2. International economic law and development: before and after neoliberalism Julio Faundez* 1. INTRODUCTION Two features have characterised international economic law (IEL) during the recent period of rapid and seemingly unrestrained economic globalization: its emergence as the most important field of international law and its close association with the ruling paradigm of development, as embodied in the celebrated Washington Consensus. The rise to prominence of IEL is a novel development. Indeed, until recently, IEL rules were not regarded as real law, even by the undemanding standards of legal validity and efficacy applied by most international lawyers. As a consequence, courses devoted to general international law rarely covered IEL. Most international law treatises and textbooks either ignored it or dedicated only a short chapter noting that there were few rules in this area and that most of them were either not binding (such as the numerous rules in the GATT Agreement) or highly contested (such as those in the area of international investment law). From the 1980s, however, after the outbreak of the current wave of globalization, IEL underwent a massive transformation to become the most important field of international law. Its importance is confirmed by three different measures: volume, scope and efficacy. The volume of new international economic rules is reflected in the large number of multilateral and bilateral treaties on matters relating to trade, finance and investment and in the numerous decisions by international economic organisations and other bodies that set standards and voluntary codes in areas as varied as banking, corporate governance and food standards. The scope of IEL rules, perhaps one of its most novel and distinctive characteristics, is related to the extent to which the rules address matters hitherto regarded * Professor of Law, School of Law, University of Warwick, Coventry, UK. ­10 m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 10 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­11 as part of the exclusive domestic jurisdiction of states. The greater efficacy of IEL rules is reflected in the significant improvements in their enforceability, due to the establishment of numerous international tribunals with jurisdiction to resolve international economic law disputes. Thus, today, there are more IEL rules and they reach deeper into the national policy­making process and are taken seriously because they are more readily enforced. The prominence achieved by IEL in the late twentieth century is noteworthy because, throughout the 1960s and 1970s, developing countries tried, unsuccessfully, to make use of international legal institutions to support their development efforts. At the time, most developing countries relied on a development model in which the state played a leading role in steering the economy. By the 1980s, however, developing countries began to embrace a set of IEL rules predicated upon a radically different model: one that is based on the principles of neo-­liberalism and drastically restricts the role of the state and transfers control over key economic decisions to international agencies or to markets. This model of development is generally known as the Washington Consensus. In the areas of trade and investment liberalisation, economic deregulation and protection of property rights, IEL rules and institutions faithfully reflect the Washington Consensus. This is precisely the reason why today most governments and international legal scholars take IEL seriously and why anti-­globalization activists deride it. This set of principles has also provided the basis for the emergence of a new economic paradigm for developing countries. Indeed, according to leading proponents of globalization, the rapid economic integration of the world economy has made it necessary to harmonise rules and standards in order to create a level playing field. These rules and standards – largely derived from economic science – have been applied to all states across the world regardless of their level of economic development. This approach is justified, according to Larry Summers – the influential US economist, policy-­maker and former chief economist of the World Bank – because the rules of economics are like laws of engineering: one set of rules works everywhere (Klein, 2009). IEL has thus become the main vehicle through which the principles of the Washington Consensus have been translated into international binding rules and policies. The recently acquired status of IEL in international law is also significant because the set of rules that currently govern the world economy seem to be slowly departing from traditional assumptions underlying the conceptual framework of international law. While hitherto international law has relied on the consent of states to legitimise its rules and institutions, today IEL rules and practices have become increasingly removed from m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 11 2/8/10 14:43:02 12 IEL, globalization and developing countries the notion that the consent of states is a prerequisite for the validity and enforceability of international law. A more powerful source of legitimation for IEL rules seems to be the imperative of global economic integration and the needs and interests of the leading developed states and international power brokers. Thus, for example, today it is not easy to discern a clear link between the profuse number of conditionalities imposed on developing countries and the traditional view that under international law states are only bound by rules that they freely accept. Regardless of whether this development signals the demise of state sovereignty, as some observers suggest, it is interesting to note that the current transformation of IEL has been accompanied by a revealing shift in the description of states and the content of IEL rules. States are now often no longer referred to as actors, but merely as economies; those that are successful are described as emerging economies and those that are not are either ignored or described as failing or fragile. Likewise, IEL rules, along with numerous decisions of questionable legal validity, are described as disciplines, thus suggesting that states no longer enjoy the prerogative of opting out of international rules. It is also revealing that the rhetoric employed by developed states and by international economic organisations suggests that one of the main purposes of IEL rules is to ‘lock in’ the process of structural reform that these states are supposed to implement so as to ensure that chronically volatile developing states do not undermine the predictability and stability of the word economy. This view of IEL rules as a straightjacket could well be a reasonable economic expectation for leading private international economic actors; but its political and legal implications are, if not dangerous, at least a matter for serious concern. The notion of IEL as a straightjacket for developing countries also raises the inevitable question of what will happen to IEL if, as is likely, the financial crisis of 2008 gives way to a new development paradigm. Will IEL shift back towards a more state-­centred approach to development? If so, will developing countries be in a position to make use of international legal institutions to further their interests? Or, will they focus instead on politics and diplomacy rather than law? The rapid ascent of IEL and its link to the prevailing development paradigm undoubtedly raises an array of complex and highly contested theoretical and empirical questions. The purpose of this chapter is to contribute towards the clarification of some of these questions. Its three main objectives are: (1) to explain IEL’s evolving approach to development during the past five decades; (2) to identify the impact that globalization has had on the foundations of international economic law and reflect upon its likely impact on developing countries; and (3) to identify contemporary legal and political trends that may provide clues to discerning how the m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 12 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­13 relationship between IEL and development is likely to evolve in the post­Washington Consensus period. 2. THE POST-­WAR SETTLEMENT AND IMPORT SUBSTITUTION (1950–80) The post-­war settlement brought about the establishment of the United Nations, the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (hereafter, the Bretton Woods institutions) and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT). This institutional framework was based upon two main pillars: the prohibition of the use of force (UN Charter: Art. 2 (4)), unless duly authorised by the UN Security Council; and the notion that the international community had a duty to promote peaceful social and economic change, in order to maintain peace and security. Under the Charter, the prohibition of the use of force is balanced by a clear understanding that the international community has a special responsibility for improving social and economic conditions throughout the world so as to create conditions for political stability and thus prevent conflicts between and within states. Seen from this perspective, the political and economic objectives of the post-­war settlement were inseparable, which explains why the UN Charter is committed to achieving both objectives at the same time. Economic and social development was thus an essential component of the post-­war settlement. The grand political objectives reflected in the UN Charter were not achieved. The cold war, which divided the world into two irreconcilable camps, undermined the ideal that the UN would centralise the use of force and generated instead a network of regional security pacts that were concerned with political stability rather than development. Moreover, the reluctance of some colonial powers to accept the principle of self­determination brought about a wave of wars of national liberation that divided members of the UN and distracted the attention of the organisation away from economic affairs. After the completion of the process of decolonisation, however, the newly independent states in Africa, Asia and the Caribbean, together with other developing countries, joined forces to create a powerful political bloc at the United Nations. The objective of this bloc (later loosely identified as the Group of 77) was to enlist international law and institutions in support of their members’ quest for social and economic development. Between 1950 and 1980 most developing countries assigned to the state a strong role in economic development. In this capacity, the state was actively involved in promoting the establishment of a manufacturing base m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 13 2/8/10 14:43:02 14 IEL, globalization and developing countries and modernising the agricultural sector, often through the redistribution of land. These goals were not easy to achieve. Chronic shortage of foreign exchange made it difficult for developing countries to import the required capital goods. Moreover, local industries had difficulties competing with imported goods from more advanced countries. Most developing countries therefore began implementing, albeit in different ways and at different speeds, an economic policy that came to be known as import substitution. This policy was based on the simple idea that, rather than wasting scarce foreign exchange on imported products that only the rich could afford, the state should, through an array of regulatory mechanisms, provide incentives for the development of local manufacturing capacity. The implementation of this policy required a commercial policy that today would be regarded as protectionist but which was then regarded as essential in order successfully to secure national development objectives. The Bretton Woods institutions, though ultimately committed to a liberal international economic system (Frieden, 2006), did not stand in the way of the implementation of import substitution strategies. On the contrary, the World Bank actively contributed to strengthening the economic capacity of states through technical assistance and grants aimed at strengthening the economic infrastructure of developing countries. The IMF, which allowed and encouraged countries to maintain capital controls, ensured, through pegged but adjustable exchange rates, that balance of payments deficits did not cause disruptions to the regular flow of international payments. The GATT, which at the time focused mainly on reducing tariffs in industrial goods, was not overly concerned with the plight of developing countries. Indeed, in the 1950s, the GATT was described as a rich man’s club. In any event, GATT rules on subsidies and other forms of state support were both vague and flexible and thus did not stand in the way of import substitution policies. Moreover, by the late 1960s, new GATT rules were adopted that exempted products from developing countries from the most-­favoured-­nation principle so that those countries could enjoy preferential access to the markets of industrialised countries (Bartels, 2007). During this period, developing countries focused their attention on two major objectives: first, strengthening their capacity to control the exploitation of their natural resources and consequently to assert their right to regulate multinational companies operating in the sector; and second, ensuring access to modern technology in order to support and further develop their efforts to implement the policy of import substitution. Disputes over the right of developing countries to control their natural resources, and in particular whether they could nationalise the assets of companies operating in this sector, were prevalent during most of the m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 14 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­15 twentieth century (Sornarajah, 1994: 294). At the international legal level there was no consensus on how to resolve these disputes. Although developed countries conceded that developing countries had a right to nationalise, they insisted, nonetheless, that international law required them to pay prompt, adequate and effective compensation. They also claimed that regulatory measures implemented by developing countries constituted indirect expropriation and, as such, also required prompt, adequate and effective compensation (Weston, 1975). The views between developed and developing countries on this issue remained far apart throughout this period. Indeed, in 1964, the US Supreme Court, in the celebrated Sabbatino case,1 candidly acknowledged that this was an area in which the law was unsettled since capital exporting and capital importing countries held widely conflicting views. As a consequence, disputes over the regulation of natural resources were largely handled diplomatically, culminating often in different forms of external intervention, which sometimes led to the overthrow of governments that insisted on their right to nationalise foreign-­owned property (Iran 1952, Guatemala 1954, Chile 1973). Transfer of technology was another issue that concerned developing countries. The devastating political and economic impact of colonialism on countries that had recently become independent was felt sharply in the area of technology. Colonial powers were not, in general, concerned with education and as a result, upon independence, there was a dramatic lack of suitably qualified people either to run the economy or to organise modern manufacturing firms. Indeed, during the period of colonialism before the Second World War, only 12 out of more than 100 developing countries had achieved enough know-­how to be classified as experienced manufacturers (Amsden, 2007: 37). The urgent need to have access to technology was also sharply felt by Latin American countries, even though they had achieved independence in the first half of the nineteenth century. Although some of the latter countries had made significant progress in the implementation of state-­led import substitution policies, they soon found that their capacity to further develop their manufacturing base was impeded by their lack of technology. During the 1960s and 1970s developing countries tried, unsuccessfully, to lobby for the adoption of new rules of international economic law that reflected their interests and development priorities. In this context, the United Nations General Assembly, where developing countries held the majority of seats, provided them with a unique platform to discuss and promote their views. This process resulted in the adoption 1 Banco Nacional de Cuba v. Sabbatino (1964) 376 US 398. m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 15 2/8/10 14:43:02 16 IEL, globalization and developing countries of several General Assembly resolutions, including the Resolution on Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources, the Declaration of the Establishment of a New Economic Order, the Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States and the Declaration on International Investment and Multinational Enterprises (Cox, 1979; Weston, 1981). These Resolutions and Declarations were not formally binding, and not one made its way into the labyrinth of customary international law. Nonetheless, these Declarations and Resolutions provided the basis for the development of more structured charters on the regulation of multinationals (Draft Code of Conduct on Transnational Corporations, prepared by the UN Economic and Social Council) and on the regulation of transfer of technology (prepared by UN Conference on Trade and Development, UNCTAD). These two Codes underwent interminable discussions within the UN, but were never formally approved (for the text of these draft codes and declarations, see Weston et al., 1990). The provisions on natural resources, foreign investment and technology transfer contained in the Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States capture the essence of the aspirations of developing countries during this period (Weston et al., 1990: 568). Article 2 (1) reaffirms the principle that states can freely exercise full sovereignty over their natural resources and economic activities. Article 2 (2) sets out in detail the rights that derive from a state’s sovereignty over natural resources and economic activity. These rights include the right to regulate foreign investment in accordance with its own laws; the right to regulate the activities of multinational companies operating within its jurisdiction; and the right to nationalise foreign-­owned property, subject to appropriate compensation determined by its own laws and reviewed by its own courts. Article 2 also provides that no state shall be required to grant preferential treatment to foreign investment and that multinationals should refrain from intervening in the internal affairs of host states. In the area of technology, the Charter (Art. 13) proclaims the right of every state to benefit from advances in technology for the purpose of furthering its economic and social development. It calls upon states to facilitate the transfer of technology for the benefit of developing countries and, in particular, it calls upon developed states to support the scientific and technological infrastructure of developing countries. Transfer of technology is defined in the UNCTAD Draft (1.2) as ‘the transfer of systematic knowledge for the manufacture of a product, for the application of a process or for the rendering of a service and does not extend to the transactions involving the mere sale or mere lease of goods’ (Weston et al., 1990: 585). The UNCTAD Draft also purported to prohibit restrictive business practices often associated with the transfer of m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 16 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­17 technology, such as exclusive dealing, restrictions on research and tying arrangements. 3. TOWARDS THE WASHINGTON CONSENSUS Attempts by developing countries to influence the content of IEL were unsuccessful. Today, the UN Resolutions and Codes drafted during this period have long been forgotten and many observers would probably regard them as politically quaint, economically barmy or the product of misguided economic nationalism (Krasner, 1985: 6–11, 299; Pauwelyn, 2005b: 42; Finger, 2008). Yet, it is worth remembering that in terms of economic outcomes the policy of import substitution was quite successful. Indeed, between 1950 and 1980, the period when this policy was applied, developing countries experienced an unprecedented expansion in living standards and per capita income that brought about an important decline in levels of poverty. During this period income in developing countries grew at a rate of 5 per cent. During this same period income in developed countries grew at a rate of 4 per cent (Amsden, 2007: 6; Yusuf, 2009: 9–11). It is therefore necessary to ask whether IEL rules played any role in the achievement of these good economic outcomes. It is clear from the account in the previous section that IEL rules did not play a direct role in securing the positive economic outcomes during the period 1950–80. Ironically, however, these positive outcomes can be rightly attributed to the fact that international economic institutions and rules provided developing countries with space to experiment with a variety of economic policies aimed at securing a more solid and competitive productive base. As Alice Amsden notes, the GATT allowed developing countries to deviate from the principles of free trade in order to build their national economies (Amsden, 2007:48). Thus, although the international trading system was liberal, developing countries were allowed to customise their policies and formulate their own industrial policies, protect the industries that they wanted to promote and exercise strict controls on foreign direct investment. The international monetary system, which did not require or encourage financial liberalisation, complemented the prevailing flexible international trading system. Thus in many respects, the notion of ‘embedded liberalism’ used by John Ruggie to describe the post-­war settlement among developed countries also applies to developing countries because, although the rules of IEL adhered in principle to liberal multilateralism, the prevailing system allowed developing countries to deviate from this principle for the sake of strengthening their economies and ensuring the stability of their political institutions (Ruggie, 1982: 397, 413). m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 17 2/8/10 14:43:02 18 IEL, globalization and developing countries The flexible system of international economic rules that allowed developing countries to liberalise at their own pace did not last. By the 1970s, as the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates collapsed and competition in trade and investment among industrialised countries intensified, the institutions of the world economy came under severe stress. In addition, the emergence of multinational companies as the leading economic agents in the world economy began to make nation states appear politically and economically outdated (Dunning, 1993). From the perspective of multinational companies, the division of the world into territorial units with diverse and conflicting regulatory frameworks was inefficient. It was an unnecessary political barrier that impeded the free flow of capital and goods. Since calling for the elimination of national legal systems was not practical, multinationals lobbied vigorously and successfully to secure uniform international standards in key areas of international trade, investment and intellectual property. Along with the spread of multinationals, other factors, such as the revolutionary developments in information technology and improvements in transport and telecommunications, also contributed to strengthening the demand for a more uniform system of economic regulation throughout the world. Changes in the organisation of production and the emergence of new technology were undoubtedly critically important in making the relatively flexible and benign rules of IEL of the post-­war settlement appear out of date. Nevertheless, there were also a variety of political decisions that, in combination with other developments, contributed to bringing about a new set of rules. By the late 1970s the United States had become increasingly frustrated by the GATT’s inability to make significant progress in the elimination of non-­tariff barriers or to develop a robust approach in the regulation of unfair trade practices (dumping and subsidies). Instead of comprehensive regulations in these areas, the GATT had developed a series of Codes that were binding only on countries that chose to accept them. The regulatory fragmentation generated by this approach was exacerbated by the fact that the leading trading nations began to look for solutions to their urgent commercial policy problems outside the framework of the GATT, resorting to a variety of devices including voluntary export restrictions, orderly marketing arrangements and special treaties that controlled the flow of products into certain markets through quotas. It is thus not surprising that, at the time, this state of affairs was described by some commentators as managed protectionism, and one of the leading trade law scholars argued that the institutions of world trade were crumbling (Jackson, 1978). Whether or not these assessments were correct, there is little doubt that by the late 1970s and early 1980s the world trading system was rapidly moving away from the ideal of multilat- m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 18 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­19 eralism embodied in the GATT. This unfortunate state of affairs was made worse by the policy of the US Government to resort to unilateral measures in order to protect its economic interests by imposing or threatening the imposition of sanctions on countries that had laws or practices which, in the view of the US President, unjustifiably restricted US commerce. This policy, characterised as aggressive unilateralism (Bhagwati and Patrick, 1990), was vigorously used to open up markets to US exports and to protect intellectual property rights held by US multinationals (Chorev, 2005: 333). 4. BRINGING IN NEW RULES The United States policy of aggressive unilateralism was combined with a more positive and dynamic policy aimed at persuading developing countries to accept the longstanding views held by the US and other capital exporting countries regarding the protection of foreign-­owned property. This policy led to the establishment of an extensive network of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) with developing countries (Vandevelde, 2000). The US policy on BITs was soon replicated by most capital exporting countries and by the end of 2007 there were over 2,600 BITs in force. This process brought about a major shift away from the views that developing countries had supported during the period leading up to the approval of the Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States. The US and other developed countries did not, however, focus only on bilateral solutions. They also used their financial clout and political influence within the United Nations to prevent developing countries using the UN as a political platform to rally support for their views on development. Thus, for example, the New York based UN Centre on Transnational Corporations (UNCTC) – which, since 1974, had been instrumental in supporting developing countries in their negotiations with multinational companies and had taken an active role in preparing the draft Code of Conduct on Multinationals – was transferred to UNCTAD in Geneva in 1993 with a smaller budget and reduced staff.2 UNCTAD itself, which had been established by developing countries to ensure that the international trade agenda did not neglect the overriding importance of development issues, was marginalised as the IMF and the World Bank began to assume a prominent role in steering the process of development (Love, 2001). The two large oil price increases in the 1970s, which were followed 2 See http://unctc.unctad.org/aspx/index.aspx (accessed 28 August 2009). m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 19 2/8/10 14:43:02 20 IEL, globalization and developing countries by the debt crisis of the 1980s, exposed, once again, the vulnerability of developing countries to the vagaries of the world economy. The sequence of events is well known. The large OPEC surpluses (petro-­dollars) were recycled by the private banking system in the form of low-­interest-­rate loans to developing countries. Since the loans were cheap, many developing countries borrowed excessive amounts and were not careful to ensure that the investments procured by the loans would generate adequate surpluses. Thus, when in the late 1970s interest rates shot up and there was a second sharp rise in oil prices, the world economy faced a serious recession, which had a devastating impact on developing countries (Cline, 1995). These circumstances provided the IMF and the World Bank with a unique opportunity to persuade developing countries to abandon their state-­led development polices and to embrace instead market-­friendly policies (Woods, 2006: 53). The mechanisms used by the Bretton Woods institutions have varied over the years (see Tan, Chapter 6 in this volume), but they have all included conditionalities, which generally involve soft loans in exchange for the implementation of policy reform. The initial programmes of policy-­based lending were embodied in the notorious Structural Adjustment Loans, which exchanged badly needed finance for the implementation of policy measures aimed at reducing the role of the state, releasing market forces and reducing the discretion of politicians (Mosley et al., 1991a: 40–45; Babb, 2005). These structural adjustment policies soon became the new paradigm for development and, in the 1990s, were christened the Washington Consensus by an insightful economist (Williamson, 1990b). The policies prescribed by the Washington Consensus included fiscal discipline, tax reform, interest rate liberalisation, trade liberalisation, liberalisation of inward foreign direct investment, reduction and redirection of public expenditure, deregulation, privatisation and security of property rights. These policies were never agreed by all states, but they enjoyed the support of the US Treasury, the US Federal Reserve Board and the two Bretton Woods institutions (Williamson, 2000: 257). They were imposed on developing countries by the Bretton Woods institutions through a range of formal and informal mechanisms, which some observers describe as soft law (Alvarez, 2005). Political and economic pressure on developing countries by the United States and other developed countries also played an important role in spreading Washington Consensus policies throughout the world. The World Bank claimed that these policies were a sound alternative to the policies of import substitution, which had given far too much discretion to corrupt politicians, usually captured by narrow interest groups (World Bank, 2005a: 6). Despite its obscure political origins, its problematic mode of implementation and questionable rationalisation, the Washington m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 20 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­21 Consensus soon became the overriding constitutional framework for IEL. In the terminology used by Hans Kelsen’s positivist legal theory, the Washington Consensus became the ‘basic law’ of the world economy (Kelsen, 1967). The completion of the Uruguay Round and the establishment of the WTO is a landmark in the process of implementation of the Washington Consensus. Indeed, after a long period of bitter wrangling and interminable arguments the international community approved, in 1995, several related agreements that brought to an end debates that had plagued the GATT for several years. The Single Undertaking brought under one roof the reformed GATT Agreement of 1947, and agreements regulating unfair trade practices, safeguards, non-­tariff barriers, trade in services, trade­related investment measures and intellectual property. It also established a unified dispute settlement system for all these agreements so that in any particular dispute any of these agreements can be considered by the adjudicating bodies – Panels and Appellate Body. The Uruguay Round also made it easier for complaining parties to establish a Panel and, through a reverse consensus rule, made the adoption of Panel and Appellate Body reports virtually automatic. The judicialisation of international trade disputes is generally regarded as the single most important achievement of the Uruguay Round (Jackson, 2008: 444). Equally, significant, however, is the fact that some of the key provisions of the Uruguay Round Agreement effectively made import substitution policies illegal: the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures prohibits subsidies contingent upon the use of domestic over imported products; the Agreement on Trade Related Investment Measures prohibits states to require foreign enterprises to use products produced locally or to set limits to the importation of products linked to the value or volume of local products that they export; and the TRIPS Agreement does not allow compulsory licensing for the purpose of furthering home-­grown industrial policies. The cumulative effect of these provisions has brought about a qualitative change that clearly distinguishes the WTO from the old GATT. While obligations under the old GATT were based on the reciprocal exchange of concessions among the Contracting Parties, the WTO has moved towards a more regulatory stance under which its rules are more prescriptive and not subject to negotiation. Thus, not surprisingly, WTO obligations are now referred to as disciplines, underlining the fact that the possibility of flexibly opting in and out of rules and procedures – a typical feature of the old GATT – is no longer available. This is one of the reasons why even ardent advocates of free trade have come to regard WTO structures as unworkable (Sally, 2007: 39). m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 21 2/8/10 14:43:02 22 IEL, globalization and developing countries The determination to deepen the implementation of the Washington Consensus did not come to an end with the approval of the WTO Agreements in 1995. Indeed, such was the perceived success of the single undertaking approach employed at the Uruguay Round that the OECD attempted to replicate it in the area of international investment. This attempt took the form of a draft multilateral agreement on investment (MAI) that was meant to consolidate, in a single treaty, the rules and principles designed to protect foreign investors currently scattered in hundreds of bilateral investment treaties. In theory, securing the approval of the MAI initiative should have been easy, since the proposed treaty was intended, in the first instance, to include only members of the OECD and the vast majority of its provisions were no longer controversial, having already been accepted by most states in the numerous BITs. Unexpectedly, however, the MAI initiative generated such enormous controversy that its sponsors decided to abandon it (Henderson, 1999). This setback did not, however, diminish the zeal of those who were keen to further pursue the implementation of the Washington Consensus. Indeed, since the WTO turned out to be a hopelessly inefficient mechanism for negotiating new rules, developed countries opted for the bilateral route. A massive wave of Regional Trade Agreements (hereafter RTAs) therefore emerged, which, as well as further liberalising trade between treaty partners, introduced new rules (disciplines) in areas where the WTO had been unable to make progress. These new obligations, also known as Singapore issues – which developing countries refused to accept at the Singapore Ministerial Conference in December 1996 – include commitments in areas such as the environment, competition policy, labour standards, international investment and intellectual property (Whalley, 2006: 16; Heydon and Woolcock, 2009). In the area of intellectual property, some bilateral agreements require developing countries to introduce higher standards of protection than those required by the TRIPS Agreement (see Roffe, Chapter 14 in this volume). For example, the US–Jordan Treaty of 2000 establishes a free trade area and also provides for extensive protection of inventions in all fields of technology without taking into account the exceptions envisaged in the TRIPS Agreement (Art. 27.3(b)) (UNCTAD-­ICTSD, 2003: 52, 60). This process has led to the emergence of a vastly complex network of bilateral treaties – described by some as a Spaghetti Bowl – that create special bilateral regimes, which are slowly eroding the WTO’s cherished principle of multilateralism and have the potential to create considerable political and legal confusion as many states find themselves subject to conflicting obligations (Baldwin, 2006: 1508; Bhagwati, 2008). As globalization intensified and the implementation of policies of eco- m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 22 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­23 nomic liberalisation in developing countries encountered difficulties, the agenda of the Washington Consensus expanded to include a variety of issues that fell within the general framework of governance. The addition of governance to the original Washington Consensus has further widened the jurisdictional domain of international economic law, thus bringing about a further reduction of what international lawyers generally regard as areas that are primarily within the domestic jurisdiction of states (Faundez, 2003). Indeed, today, the World Bank and other international organisations have unilaterally assumed jurisdiction to decide whether the quality of governance in individual states is consistent with accepted minimum international standards. These minimum standards have not been agreed by states and are based broadly on Anglo-­American notions of law and administration (Kapur, 1998: 8). Following this newly acquired power, the World Bank and other international organisations have began to judge whether domestic institutions are adequate for the implementation of the policies prescribed by the Washington Consensus. Although IEL rules have not yet formally authorised the World Bank or the IMF to determine when a complete overhaul of domestic institutions is required (regime change), the persistent use of concepts such as fragile and failed states suggests that this could well be the next stage in the process. In any event, regardless of whether or not the World Bank has the power to compel countries to follow standards of governance consistent with the original principles of the Washington Consensus, industrialised countries have already made use of their superior economic power to persuade developing countries to make changes in their standards of governance. To this end, developed countries have made prolific use of the Generalised System of Preferences, which dates back to the 1970s, to ensure that developing countries comply with governance standards. India recently challenged some aspects of the EU preferential trade programme that it deemed discriminatory. The Appellate Body upheld India’s challenge on the ground that the EU’s programme did not represent a positive response to an objective development need of the beneficiaries. The EU introduced changes to its programme, but its revised programme is also flawed since, while one of the conditions for eligibility is that the countries should be vulnerable, vulnerability is not defined in terms of the objective needs of the beneficiaries but in terms of their share of EU imports. The revised programme also requires states that wish to benefit from the programme to ratify several human rights conventions, which are not linked to any objective development need (Bartels, 2007: 742). The United States also uses its GSP programme to persuade developing countries to sign treaties and adopt legislation that they would not have otherwise accepted or enacted (Jones, 2006). It also makes use of pre-­negotiation agreements, m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 23 2/8/10 14:43:02 24 IEL, globalization and developing countries also known as Trade and Investment Framework Agreements (TIFAs), to persuade countries interested in entering into RTAs to introduce legislative and institutional changes (UNCTAD, 2008b). They are very effective since conditions imposed through bilateral treaties are tailored to suit the trading and commercial interests of the US. They are also easy to monitor and verify. Bilateral conditionalities therefore complement and reinforce the policies pursued by the World Bank and the IMF. From a developing country perspective, the current international economic legal system is flawed for the following five reasons. First, most developing countries have little or no influence in the decision-­making processes of international economic organisations, especially in the IMF and the World Bank. Moreover, even in organisations such as the WTO, in which all countries formally have the same power to influence decisions, most developing countries effectively have no input in the decision-­making process as developed countries employ a series of informal devices and subterfuges to exclude them (Jawara and Kwa, 2003: 305; Gathii, 2006). Second, today, international economic institutions, such as the World Bank and the IMF, have assumed an inordinate amount of control over key economic policy and governance decisions of developing countries through the imposition of various forms of conditionalities and the exercise of surveillance powers (Woods, 2006). Third, even in cases where developing countries are formally equal counterparts in the formulation of IEL rules (as is the case of bilateral investment treaties between developed and developing countries), the reciprocal obligations established by these treaties are, in fact, vastly unequal. Indeed, while both parties agree to protect the investment of the other party’s nationals in their territory, in reality, investment flows in only one direction – from developed to developing country. These treaty obligations, though formally symmetrical, therefore ensure that the standards of one of the parties are respected by the other. The process of negotiation of these treaties further confirms their asymmetrical nature. Indeed, these treaties are based on Model Treaties drafted by lawyers in the Foreign Offices of developed countries and leave developing countries very little room for negotiation (Schneiderman, 2000; Singh, 2001). Fourth, the recent expansion of IEL-­based international adjudication has been loaded in favour of private-­sector actors, as key decisions in international investment and trade disputes are mainly handled by arbitrators and panellists whose expertise is mainly in private and commercial law (as is the case of ICSID) or in specialised areas of international trade (as is the case of WTO Panels). These experts often lack the necessary knowledge, experience or inclination fully to assess the wider national and m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 24 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­25 international public policy implications of the issues arising from cases submitted to them. Fifth, in the absence of explicit IEL rules, many areas of international economic relations are governed by standards that are designed either by small groupings of powerful states, such as the G-­7, the G-­8, and more recently the G-­20, or by inter-­governmental organisations in which developing countries have little or no influence (Schneider, 2005). There is little doubt that under the current international economic legal system developing countries are, in general, ‘rule takers’, rather than active agents in framing legal rules. There are, of course, many areas in which developing countries have made good use of and achieved benefits from the new IEL rules. Indeed, some countries have successfully defended their rights through the WTO dispute settlement mechanism (such as the case of Brazil and cotton subsidies; see Cross, 2006); others have benefited from the use of provisions of the GATS to exploit their comparative advantages (such as India and outsourcing; see Jensen and Kletzer, 2008); and developing countries successfully campaigned to persuade the WTO to adopt a Declaration on the TRIPS Agreement and Public Health that restates that countries have the right, under the TRIPS Agreement, to grant compulsory licences to protect public health (UNCTAD-­ICTSD, 2003: 16). Yet, for developing countries as a whole, the current framework of IEL rules is not an unqualified success. The economic performance of developing countries during the upsurge of globalization in 1980 has been disappointing, especially when compared with the levels of growth achieved during the preceding thirty years. Indeed, while developing countries’ income grew at an average rate of 5 per cent between 1950 and 1980, average growth rates dropped to barely 3 per cent between 1980 and 2000. These average figures conceal, of course, significant variations. India and China, which opened their economies but did not apply the Washington Consensus, have registered spectacular growth rates, while other developing countries in Latin America and Africa, which followed the Washington Consensus and/or were subjected to strict structural adjustment programmes, registered average growth rates below 3 per cent (Amsden, 2007: 6, quoting World Development Report 2002 Development Indicators). These figures show, contrary to the views of some observers (IMF, 2007: 135–70), that unrestrained globalization has not been an unqualified success for developing countries. It is also unclear whether globalization has brought about an overall reduction in inequality, either in terms of the relationship between developed and developing countries or in terms of poverty reduction within countries (Sutcliffe, 2004; Wade, 2004). m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 25 2/8/10 14:43:02 26 IEL, globalization and developing countries 5. HAS IEL GONE TOO FAR? The fact that developing countries have not played a major role in shaping the form and content of IEL rules is not surprising. After all, they have never played a major role in shaping events in the world economy. In recent years, however, developing countries have been under enormous political and economic pressure to ‘globalize’, and IEL rules have played a crucial role in this process. The problem, however, is that many of the new IEL rules have come into being through mechanisms (such as conditionality) that do not fit comfortably with the traditional notion that binding rules of international law are created by the consent of states. Also, many of the new IEL rules have penetrated so deeply into the fabric of what has previously been considered the domestic jurisdiction of states (the issue of policy space) that questions are rightly raised about the impact of globalization on the foundations of international law and state sovereignty. These questions have been widely debated among social scientists and legal theorists and no consensus has yet emerged on this issue. This debate is relevant to this chapter because it is premised on the problematic assumption that IEL is a coherent and systematic system of rules. Before testing this assumption, however, it is necessary to offer an overview, albeit schematic, of the way some social scientists and legal theorists have addressed the question concerning the wider relationship between sovereignty, globalization and international law. The impact of globalization on state sovereignty has been noted by most international relations specialists, political economists and international lawyers. While economists do not generally address issues relating to international law or state sovereignty, some ideologues of globalization regard the advent of globalization as inevitable, thus highlighting the economic logic of this process while downplaying the role of international law and political bargaining (Friedman, 1999; Wolf, 2004). Political scientists and lawyers sceptical about normative concepts such as sovereignty argue that the focus for a proper understanding of the world economy should be on the political and economic interests of the leading players in the world economy, rather than on empty normative concepts (Krasner, 1999; Goldsmith and Posner, 2005). Those who hold this view about international relations are also sceptical about international law and, as a consequence, are not overly concerned about the impact of globalization on its foundations. There are, of course, many social scientists who take more seriously the impact of globalization on sovereignty and international law. Within this group, some regard globalization as a positive factor insofar as it may be the prelude to a world order in which citizens are part of a larger cosmo- m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 26 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­27 politan order (Pogge, 2002: 168; Held, 2004; Habermas, 2006). These theorists, however, do not address difficult issues such as the sources of law or the structure of the institutions in the new cosmopolitan order. Theorists who take a less sanguine approach to the current process of international economic norm setting describe the process as coercive socialisation (Hurrell, 2007: 212), neo-­colonialism (Mutua, 2000; Anghie, 2006) or simply a new form of imperialism (Chimni, 2004). International lawyers have adopted a variety of approaches to interpret and conceptualise the impact of globalization on IEL and international law generally. Most of these approaches have been pragmatic insofar as they attempt to incorporate the momentous changes that have taken place in recent years into the current international law discourse. José Alvarez (2005), for example, in an extremely well-­documented study, provides unambiguous evidence that, in recent years, international organisations have taken an expansive and often careless approach to the creation of international law rules and notes that this process is effectively changing the meaning of national sovereignty. A more ambitious attempt to wrestle with the abundance and complexity of new international economic rules is found in the work of lawyers who have sought to apply principles and techniques of administrative law to interpreting the emerging IEL regulatory framework (Kingsbury et al., 2005). This approach is valuable insofar as it provides enormous data on the rapid spread of IEL rules and raises important questions about overall political and legal implications. The weakness of this approach is that it assumes that the political problem of legitimacy generated by the current process of economic globalization can be resolved by applying principles and techniques of domestic administrative law originating mainly in Europe and the United States. It thus fails to take into account that, although in domestic settings administrative law is an essential feature of the rule of law, a good and efficient system of administrative law presupposes a strong and legitimate political system, something that is sadly missing at the international level. Some international lawyers, observing that globalization has undermined the old-­fashioned, state-­led diplomatic process for making and interpreting international law, have opted for pragmatic solutions that change the focus of analysis. Thus, Anne Marie Slaughter (2004a, 2004b), for example, points out that the role of established professional diplomats has now been taken over by governmental and non-­governmental experts who are controlling and driving the process of norm creation at the international level. In order to ensure that the leading actors in this network do a good job, international lawyers should develop creative mechanisms of accountability to control their activities. This approach does not, m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 27 2/8/10 14:43:02 28 IEL, globalization and developing countries however, address the issue regarding the transformation of sovereignty under the impact of globalization nor the impact of this transformation on the role of developing countries in the emerging international economic legal order. Instead, working on the assumption that the spread of worldwide economic liberalism is inevitable, it seeks to provide lawyers with a technical perspective in order to make networks accountable, thus enhancing the legitimacy of this process. Not all lawyers, however, take such a complacent view. Ernst-­Ulrich Petersmann (2002b, 2008), for example, is keenly aware that the legal and political foundations of the current process of economic globalization are weak. Noting that there is a manifest incoherence between the principles of the WTO that focus on free trade and some international human rights instruments that have a distinct anti-­market bias, he calls for a radical approach to ensure simultaneous and timely respect of all human rights – economic, political and social – both at national and international levels. He calls this approach multi-­level constitutionalism and argues that in order to achieve it the international community should adopt the European Union’s approach to economic integration. Petersmann’s proposal has provoked a lively and unexpectedly acrimonious response from prominent members of the international human rights community (Alston, 2002; Howse, 2002; Petersmann, 2002a; see also Picciotto, 2003). Most international lawyers have focused their attention on rationalising and explaining international legal development and have refrained from directly addressing the delicate question of state sovereignty (but see Schachter, 1997; Lauterpacht, 1997). One of the most prominent international lawyers, the late Robert Jennings, has offered a powerful defence of the continuing validity of the notion of sovereignty (Jennings, 2002). A more qualified defence of sovereignty is offered by John Jackson, a leading IEL specialist. He argues that sovereignty should be renamed and redefined. He proposes to call it ‘sovereignty modern’ so as to take into account the fact that not all contemporary rules of international economic law can trace their origin to the consent of states (Jackson, 2003, 2006). Jackson’s argument, though interesting, is unpersuasive. He does not clearly explain which international rules do not require the consent of all the states, nor does he explain where and how these rules originate. Thus, his objective of redefining sovereignty does not succeed. It amounts to little more than a gentle plea for the peaceful co-­existence of traditional international law with a so-­called ‘modern’ international law that has to be accepted because otherwise the world economy would become ungovernable. In this respect, Jackson’s argument comes close to those who argue that the economic rules of the global economy should not be subjected to political bargaining. m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 28 2/8/10 14:43:02 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­29 Regardless of whether political or legal theorists welcome, or deplore, the demise of national sovereignty, they all seem to share the same assumption: that current IEL rules are part of a comprehensive and coherent system of rules. In formal terms this assumption is reasonable because, as explained in earlier sections of this chapter, most of the new rules of IEL are consistent with the principles of the Washington Consensus. Yet, on close inspection the new rules of IEL are more fragile, less predictable and not as uniformly applied as either pro-­ or anti-­globalization activists and scholars assume. Indeed, a close analysis of the application of IEL rules would probably show that, at the point of implementation, the variety of increasingly intrusive forms of international regulation are either ineffective or their implementation is partial and selective. The fragility of international economic law rules stems – as I argue below – from the absence of adequate international institutions with the capacity to transcend genuinely the narrow political and economic interests of the leading actors in the world economy. In the absence of a strong international institutional framework, IEL rules are subject to the political and economic vagaries of powerful nation states. Thus, in terms of the question raised by the title of this section, IEL rules have not gone far enough because they are not embedded within a coherent system of international institutions. This may greatly facilitate the renewal of IEL rules once market fundamentalism, as embodied in the Washington Consensus, gives way to another development paradigm. 6. IEL RULES AND INTERNATIONAL GOVERNANCE The objective of establishing a level playing field among actors in the world economy is frequently cited as the main justification for the proliferation of IEL rules. In terms of international law, this sound objective is embodied in the ideal of multilateralism, which is in turn based upon the principles of equal treatment and non-­discrimination. The GATT was the first international economic instrument to take this principle seriously, and the WTO, as its successor, is the main vehicle entrusted with the implementation of this important objective. Yet, despite the rhetoric of multilateralism, the main proponents of the WTO have not taken this commitment seriously either when they designed the WTO or in their practice within the institution. Indeed, as numerous observers have noted, the political mechanisms of the WTO are hopelessly inefficient and its political organs have no capacity to take decisions or shape the practice of the organisation in accordance with m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 29 2/8/10 14:43:03 30 IEL, globalization and developing countries changing economic circumstances. The persistent failure to develop new rules and policies in successive Ministerial meetings is directly related to the inadequacy of the WTO as a political institution. The principle of unanimity, inherited from the GATT and described by some as medieval, is not at the heart of the problem. The main problem is that developed countries are not genuinely committed to the principle of multilateralism because of their distrust arising from the need to protect and further their own national economic interests. The WTO thus contains a labyrinth of complex rules that are interpreted by an adjudicatory mechanism, yet it does not have an effective mechanism to provide timely and dynamic responses to the ever-­changing global economic environment (Pauwelyn, 2005a, 2005b). Although the reluctance to establish a more coherent and politically effective WTO is often attributed to the neo-­liberal distrust of bureaucracies and big government, this interpretation has no basis. Indeed, the opposite is closer to the truth. The decision to opt for a model of globalization that relies on self-­enforcing rules stems from a lack of faith in the possibilities of achieving economic globalization through genuine multilateral channels and not from a genuine belief in the virtues of unregulated markets. This explains why the patently naïve belief that unregulated markets would rule the world was so readily embraced by the leading industrial countries in the world. The reluctance to establish institutions capable of effectively creating a more equitable process of globalization through multilateral mechanisms is also reflected in the policy of the major industrial powers towards the Bretton Woods institutions. These institutions, which should have played a critical role in providing guidance to achieve equitable economic outcomes, became instead the leading organs entrusted with the implementation of the now discredited Washington Consensus. In the 1980s, the World Bank pushed the structural adjustment agenda, with no concern for its social and economic impact (Onis and Senses, 2005: 284). Poverty eradication was an afterthought, incorporated into the Bank’s agenda in the 1990s, long after it had become clear that the ‘one-­size-­fits-­all’ Washington Consensus policies were not yielding good development outcomes and were causing serious domestic political problems. The IMF’s appalling record in applying Washington Consensus principles for the resolution of financial crisis in developing countries in the 1990s is well documented and has been widely criticised (Stiglitz 2002a; Woods, 2006). The poor performance of these two major institutions can again be traced back to the failure by the leading proponents of globalization to take seriously the importance of creating a level playing field managed through effective multilateral institutions. Neither the IMF nor the m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 30 2/8/10 14:43:03 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­31 World Bank has the structures or procedures to take decisions that would remotely reflect the interests of the majority of countries in the world. Their voting system, designed for a different era, gives privileged influence to western powers, especially the United States. Paradoxically, the failure to introduce a timely redesign of the Bretton Woods institutions called for an approach to globalization that played down its political edge by relying on the technical language of economics. Thus, the Washington Consensus became a useful mechanism which, while empowering the Bretton Woods institutions, concealed the disagreements and tensions among the leading proponents of globalization. Against this background, it is not surprising that the leading industrial nations have all but ignored the principle of non-­discrimination in international trade – one of the pillars of the ideal of multilateralism. In recent years, Regional Trade Agreements (RTAs) have become the most popular international instrument to manage trade and other international economic relations at the bilateral or regional level. Indeed, such is the popularity of these agreements – which at the last count numbered over 200 – that today they account for 50 per cent of world trade. The rationale for entering into these agreements is that they are building blocks aimed at facilitating economic integration among partners. Although these agreements are not prohibited by the WTO, they are closely regulated by the treaty (GATT 1947: Art. XXIV). Under this provision RTAs are intended to further trade liberalisation, but must not raise trade barriers in relation to WTO members that are not parties to the agreements. This basic principle requires members of RTAs to eliminate duties and other restrictive regulations of commerce with respect to substantially all trade and not to introduce more restrictive trade regulations in respect of trade with third parties. Under the rules of Article XXIV, all RTAs must be notified and approved by the Committee on Regional Trade Agreements, which includes all WTO members. Although the first of these requirements has been fulfilled, the second has not. Indeed, the Committee has only approved one RTA (the customs union between the Czech Republic and the Slovak Republic) because its members disagree on the interpretation of Article XXIV. As a consequence, all but one of the RTAs in force exist in a virtual legal limbo because WTO members have been unable to decide whether their aims and objectives are consistent with the aims and objectives of the WTO. According to Jagdish Bhagwati (2008), RTAs have effectively destroyed the principle of non­discrimination and have swallowed up the trading system. The reluctance of the leading industrial powers fully to implement the principle of multilateralism is yet another reflection of their half-­hearted commitment to establishing a genuine level playing field for the global m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 31 2/8/10 14:43:03 32 IEL, globalization and developing countries economy. Their own national political and economic interests have made it impossible to achieve this objective. This has not prevented them from imposing ‘one-­size-­fits-­all’ obligations on developing countries, as reflected in most IEL rules. Thus, while developing countries are prevented from using subsidies to develop local industries, developed countries employ subsidies to protect their agricultural sectors; while developing countries are required unconditionally to open up their economies to foreign investors, developed countries carefully screen investment from sources that they deem politically sensitive (Mattoo and Subramanian, 2009); while most developing countries have no choice but to accept tough conditionalities from the IMF and the World Bank, some developed countries use their influence in these institutions to give preferential treatment and additional financial support to their political allies (Stone, 2008); while the Millennium Development Goals were agreed with great fanfare, their implementation has provided developed countries with yet another opportunity to compel developing countries to adopt policy changes (Soederberg, 2004); while developing countries that enter into trade agreements are required to make sweeping changes to their tariff structures, their developed country partners are not prepared to commit themselves to even a minimum level of foreign aid (Hinkle and Schiff, 2004; South Centre, 2008a); while preferential trade agreements are described as building blocks to further integration, some of these agreements have made it difficult for developing countries to avail themselves of the flexibilities of the TRIPS Agreement (Stiglitz, 2008: 1701). Thus, one of the features of international governance in recent years is that international economic law has been used largely to impose discipline only on developing countries. Indeed, it is quite revealing that, in a recent negotiation of a free trade agreement with the US, Australia refused to accept a state-­investor arbitration clause, claiming that it has a well-­established legal system that can fairly and equitably handle claims from the private sector (Gagné and Morin, 2006: 372). Australia’s argument underlines the one-­sided nature of most IEL rules. While developing countries are rule-­takers, developed countries retain enormous discretion to decide whether and how to comply with rules that are meant to create a so-­called level playing field. The lack of coherence of IEL rules stems largely from the fact the promoters of the Washington Consensus failed to create institutions capable of directing and managing the process of globalization. Instead, they chose to introduce massive structural change through institutions, such as the IMF and the World Bank, which have a huge legitimacy deficit and institutions, such as the WTO, which do not function as genuine multilateral organisations. m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 32 2/8/10 14:43:03 IEL and development: before and after neo-liberalism­33 7. CONCLUSION This chapter has shown that either directly or indirectly IEL has been concerned with economic development. From the immediate post-­war period until the 1980s, IEL was weak and almost irrelevant, thus allowing developing countries space to formulate their own economic policies. During the recent period of unrestrained globalization, IEL has played a crucial role as a vehicle for implementation of the Washington Consensus in the developing world. Developing countries have been required to implement a strict set of rules, while developed countries, especially those that have played a leading role in the promotion of globalization, have embraced these rules half-­heartedly. Instead of tackling the urgent need to reform old international institutions and build effective new institutions to manage the process of globalization, these countries have pursued, through a range of bilateral and regional arrangements, a strategy that gives them ample political space to secure advantages over their close economic competitors. This process has undermined the ideal of multilateralism and made a mockery of the much flaunted objective of creating a level playing field. Paradoxically, the weakness of the prevailing international institutional framework bodes well for the future of IEL. Indeed, because IEL rules are not deeply embedded in dynamic, efficient or legitimate institutions, they cannot stand in the way of major reform. Indeed, if the world’s leading powerbrokers take seriously the task of building new and more effective institutions for the world economy, and if there emerges a new consensus on development that takes into account the needs and capacities of developing countries, there will then be a unique opportunity to develop new IEL rules and procedures to steer and manage globalization. This is a difficult task which will succeed only if it is carried out in consultation with all interested parties. One reason to be optimistic is that, today, developing countries will not be taken by surprise as they have learned the hard way that IEL rules, even the most technical, have a major impact on development. m2397 - faunDeZ Print.indd 33 2/8/10 14:43:03