions were ignored because they contradicted what Darwinism justified. real and meaningful change to the way people live, the way society functions, the way the world relates. Of course, Britain is integrated into the architecture of global finance, so any change would mean that jobs would probably be lost, capital would flee, people’s lives would be significantly changed and in many cases negatively affected. The fact that the economy is effectively insulated from democratic change, and to avoid temporary capital relocation, means that change would have to occur globally… and you can just imagine the conversation with the emerging Eastern economies: “So Capitalism’s bad now, is it? The error of your ways, have you? Now we have to all work together, do we?” What I think we need is a fundamental change of values. It seems that capitalism will probably be the system that makes the most money. Any measures that interfere with the production and flow of capital will be deemed impractical (e.g. the Tobin Tax). It depends, though, on what we value most: money or people? Our wallet or ourselves? I am not particularly confident that this sort of change can be made in Britain. I’m not sure if I’m too radical or not radical enough. There are other options, maybe the reskilling of workers through the redesigning of machines and technology – but I don’t see where the incentives to reverse the continuation of the deskilling process would come from. George Monbiot heralded a totally self-sustainable community – it is in fact a real die-hard hippy commune – living in England as proof of the feasibility of an alternative lifestyle. But for the millions who tune into all of the ‘do your home up’ programmes on TV that’s not an alternative to global cataclysm. The problem for a radical solution is of course that it must be made palatable for the majority of people. Although capitalism is imposing nondemocratic reform – that is incidentally undermining democratic powers – I believe any other type of non-democratic reform would face insurmountable resistance in Britain… unless you said that it was to fight terrorism maybe. Gray gives an apt example of this contradiction between the claim and reality. Neo-liberalists claim that free-markets are the result of natural processes, when in fact they are the deliberate products of political coercion. In 19th Century Britain this was due to an absence of functioning democratic practices. The ascendance of non-democratic organisations, such as the WTO, that insulate economic policy from democratic control are the modern analogues. So my ‘radical’ alternative is that we recognise that economic relations grew out of social relations and so we should re-integrate them back into a function that genuinely serves the social, meaning humanity not just the people of Britain. So, my brief brushstrokes of an alternative future would include a form of participative democracy and the re-politicisation of economics. Beyond that is for the participative democratic system to decide but the re-politicisation of economics would allow Singer, D. (1999) Whose Millennium? Theirs or Ours? New York: Monthly Review Press. REFERENCES Gray, John (2002) False Dawn: The Delusions of Global Capitalism. London: Granta. Sklair, Leslie (2002) Globalization: Capitalism and its alternatives. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 10 The Future of Great Britain Keith Addenbrooke MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick Can I now retire happy? After all, two of the predictions in my presentation at the G+D Forum have proved to be correct: we have had a general election in Britain and, yet again, forty per cent of those eligible to vote elected not to. Although I did vote, my choice of candidate and party was made by an immiserated process of elimination: who did I dislike the least? In this, I know, I was not alone. Which leaves the question opening my presentation on an alternative future for Britain still valid: which way now? As a parent it is an important question, for my three children can be expected to live into the second half of this century, by which time the UN estimates the world population will have swelled to around 9 billion. And this is one of the reasons why I cannot subscribe to the conventional view that ‘more of the same’ will do, especially as ‘the same’ meant a reduction in official development assistance to nothing more than 0.23 per cent of developed countries’ GDP during the 1990’s (although it has since risen it is still well below the UN target of 0.7 per cent). Like Leslie Sklair, I believe that the self-interested nature of consumerism that defines Western lifestyles represents the fundamental weakness of the present system. But mass consumption was never intended to be the final stage of development. Walt Rostow argued that there was a stage ‘beyond consumption.’ Rostow’s problem was that, writing in 1960, he had to observe that it was ‘too soon’ to work out what it might be. Now is the time to find out. The problems of persistent inequality and deep social injustice are not just global – they exist here in Coventry and across Britain too. John Gray argues that, “the innermost contradiction of the free market is that it works to weaken the traditional social institutions on which it has depended in the past.” In Britain, I believe it has. But I cannot share Sklair’s enthusiasm for a global socialist future. Instead, I believe Britons will increasingly come to be recognised for their contribution to an alternative view of development. For me, fifty years of failure in development merely confirms the view that ‘the Enlightenment’ was, in some respects, a rather big mistake. In alternative development however I see a plurality of bottomup initiatives that do not converge into a new metanarrative, but really can deliver localised results. I argued in March that Britons are beginning to rediscover the values that underpin society, as disenchantment with the endless consumption that has become the sorry end-game for development grows. Under the heading of ‘the respect society’ this, it would appear, has become government policy in just two months. But I don’t believe the rebuilding of societal values will come from government policy. It will be ordinary people who will make the change. In many ways, eighteen weeks of seminars only allowed us to scratch the surface of Globalisation and Development, but I will leave Warwick believing that there is a new hope that lies outside our present paradigm. Instead, I ask that we look for the good things that good people are now doing on fair trade, poverty/debt reduction and the environment, and see in them a better future. 11 WORLD MODEL UNITED NATIONS CONFERENCE University of Edinburgh, Scotland 28th March to 1st April 2005 Introduction Laura Dunbar MA student in International Political Economy, University of Warwick The World Model United Nations Conference is an annual event which brings together over 1,000 students from across the world to debate social, economic, political and cultural issues within the simulated environment of the United Nations. The conference provides a fascinating insight into the workings of the United Nations, with difficult decisions to be made and careful diplomacy required. This year delegates enjoyed lively discussion on a variety of topics, from debt relief and the politics of free trade, to gay rights as human rights and Israeli withdrawal from Gaza. Within the UN committee structure representatives worked to resolve issues in an environment best characterised as one of ‘competitive cooperation’. As the delegations of Mozambique and Iraq, thirteen postgraduate students from the Department of Politics and International Studies were confronted with the challenge of shaping this policy environment to their country’s advantage. For the Iraqi delegation this task was significantly complicated by the uncertainty and insecurity of the country’s current political and economic situation. In the absence of a formed Iraqi government, alliances were at best tentative, and policy stances subject to change. The following accounts detail various aspects of this richly diverse conference. Considering the Role of the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) Laura Dunbar MA student in International Political Economy, University of Warwick World Model United Nations aims to foster an environment of cooperation and friendship through a simulation of the United Nations system. My experience as the head delegate for Iraq and representative on the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) testifies to this fact, with the near unanimous vote to pass a resolution on the topic of debt relief epitomising this cooperative spirit. For Iraq the resolution provided a positive outcome. The country carries a heavy debt burden. It owed more than $120 billion in external debts and up to $300 billion in war reparations in 2004. Yet after five days of debate and discussion it was clear that the strengths of the UNDP had not been fully harnessed to bring action to bear on the issue of debt relief, provoking more questions than answers about the role of the UNDP and its strengths as a development agency. The following article aims to address some of these issues. The work of the UNDP is of undisputed importance. The organisation’s declared mission is to help countries in their efforts to achieve sustainable human development by assisting them to build their capacity to design and carry out development programmes in poverty eradication, employment creation and sustainable livelihoods, the empowerment of women and the protection and regeneration of the environment, giving first priority to poverty eradication. The UNDP specialises in the provision of resources, experience and knowledge required to achieve these objectives. The success of the UNDP is built upon a committee structure which affords each member state equal representation on the basis of a one member, one vote system. It also accords consultative status to selected non-governmental organisations. In theory these measures expand the 12 basis of informed debate, encourage dialogue and ultimately foster effective development policy solutions. As a result, the UNDP enjoys unrivalled country ownership of policies and programmes. However, in practice, these multilateral negotiations may be replaced by the formation of competing majority voting blocs, which impede any meaningful dialogue and produce a resolution with no practical consequences. In such cases major donors may prefer bilateral negotiations, which produce agreements that can be implemented. This undermines the utility of the UNDP as a forum for the coordination of development policy. To some extent this was the experience of the World MUN UNDP committee. Early on in the proceedings voting blocs were formed reflecting different country interests, perceptions and expectations. Mozambique aligned with the African bloc, Iraq with any country willing to consider the case for the cancellation of odious debts. A consensus was formed in favour of debt relief, but agreed standards were matched by disagreement over the method by which these standards were to be achieved. More time was required to grapple with and resolve contentious issues in order to provide a sustainable solution to the crippling debt burden confronting so many countries. However, cooperation within the UNDP is a necessary but insufficient condition for the resolution of the problems associated with the scheduled committee topics: ‘rethinking the conditions for debt relief’ and ‘the costs and benefits of financing AIDS programmes’. At the very least, the scope of action required to effectively address these issues requires the coordination of economic and social policies between the various UN bodies; including the specialised agencies, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank, whose policies often contradict the values and purpose of the UNDP. Delegates devoted much time in committee session to these financial institutions in an attempt to utilise the UNDP as a means by which to rein in their worst excesses, in particular to reform aspects of the current initiative to relieve the debt of the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC). However, the World Bank and the IMF cannot be regulated through the UNDP precisely because of the functional separation institutionalised between the central UN system and the specialised agencies. This means that “no matter whether development issues, administration or financial methods are concerned, the agencies cannot be obliged to adopt policies laid down by the Secretariat or other bodies of the United Nations” (Ho-Won, 1998, p.224). On the contrary, the UNDP lacks this organisational independence. Instead it falls within the remit of the Economic and Social Council (ECOSOC). Therefore, the UNDP’s management arrangements are subject to direct General Assembly supervision and modification by Assembly resolution, and like other funds and programmes within the UN system the organisation is largely funded on a voluntary basis (Taylor, 1997, p.267). This relationship brings the UNDP into direct competition for funding with other UN bodies and politicises the formulation of development policy. In response to these challenges, Klingebiel argues that reform of the UNDP is required not only to strengthen, but also to sustain its position within the international development community (Klingebiel, 1999). Greater policy coordination is required within the UN system and a more stable source of funding for the UNDP remains its principal challenge. These problems of funding and coordination will require more extensive reform of UN development cooperation. Originally the UNDP was envisaged to play a greater coordinating role within the UN system. This function was undermined, in part by the growth in funding for technical assistance by the World Bank. Now more than ever is the time to increase this role by according the UNDP greater status and powers. Only then can the cooperative efforts of UNDP committee members produce maximum effective action. The need to ensure that this cooperation becomes more than simply words on paper is surely one of the most important lessons to be drawn from the World MUN experience. For further information about the World MUN conference and this year’s committee resolutions please visit www.worldmun.org/2005/committees/ REFERENCES Ho-Won Jeong (1998) ‘The struggle in the UN system for wider participation in forming global economic policies’, in Chadwick F. Alger, ed., The future of the United Nations system: Potential for the twenty-first century. Tokyo; New York: United Nations University Press. Taylor, Paul (1997) ‘The United Nations and International Organization’, in John Baylis and Steve Smith, eds., The Globalization of World Politics: An Introduction to International Relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Klingebiel, Stephan (1999) Effectiveness and Reform of the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP). London: Frank Cass. 13 Debates in the Sixth Committee (Legal Committee) of the General Assembly in the Harvard World Model of the United Nations (Edinburgh, March, 2005) on the Issue of Standards for Imposing Sanctions and other Coercive Measures Rossalina Madjirova MA student in International Political Economy, University of Warwick The Iraqi delegation took part in the debates on one of the most important and interesting issues in the Harvard World Model United Nations Conference (Edinburgh, March, 2005) – standards for imposing sanctions and other coercive measures. The problem is debated in the Legal Committee – one of the six permanent committees of the General Assembly of the United Nations. The issues discussed there are voted on through resolutions passed in plenary meetings of the General Assembly, after the committee has completed its consideration of them and submitted draft resolutions to the plenary Assembly. The Legal Committee members of the Harvard World MUN first decided on the agenda, i.e. they had to choose between two topics – Jurisdictional Immunities of States and their Property and Standards for Imposing Sanctions and other Coercive Measures. Although the latter one is much more controversial and difficult to reach consensus on, Harvard World MUN delegates, including Iraq, decided to consider the issue of sanctions at their meeting. Sanctions have negative humanitarian and economic effects on targeted states as well as on third parties. Reforming those provisions of international law pertaining to sanctions with the aim of addressing these effects and striving to minimise them has become one of the priorities of the United Nations. There is a consensus among UN member states that standards for imposing sanctions need to be reformed, but there is strong disagreement on the scope that this reform should take and on the legal means of implementing such reforms: the type of legal framework that should be used and legal tools that could be utilized. The problems that the delegates in the Legal Committee of the MUN in Edinburgh predominantly focused their attention on were related to measures for insulating third parties from economic difficulties resulting from sanctions, as well to minimizing the adverse effects of sanctions on innocent populations. POSITION OF THE IRAQI DELEGATION IN THE WORLD MUN These issues are of extreme importance and sensitivity for the Iraqi government, given the fact that comprehensive sanctions were imposed on the country for the twelve years from 1990. The economic sanctions, though intended to be focused on the previous regime, did not have as a result the removal of the former Iraqi leadership or a change in its behaviour, but led to the immense suffering of the innocent population. The losses in terms of economic and social development and cohesion were huge. In this context Iraq acknowledges the vital role of the United Nations, and in particular its humanitarian commitment, which provided a lifeline to millions of Iraqis at that time. In order to prevent a catastrophe, which could have included epidemics and famine, the Oil for Food programme was established in 1995. Although the programme had contributed to arresting the decline and to improving the overall socio-economic conditions of the Iraqi people, it could not be considered a substitute for normal economic life. BACKGROUND TO THE ISSUE It is entirely within the competences of the Security Council of the United Nations to decide on the issue of the imposition of sanctions on a particular country: according to article 41 of the UN Charter “the Security Council may call upon Member States to apply measures not involving the use of armed force in order to maintain or restore international peace and security”. Such measures are commonly referred to as sanctions and may include a complete or partial interruption of economic relations and of rail, sea, air, postal, telegraphic, radio, and other means of communication, and the severance of diplomatic relations. The members of the Security Council deal with each case on an ad hoc basis. Iraq considers that all efforts should be made so that the legal basis for imposing sanctions may be improved in order to reduce the negative effects that sanctions may have on innocent populations and on non-targeted States. The present legal framework for imposing sanctions is not sufficient and is not precise enough to grasp the complexity of the issues that arise in this context. A detailed document, preferably with legal force, should be elaborated to meet these challenges. Given the difficulties and the long process of drafting and adopting and entering into force of a legally binding instrument, a document containing strong political commitment would be a positive step forward. Iraq confirms its attachment to the principle of equity with regard to the bearing of the burden of 14 sanctions. This requires the establishment of a special mechanism to safeguard the interests of neighbouring countries and of the main trading partners of the targeted country. Iraq believes that a sanctions regime should be focused and with minimal negative consequences. Targeted, or so-called ‘smart’ sanctions should become the regular tool of the Security Council. To that end, sanctions regimes should involve clearly defined objectives and criteria for determining that their purpose has been achieved. Being a political body, the Security Council must take care that objectivity does not yield to partisan interests. The application of sanctions should be monitored so as to measure their effect to enable the Security Council to fine tune them with a view to maximising their political impact and minimizing collateral damage. And, above all, the delivery of humanitarian assistance to vulnerable groups should be ensured. The basis for the debates in the Legal Committee of the World MUN was the draft Declaration on the basic conditions and standard criteria for the introduction and implementation of sanctions and other coercive measures contained in the Working paper of the Russian Federation. The Iraqi delegation expressed its general approval of the document, and in particular to the view that sanctions are an extreme measure which should have clear and precise objectives, be limited in time and be subject to regular review. Iraq especially shares the consideration that the concerns of the targeted State should be taken into account. But Iraq believes that the Secretariat should provide Security Council and sanctions committees with an assessment of the humanitarian and socioeconomic impact of sanctions not ‘at their request’, as the paper stipulates, but as a mandatory part of the process. CONTENT OF THE ADOPTED RESOLUTION Following heated discussions, a resolution was adopted by the delegates in the Legal Committee. The basis of the resolution was the proposed draft by a group of delegates from the Arab countries, including Iraq. The resolution encouraged the Security Council to consider the implementation of sanctions after extensive negotiations with the targeted state. It provided that sanctions should have explicit and clearly stipulated goals, which would allow for them to be limited in time. An advisory body is to be created under the UN Secretariat with analytical tasks and with the competence to observe and investigate the humanitarian and economic outcomes of existing sanctions and issue reports on the issues, which are publicly accessible. The resolution urges all Member States of the United Nations to pledge humanitarian assistance to the vulnerable populations of the targeted and third party states and recommended that the Commission on Human Rights (a functional body of the UN Economic and Social Council) include the topic of humanitarian effects of imposing sanctions and other coercive measures on its agenda. The Security Council is also encouraged to suspend sanctions in emergency situations which threaten to create humanitarian disasters. According to the provisions of the resolution, sanctions should not be open-ended and should be subject to periodic reviews. The Iraqi delegation to the Harvard World MUN supported the adoption of the resolution, given that its provisions reflected to a large extent its views on the issue of sanctions. WHERE TO FROM HERE? Ever wondered what your classmates will be doing after submitting their final dissertation (apart from falling down the stairs on their way home from the pub)? Beyond Globalisation and Development Keith Addenbrooke MA student in International Relations, University of Warwick I applied to Warwick to study Globalisation and Development because my career as a divisional finance director in a multi-national company (albeit an ailing one) had left me with questions that business alone could not answer. I will leave Warwick in the summer with some answers, more 15 questions, our third child, a lot less money and the chance to pursue a direction I believe in. In early May I learned that the Church of England is to sponsor me to train to be an Anglican priest. Although it is something I have wanted to do since I first made a commitment to Jesus Christ and the Christian faith when I was 11 years old, it is only now that I can step forward with any confidence that I can make some sense of the problems of the world and my small role within it! Although the contribution of faith and religion (both good and bad) has not been central to our syllabus, it is only in my faith that I can truly reconcile the persistent failure of secular Enlightenment thinking to resolve the problems of poverty, inequality and structural injustice with a belief in a God who created a world where it was intended that our brief sojourn here would be fulfilling. The African Growth and Opportunity Act (AGOA) is a trade act concerning 38 eligible countries in sub-Saharan Africa, with the aim of increasing export trade to the United States through the elimination of US tariffs on approximately 6,400 export products. For more information http://www.agoa.gov on AGOA, see As a destination, the priesthood will offer the exciting prospect of being able to apply what I have learnt in a community setting and while that may not shake the foundations of the present worldsystem, it will give me the chance to support the ordinary people who do extraordinary things day in and day out to try to make our world a better place. For, as Peter Newell, Shirin Rai and Andrew Scott observe in the introduction to their 2002 book, Development and the Challenge of Globalization, it is at the micro level that we understand the way in which globalisation manifests itself (p15). It is where I intend to be. References Newell, Peter; Rai, Shirin M.; Scott, Andrew (2002) Development and the Challenge of Globalization. London: ITDG. West African Trade Hub Abou Fall MA student in Globalisation and Development, University of Warwick I am supporting the West Africa Trade Hub (WATH), a USAID funded program based in Accra, Ghana, in planning programmed AGOA-related community outreach and training to six out of the 15 established AGOA Resource Centers (ARCs) in West Africa. This activity aims at enhancing awareness on the part of the business community of the potential benefits of exporting under AGOA and of available resources from the AGOA Resource Center. The final aim is to help West African businesses increase export trade to the United States, and within Africa. The Team JUSTINE COULTER (WGDS President) FABIANA ILLESCAS TALLEDO (Editor) MATHEW DOIDGE (Co-Editor and Technical Production) VULINDLELA NDLOVU (Co-Editor) Want to Contribute? Please e-mail queries and submissions to: FABIANA ILLESCAS TALLEDO F.Illescas-Talledo@Warwick.ac.uk 16