Centre for Studies in Democratisation CSD Students' Working Paper Series Facilitating Peace: Democracy Building Following Violent Conflict Shanila De Silva MA International Relations, Department of Politics & International Studies, University of Warwick shaniladesilva@gmail.com Working Paper n. 1/ 2011 Centre for Studies in Democratisation Department of Politics and International Studies University of Warwick Coventry CV4 7AL United Kingdom http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/research/csd/ The Centre for Studies in Democratisation (CSD) was established at the University of Warwick in 1992 in response to a growing interest in the study of democracy at a theoretical and empirical level. Democratisation has become a central political theme and features now prominently on the foreign policy agenda of western countries. Members of CSD are seeking to understand why, how and when democracies emerge, sustain or collapse. They also investigate the reasons why democratisation can sometimes be problematic. Do not hesitate to contact us for more information! Renske Doorenspleet (Director): Renske.Doorenspleet@warwick.ac.uk Or visit our website: http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/pais/research/csd/ Abstract The idea of democracy building as a solution to violent conflict is a challenging one. Statistically, with high levels of stable and evenly distributed growth, and sufficient governance, regime type becomes unimportant to peace. However, democracy’s strength lies in its inherent ability to deliver these conditions. Where policy-makers and theorists run into problems is in the transition and design process of democracy following civil conflict. The following paper argues that in combination with growth and governance, democracy can have a positive impact on the peace process. While democracy building can be challenging, there are ways to mitigate potential instability and to design around potential hurdles. Given democracy’s intrinsic qualities, policy makers should focus on effective design of democracy and on facilitating conditions for growth and governance. Such a combination should theoretically result in a stable system. While reality does not always follow theory, the cases examined in this paper show that these conditions are effective and mutually reinforcing. They go on to demonstrate, that while there is no perfect model to create post-conflict stability, with a carefully managed transition, and a series of necessary conditions, democracy can help to facilitate peace in a developing country. Keywords: Democracy Building; Democratic Transitions; Violent Conflict; Peacebuilding; Post Conflict Stability Facilitating Peace: Democracy Building Following Violent Conflict Shanila De Silva INTRODUCTION Understanding the relationship between democracy and violent conflict is a challenge to policy makers and theorists alike. Historically, 31% of conflicts where violence has ended see a resumption of hostilities within the first 10 years.1 This seems to suggest that we have not come up with an effective formula for maintaining peace. Much of the literature points to the following two strategies as effective methods of addressing conflict: policy makers should either focus on overall economic growth, or the maintenance of security through effective governance.2 Democracy is often seen as an end goal or else is treated as an expected outcome given a prolonged period of peace and prosperity.3 This approach ignores democracy’s ability to be a positive solution to civil conflict. In a developing country, following a conflict, liberal democracy, and the institutions built into it, may be able to provide the tools for a stable resolution and overall political stability. This is assuming that the democratization process happens in a way that takes into account the causes of conflict, the settlement environment and carefully manages the settlement 1 2 Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building post-conflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 323. Snyder, Jack. From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist conflict. New York and London: Norton (2000). 3 Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?." American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50. 1 arrangements.4 The literature on conflict resolution is quick to say that there is no perfect model that provides a solution to civil conflict.5 It also advocates a country-specific, tailored approach to peace and stability. While this is true, we can actually identify some specific policies.6 This essay argues that, while democracy is not a sufficient condition for stability immediately following a violent conflict, it may accelerate its attainment. Furthermore it argues that democracy is better equipped to provide the necessary conditions for stability, including growth and good governance. The series of conditions and examples examined in this essay demonstrate that post-conflict stability is a tricky process for which there are no catch all approaches, but, that if carefully implemented, democracy can play a positive role. DEFINING DEMOCRACY BUILDING Much of the literature discusses the concepts of democratization, democracy assistance and democracy promotion, but democracy building remains a mystery. The idea of ‘democracy building’ implies change over time. Here, I take it to mean the building of more effective democratic institutions, whether this means a transition out of 4 Hartzell, Caroline, Matthew Hoddie and Donald Rothchild. “Stabilizing the Peace After Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Variables.” International Organization 55:1 (2001), 183– 208. 5 Kaufmann, Chaim. “Possible and Impossible Solutions to Ethnic Civil Wars.” International Security 20:4 (1996), 136 – 175. Also see Barnes, Samuel H. “The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies.” American Journal of International Law 95:1 (2001), 86 – 101. 6 Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building post-conflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 324. 2 dictatorship or better democratic design. It also implies a choice of regime type, meaning that the peacebuilding process involves a choice between the implementation of autocracy or democracy. For the purposes of this essay, democracy implies liberal democratic institutions. The ways in which these institutions are built play a large role in the prospects for peace over both the long and short run. To assess democracy’s contribution to solving violent conflict, it is important to go beyond the idea of a simple electoral democracy. Collier points out the distinction between electoral democracy and true democracy,7 noting that a ‘proper’ democracy does not merely consist of competitive, multi-party elections, but includes rules for the conduct of elections, as well as checks and balances to limit the power of governments, once elected.8 This definition distinguishes democracy from illiberal democracy or semiauthoritarian regimes and instead categorizes democracy as containing genuine checks and balances and mechanisms to ensure popular participation.9 I also want to clearly distinguish this definition of democracy building from the overall definition of peacebuilding. Peacebuilding and democracy building are different processes. Peacebuilding involves external actors and focuses on maintaining stability until it is reasonable for peacekeepers to mount an exit strategy.10 Although I will address this transition process 7 8 Collier, Paul. Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places. London: The Bodley Head, Random House (2009), 15. Ibid. 9 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). 10 Collier, Paul, Anke Hoeffler and Mans Soderbom. “Post-conflict risks,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge 3 briefly, my analysis primarily focuses on the benefits of democracy and the ways in which it addresses the causes of conflict and promotes stability in the longer term. CAUSES OF CONFLICT It is assumed that the risk of a resurgence of conflict is higher in a post-conflict society because it still contains the elements that made it prone to this risk in the first place.11 Therefore, it is important to understand the causes of conflict in order to effectively assess solutions. Causes are numerous and idiosyncratic. Overall however, they can be narrowed down to some combination of social, political and economic factors.12 Civil wars often persist because of state weakness – a decreased ability to provide social goods to its citizens and maintain rule-of-law.13 Conflict affected nations have a history of weak social contracts, largely characterized by a lack of political representation.14 Corruption and social cleavages also increase the incidence of violent conflict. The former does so through its corrosive effect on rules-based institutions.15 Many conflicts can (2011), 86 – 103. 11 Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building postconflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 325. 12 Fearon , James and David Laitin. “Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war.” American Political Science Review 97:1 (2003), 75 – 90. Also see Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 1 - 34. 13 Acemoglu,Daron, Davide Ticchi, and Andrea Vindigni. “Persistence of Civil Wars.” NBER Working Paper No. 15378 (September 2009). 14 Murshed, S. “Conflict, civil war and underdevelopment: an introduction.” Journal of Peace Research 4:39 (2002), 387 – 393. 15 Addison, T. and M. Murshed. “Explaining violent conflict: going beyond greed versus grievance.” Journal of International Development 15 (2003), 391 – 396. 4 occur along religious or ethnic lines, often because these issues can be easily manipulated by politicians.16 These social cleavages often combine with economic factors to generate conflict.17 Collier and Hoeffler explain the outbreak of civil conflict in terms of economic opportunities.18 They highlight the importance of conflict financing, primarily through natural resource rents, noting that countries that rely on primary exports are more likely to break into conflict.19 Slow growth and low GDP are also important determinants of the eruption of conflict. Overall, countries with low incomes are disproportionately more likely to be involved in civil wars.20 Grievances often begin as a result of economic inequality. This inequality combines with a series of factors to breed conflict.21 Specific, identifiable horizontal inequalities, which are inequalities among a group with a shared identity, can lead to state collapse and civil war.22 While conflicts have a cultural dimension, it has been found that a simple cultural explanation is insufficient, meaning that cultural dimensions are the result of economic and political factors.23 16 Collier, Paul, V.L. Elliot, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol and Nicholas Sambanis. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2003). 17 Addison, T. and M. Murshed. “Explaining violent conflict: going beyond greed versus grievance.” Journal of International Development 15 (2003), 391 – 396. 18 Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 1. 19 Ibid. 20 Besley, Tim and Torsten Persson. “The incidence of civil wars: Theory and Evidence.” NBER Working Paper No. 14585 (2008). Also see Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 531. 21 22 23 Murshed, S Mansoob, “Conflict, civil war and underdevelopment: an introduction.” Journal of Peace Research 4:39 (2002), 387 – 393. Ibid. Stewart, Frances. “Policies towards Horizontal Inequalities in Post-Conflict 5 The economic, political and social cleavages mentioned above can be created or exacerbated by international factors. Histories of colonialism may increase the prospects of rebellion in a country.24 Rebellion may occur as a spill-over from violence in a neighbouring country.25 In fact, some cases involve deliberate destabilization on the part of neighbouring countries.26 Many of these causes work together and drive each other. While these causes can change in significance during the period of conflict, better policy offers considerable scope to reduce conflict repetition.27 Where the causes of conflict are varied, the strategies of resolution must be varied as well. While it is true that there is no perfect model, there are several points of convergence in the literature around the basic conditions that are necessary in order to promote peace and stability in a developing country following a conflict. Each of these causes can be addressed, to differing extents, by liberal democracy. Lack of strong democratic institutions often combines with other factors to precipitate civil war.28 It is often argued that democracy is intrinsically good,29 but that post-conflict countries should wait before Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 136 – 174. 24 25 26 27 28 Murshed, S. “Conflict, civil war and underdevelopment: an introduction.” Journal of Peace Research 4:39 (2002), 390. Doornbos, M. “State collapse and fresh starts: Some critical reflections.” Development and Change 33:5 (2002), 797 – 813. Ibid. Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building post-conflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 347. Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 228 – 49. 29 Sen, Amartya. “Democracy as a Universal Value.” Journal of Democracy 10:3 (1999). 3 – 17. 6 becoming democratic.30 This assumes that democratic processes lead to violence. I argue however that this is not the case. DEMOCRACY AND POST-CONFLICT STABILITY Elbadawi and Sambanis identify an “appropriate political framework which focuses on participation, inclusion and consensus building” as an essential condition for preventing a resurgence of conflict.31 Mature democracies are the most likely to provide this since the process of change is more stable.32 This, combined with democracies’ intrinsic value,33 seems to suggest that “liberal democracies are really the only type of regimes that can truly insulate themselves from violent internal challenges.”34 Democracy can provide a series of goods that help to offset the effects of some of the aforementioned triggers of conflict. Democratic peace theory, or the idea that democracies rarely go to war with each other, is thought to apply solely to interactions between states. However, there is a growing recognition that democracies may be more peaceful overall.35 30 31 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 94. Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 265 – 266. 32 Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 382. Also see Feng, Yi. “Democracy, political stability and economic growth.”British Journal of Political Science 27 (1997), 391 – 418. 33 Collier, Paul and Lisa Chauvet. “Elections and economic policy in developing countries,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 254. 34 Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 382. 35 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 96. 7 Growing evidence shows that democracies experience fewer civil wars than non-democracies.36 This is because democratic governments manage social conflict by channelling issues into conventional politics. In addition, they are both able to, and obligated to, incorporate multiple interests into their policies. Furthermore, increased political rights and civil liberties means that democracy in a developing country decreases the likelihood of grievancebased rebellion.37 Democracy has a positive effect on the quality of governance by constraining the behaviour of political elites in the long term.38 This constraint, we will see, is essential to stability. One cannot assume leaders will always have the best interests of their populations in mind.39 In fact, rulers with discretionary power will often set up policies that benefit the few rather than the many.40 Democracy consistently keeps this behaviour in check by making policies subject to public scrutiny and by providing alternatives in the form of opposition parties.41 Democracies’ features can thus address the causes of conflict, but democracy alone cannot cure all ills, particularly in the period immediately following conflict. According to the vast body of literature, growth, and good governance are necessary conditions for stability following violent 36 37 38 39 40 41 Ibid. Reynal-Querol, Marta. “Ethnicity, political systems and civil wars.”Journal of Conflict Resolution 46:1 (2002), 35. Tavares, Jose and Romain Wacziarg. “How democracy affects growth.” European Economic Review 45:8 (2001), 1344. Halperin et. al. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 26. Tavares, Jose and Romain Wacziarg. “How democracy affects growth.” European Economic Review 45:8 (2001), 1344. Ibid. 8 conflict.42 The benefit of democracy comes from its ability to deliver these conditions.43 Growth, governance and democracy, are mutually reinforcing. Whereas growth and governance are essential for democracy to remain stable, democracy reinforces the stability of growth and good governance. Together, they address the aforementioned causes of conflict and can theoretically maintain stability over the long term. The problem, I argue, lies not with democracy, but rather with the short term processes of democratization and democratic design. DEMOCRACY AND GROWTH Economic growth is an essential condition for stability. We know that below $2700 of income per capita, that a country is likely to be unstable.44 Collier et al. collected data from 161 countries and found a significant correlation between low levels of income and the incidence of war.45 Thus countries are encouraged to focus on economic growth during the peace process.46 Statistically, democracies are on par with dictatorships 42 Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 531 – 540. Also see Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 244 – 269. 43 Ibid. Also see Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?." American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50. 44 45 46 Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 531 – 540. Collier, Paul, Anke Hoeffler and Nicholas Sambanis. “The Collier-Hoeffler Model of Civil War Onset and the Case Study Project Research Design,” Understanding Civil War: Evidence and Analysis. Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis (Eds). Washington: The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development/The World Bank (2005), 1 – 34. Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 96. 9 in terms of growth.47 However, when making decisions about regime type, democracies may be more compatible with development and stability because they have positive effects on the sustainability and distribution of growth. Indeed, with the long run in mind, democracy is preferable to an authoritarian regime. 48 Effects of Growth In the short term, growth can prevent potential combatants from reverting to conflict.49 Walter explains that countries where citizens enjoy higher levels of economic growth are less likely to revert back to war.50 The logic behind this is that rebels rely on local recruits. In countries where citizens are engaged in the economy, it becomes more costly to go to war.51 In the medium term, low levels of income can increase the risks of a reversion to conflict.52 Moreover, sustained growth dilutes the tensions that fuel conflict. Fearon and Laitin found that by holding economic growth constant, ethnic or ideologically divided societies were not more likely to experience conflict than more homogeneous societies.53 This demonstrates the significance of economic factors in the occurrence of conflict. In countries that are heavily reliant on primary commodities, this growth is 47 48 Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 53. Feng, Yi. “Democracy, political stability and economic growth.”British Journal of Political Science 27 (1997), 391 – 418. 49 Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 382. 50 Ibid, 371 – 388. 51 Ibid, 372 – 374. 52 Barnes, Samuel H. “The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies. American Journal of International Law 95:1 (2001), 87. 53 Fearon , James and David Laitin. “Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war.” American Political Science Review 97:1 (2003), 75 – 90. 10 essential in order to increase the expected costs of rebellion.54 Over the long term, in order to preventing a reversion to conflict, growth must be sustained and distributed evenly.55 A number of civil wars have been started largely as a result of low income and high inequality.56 It becomes essential, therefore to address these issues. Democracy does this better than other regime types.57 Furthermore, assuming that growth happens in a market economy, which is usually the case,58 democracy may be better equipped to effectively distribute the gains from growth.59 Growth and Democracy Rodrick and Wacziarg show that democratization is not bad for economic performance and that, in fact, democracies have positive effects on growth.60 They conclude that the idea that political reforms should wait until a country is ‘mature enough’ for democracy, or the idea that growth should precede democracy, is not supported by evidence.61 The assumption that 54 55 56 Collier, Paul, V.L. Elliot, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol and Nicholas Sambanis. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2003). Ibid. Murshed, S. “Conflict, civil war and underdevelopment: an introduction.” Journal of Peace Research 4:39 (2002), 387 – 393. 57 Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?." American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50. Also see Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. "Democracy and development: The devil in the details." American Economic Review 96 (2006), 321. 58 Bhagwati, Jagdish N. “Democracy and Development” Cruel Dilemma or Symbiotic Relationship?” Review of Development Economics 6:2. (2002) 158. 59 Collier, Paul and Lisa Chauvet. “Elections and economic policy in developing countries,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 293. 60 Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?" American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50. 61 Ibid, 56. 11 autocracies are better equipped to grow the economy presupposes that autocracies deliver better performance than democracy, which, in their analysis, is shown to be false.62 A market system may reduce the tendency towards corruption by providing higher standards of living and alternative pathways for advancement.63 However, in a market economy there are winners and losers, and while growth, overall, may be a stabilizing factor, inequalities can be destabilizing.64 Wittman explains that in a democracy, it is in the interest of policy makers to create policies that result in a more equitable distribution of the gains from growth the gains from growth.65 A more even distribution, including higher investment in human capital, enhances overall stability.66 Democracy can maintain the high standards of living and substantial economic growth that are required for long term stability.67 Besley and Kudamatsu show that autocracies that achieve high levels of growth are those which constrain the behaviour of their leader, meaning that it is not the case that all dictatorships benefit from growth.68 Growth seems to be correlated with constrained leaders.69 Liberal democracies have 62 63 64 Ibid, 56. Barnes, Samuel H. “The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies. American Journal of International Law 95:1 (2001), 92. Also see Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 51. Stewart, Frances. “Policies towards Horizontal Inequalities in Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 155. 65 Wittman, Donald. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” The Journal of Political Economy 97:6 (1989), 1395 – 1424. 66 67 68 69 Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 51. Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 244 – 269. Besley, Timothy and Masayuki Kudamatsu. “Making Autocracy Work,” in Institutions and Economic Performance, Elhanan Helpman (Ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press (2008), 498 – 499. Besley, Tim. Principled Agents: The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford 12 constraints built in, through the ability of voters to discipline politicians.70 They also make sure that political change, in the event of inadequate leadership, is regular and stable rather than irregular and unstable. This regular-change effect has further positive impacts on growth.71 Democracy and growth are mutually reinforcing.72 While democracy can have a positive effect on post-conflict stability, this effect is more pronounced when a country’s income is higher.73 Overall, “countries whose citizens enjoy high levels of economic well being and have access to a more open political system are significantly less likely to experience multiple civil wars than autocratic countries with low levels of individual welfare.”74 An appropriately moulded democratic system, combined with effective institutions results in stable, growth oriented states.75 Effective institutions highlight the importance of governance, which is the next condition necessary for stability and is as important as economic management.76 70 University Press (2006), 25. Ibid, 95 – 96. 71 Feng, Yi. “Democracy, political stability and economic growth.”British Journal of Political Science 27 (1997), 407. 72 Ibid. 73 Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 532. 74 Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 372. 75 76 Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 244 – 269. Ibid. 13 DEMOCRACY AND GOVERNANCE Elbadawi and Sambanis point to effective governance as an important tool for managing social, ethnic and political diversity in post conflict situations.77 Brinkerhoff identifies three targets for governance in post conflict societies. These include legitimacy, security and effectiveness.78 Legitimacy The accountability and legitimacy associated with a vibrant political culture helps to facilitate stability in a developing country with previous experience of civil war.79 This political culture can be created by a vigorous civil society.80 Liberal democracy has the presence of civil society built into it, with the two factors working together in a mutually reinforcing relationship.81 Civil society provides a variety of social goods, namely by enhancing accountability and representativeness.82 It also enhances the vitality of democracy. The persistence of democracy in a number of states, owes much to the presence of strong voluntary organizations.83 Part of governance and reconstituting legitimacy involves the building of a strong political culture. In order for democracy to be effective, 77 Ibid. Also see Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 562. 78 Brinkerhoff, D. “Rebuilding governance in failed states and post conflict societies: Core concepts and cross-cutting themes.” Public Administration and Development 25 (2005), 3 – 14. 79 80 81 82 83 Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 228 – 49. Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 54. Halperin et. Al. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 16. Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 54. Ibid. 14 it is important that citizens care about politics.84 In addition, a democratic political culture requires tolerance, trust, cooperation, and accommodation.85 However, such a political culture cannot be created overnight. It requires the aforementioned forces of socio-economic development and investment in human capital in order to develop. The absence of such a democratic culture renders the legitimacy of a regime more vulnerable to erosion.86 Security A significant threat to the establishment of security in a country is state failure define state failure.87 One of the key ways that democracy contributes to governance is that it reduces the risk of state failure.88 Failed states are considered breeding grounds for conflict.89 The stronger a country’s democratic institutions, the lower the likelihood of it becoming a failed state.90 Effectiveness Another benefit of democracy comes from its ability to provide public goods. We have seen in the section above that democracy can have 84 85 Ibid, 56. Ibid. 86 Collier, Paul and Lisa Chauvet. “Elections and economic policy in developing countries,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 258 – 259. 87 88 89 90 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 97. Ibid. Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 553. Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005), 97. 15 positive effects on growth and distribution. Democracy has built in constraints that require it to provide its citizens with goods. Democracy creates a system in which needs can be translated into demands.91 The flow of information in a liberal democracy provides the ability and the incentive to translate information into pressure on the government.92 Democracies can adapt to changing circumstances.93 They are ‘learning organizations’ which gather information and, through a process of trial and error, change policies accordingly.94 Thus democracy ensures that effectiveness can be rebuilt and that, overall, governments remain effective. THE IMPORTANCE OF ALL THREE CONDITIONS In theory, the presence of all three conditions should result in stability. The following examples discuss the ways in which these three factors can work together to manage conflict. Indonesia The case of Indonesia highlights the necessity of growth to decreasing the likelihood of a recurrence of war. In Indonesia, the rebellion could not find recruits as a result of improved living conditions, increased GDP and rapid growth.95 Governance and growth made it possible in this case, to raise 91 92 93 94 95 Bhagwati, Jagdish N. “Democracy and Development” Cruel Dilemma or Symbiotic Relationship?” Review of Development Economics 6:2, (2002) 156. Ibid, 157. Halperin et. Al. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). Also see Besley, Tim. Principled Agents: The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2006), 25. Halperin et. Al. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” 16 the costs of a reversion to warfare. The idea behind this is that citizens whose incomes are low and have no political means of improving their living standards are the ones more likely to enlist in a rebel organization.96 Afghanistan The difficulties around peace enforcement in Afghanistan highlight the importance of good governance. Simple elections without growth or effective governance, make Afghanistan a potential breeding ground for renewed conflict, with violence and instability persisting during the peacebuilding process.97 Weak governance on the part of the elected administration undermines the legitimacy of the elected governments.98 The result is a power shift in favour of a number of warlords.99 Slow growth in the country results in the development of illegal economies, particularly the opium trade.100 Civil society, accountability, and the liberties typically associated with a liberal democratic system are not present in the country. The example shows that purely electoral democracy is insufficient to maintain stability making Afghanistan an open question for policy makers. Mozambique Mozambique is a case where democracy, governance and growth were Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 375. 96 97 98 99 100 Ibid, 385. Addison, Tony and Tillman Bruck. “Achieving Peace, Participation and Prosperity,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 30. Addison, Tony and Tillman Bruck. “Achieving Peace, Participation and Prosperity,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 30. Ibid, 16. Ibid,18. 17 implemented and managed effectively. Considered a success story for stability building,101 Mozambique implemented a series of policies that resulted in its peace and stability following civil war.102 In the years since its 1992 peace agreement, it has experienced a number of multi-party elections. With strong support given to institution building, it has been relatively successful at reducing poverty and stimulating growth.103 While it does fit the criteria of an electoral democracy, it does suffer for a lack of the civil society and checks on power built into liberal democracy. Stewart notes that while Mozambique is a case where growth was managed effectively, the electoral system results in a government that has little incentive to manage horizontal inequalities. In a country where horizontal inequality was a primary driver for conflict, this could prove to be difficult. The country is heavily reliant on aid to manage horizontal inequalities104 and a more representative, liberal system of government may be able to manage such inequalities in the long run. Overall however, the case of Mozambique demonstrates that where all three conditions, democracy, growth and governance, are in place, stability will follow. Note that growth, governance, and democracy help to manage conflict, but the reality remains that there is no perfect model. Examples 101 102 103 104 Hellsten, Sirkku. “Ethics, Rhetoric, and Politics of Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 76. Also see, Stewart, Frances. “Policies towards Horizontal Inequalities in Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 156. Stewart, Frances. “Policies towards Horizontal Inequalities in Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 155. Ibid, 156. Addison, Tony and Tillman Bruck. “Achieving Peace, Participation and Prosperity,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 23. 18 vary as the result of any number of additional factors. For every country in which democracy can provide positive results, there are a number of countries where democracy building can be followed by instability. During the transition process a number of factors need to be considered. MANAGING DEMOCRACY BUILDING Overall democracy can have a positive effect in post-conflict countries, meaning that a stable democracy is more desirable than a stable autocracy. The establishment of democracy, however, may be tricky. While democracy may be able to prevent a reoccurrence of conflict in the long term, many believe that in the term immediately following a conflict, democracy will have destabilizing side effects.105 This is not caused by democracy per se, but is the result of the settlement environment and settlement arrangements.106 Mismanagement of the peacebuilding process can have undesirable consequences, both for the stability and legitimacy of democracy and for overall post-conflict stability. While democracy itself is not undesirable, many variables need to be taken into account during its implementation. The following list is by no means exhaustive, but is meant to demonstrate that numerous other factors need to be present to ensure the success of the democracy building process. 105 Paris, Roland. “Peacebuilding and the Limits of Liberal Internationalism.” International Security 22:2 (1997), 55. 106 Hartzell, Caroline, Matthew Hoddie and Donald Rothchild. “Stabilizing the Peace After Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Variables.” International Organization 55:1 (2001), 183– 208. 19 Electoral Institutions The choice of democratic electoral institutions is of vital importance during the peacebuilding process and will have implications for the stability of the political system over the long term. The trend in the practice of democratization is toward systems of proportional representation. However, while this makes a system more representative it also makes it less governable.107 It does this for three reasons. Firstly, it ensures that individuals are only accountable to the portion of the electorate that got them into power. Secondly, it means that the same group of people are voted in repeatedly and, hence, it is difficult to eliminate governments that are implementing ineffective policies. This means more stability, but less choice. Lastly, it creates issues of leverage. That is, large parties will often have to balance the policies of small parties, which creates governability issues in the event that there are more than two main parties in the system.108 Good governance involves resolving the tension between governability and accountability.109 This means finding an effective balance between sufficient concentration of power to choose and implement policies with energy and efficiency and the ability to hold power accountable.110 “Each country must find its own way of resolving this universal tension,” making the choice of institutions an important exercise.111 Several elements work to manage ethnic or ideological divides within a democratic framework. These include federalism, proportionality in 107 108 109 110 111 Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 55. Ibid, 55 – 56. Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 558. Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 53. Ibid, 54. 20 the distribution of resources and power, minority rights and a sharing or rotation of power.112 In Nigeria, a federal system had positive results for conflict management. This was the case for several reasons. Federalism worked to disperse conflict. It also generated intra-ethnic conflict while inducing inter-ethnic cooperation. It created crosscutting cleavages, meaning, parties would disagree about other issues than ethnicity. Lastly, it worked to reduce disparities.113 Building Democratic Culture Decentralization is an increasingly popular form of managing post conflict societies through building democratic culture.114 Where ethnic tensions are the main cause for conflict, decentralization has proved useful leading to successful transitions in Uganda, Rwanda, and Eritrea.115 Following ideological conflicts, this approach empowers groups and reduces political tensions. Bigombe et al. note the example of Uganda where decentralization was used by Museveni’s administration to improve accountability, equity and effectiveness.116 The decentralization process included cultivating democratic practices at the local level by encouraging local ownership, improving relations between local and central authorities, and “taking decision making closer to the populations affected by the reforms.”117 Here, decentralization was expected to enhance democratic 112 113 Ibid, 58. Ibid. 114 Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building postconflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 344. 115 Ibid. 116 Ibid, 345. 117 Ibid. 21 culture by encouraging behaviours of “tolerance, development, consensus and local reconciliation.”118 Political Elites Political elites are essential to the institutionalization of good governance in the short term. The tensions between elite interests and marginalized populations are often overlooked in the peace process and need to be addressed.119 Successful democracy building involves raising the costs of conflict for these elites and lowering the costs of democracy. In order for democratic governance to succeed, opposing parties must come to some sort of agreement. Consolidation of democracy requires a negotiation or an agreement by parties on the direction of reform, the renunciation of certain types of political appeals, an agreement on the sacrifices that all social forces will share and a method ensuring that the burdens of adjustment are shared more fairly by all segments of society.120 A successful example of this process was Venezuela in 1958, where political and economic pacts were negotiated by potential elites, resulting in policy stability regardless of election results.121 118 Ibid. 119 Call, C. And S. Cook. “On democractization and peacebuilding.” Global Governance 2 (2003), 236. Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 50 – 51. Ibid, 51. 120 121 22 Internal vs. External Approaches In recent history, external efforts at democratization have experienced a surge.122 While it may be true that countries coming out of conflict may be in need of both financial aid and policy advice, if country specific circumstances are not taken into account, this aid may come at the expense of stability.123 Hippler points out that external approaches to democratization are problematic. Questions around motives and the maintenance of an external occupation force present a challenge in war weary countries.124 Finally, in the case of complex local societies, external actors would likely be unable to understand the context of the conflict and may exacerbate a problem rather than solve it.125 The growing consensus is that democracy, good governance and good economic policies cannot be implemented from the outside, but rather, have to come from within.126 The marginal failure to implement post-war democracy from the outside can be seen with the example of Cambodia, where UN support for democracy was unsuccessful and resulted in a coup that ousted the democratically elected government.127 This example shows 122 Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 554. 123 Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler. “Aid, policy and growth in post conflict-societies.” European Economic Review 48 (2004), 1125 – 1145. 124 125 Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 565. Ibid. 126 Collier, Paul and Lisa Chauvet. “Elections and economic policy in developing countries,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 253 – 298. Also see Bermeo, Nancy. “What the democratization literature says – or doesn’t say – about postwar democratisation.” Global Governance 9 (2003), 159 – 177. 127 Call, C. And S. Cook. “On democractization and peacebuilding.” Global Governance 2 (2003), 242. 23 the difficulty of implementing democracy without the necessary conditions and also shows the difficulty of maintaining it in a country unfamiliar with the processes. Building Democracy vs. Re-building Democracy Regime type before conflict plays an important role in the chances for stability following the conflict.128 Hartzell, et al. explain that civil settlements negotiated in countries where the previous regime was democratic or semi-democratic, will be more stable than civil settlements agreed upon in previously authoritarian regimes.129 These countries are assumed to have more experience in accommodating competing interests.130 Where democracy has already been present it will have higher levels of prestige and citizens will have a level of familiarity with its operating principles.131 Some claim that too early an introduction of democracy may result in increased hostilities.132 It is true that new democracies run the risk of backtracking. This most often happens within the first two years of the democratization process.133 This backtracking is often a result of a number of factors including slow growth, further highlighting the importance of growth 128 129 130 Hartzell, Caroline, Matthew Hoddie and Donald Rothchild. “Stabilizing the Peace After Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Variables.” International Organization 55:1 (2001), 189. Ibid,189. Ibid. 131 Barnes, Samuel H. “The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies. American Journal of International Law 95:1 (2001), 87. 132 Hippler, J. “ Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 562. 133 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). 24 and governance to this process.134 Overall, successful democracy building requires careful design that takes a number of issues into account. As mentioned before, the causes of conflict are varied and solutions must be varied as well. Any number of factors can affect the viability of democracy, but the same could be said for the peace building process overall. Regardless of regime type, the transition process is tricky and requires careful design and management. REGIME CHOICE AND CONFLICT MANAGEMENT Democracy, as we have seen above, is not a sufficient condition and may not be a necessary condition for the immediate resolution of violent conflict, but it does facilitate the necessary conditions. Two final issues need to be addressed: alternatives and timelines. While it is difficult to show a perfect model of democracy as a solution to peace, it is necessary to examine the alternatives. There is little evidence to show that alternative regimes types can sustain peace. Several authors argue that clear democracies or clear autocracies are less likely to experience violent conflict.135 It seems to be that semi-democratic or semiauthoritarian systems are the most likely to experience conflict.136 It seems to be the case that a clearly defined, stable regime, either authoritarian or democratic, is necessary for building post conflict peace137. However, Halperin et al. note that “autocracy, poverty and conflict are a 134 Ibid,75. 135 Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 382. 136 137 Ibid. Ibid. 25 package deal.”138 This suggests that a stable democracy is better than an autocracy. If, at above certain levels of income, autocracies become unstable, it seems to suggest that we should be providing support for democracy along with support for growth. While Collier and Hoeffler’s analysis shows that below a certain level of income, democracy may have destabilizing effects, they also show that above that threshold, autocracies will be unstable.139 It seems that the risk of instability in the transition process should not rule out democracy’s merits as a potential long term solution. If designed correctly, with provisions made for potentially unstable transitions, democracy, as we have seen above, is not incompatible with peace, as long as it is combined with policies that result in growth and good governance. This brings us to the second issue, the one of timelines. Creating stability, institutions, growth, and democratic culture all take time. There are risks associated with the first two years following violent conflict.140 Thus, it is important to implement policies that can mitigate conflict risks over the long term. Arguably, autocracies have the ability to quell rebellion over the short term,141 but, as we have seen above, this is unsustainable. Both through its inherent ability to channel conflict into politics, and through its positive effects on growth and good governance, 138 Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). 139 Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 531 – 540. 140 Collier, Paul, Anke Hoeffler and Mans Soderbom. “Post-conflict risks,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 94. 141 Collier, Paul. Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places. London: The Bodley Head, Random House (2009). 26 democracy has the potential to manage conflict over the long term. While the risks of conflict decrease over time, it is important to know that they are only reduced marginally over the 10 year period.142 Meaning that, the best choice of regime, is the one that can best maintain stability over this decade. The best regime is the one best able to reduce poverty and inequality and to provide good governance. Thus, implementing an autocratic peace in the short term with the hope that it will result in long term stability may not be the best way forward.143 CONCLUSIONS Overall, democracy is not a necessary condition for peace. However, if implemented carefully, with attention paid to the specific circumstances of a country, its positive effects on stability, governance and growth show that it can have an indirect, positive impact on the peace process. While it is easy to point to democracy’s failings as a solution to violent conflict, I argue that this mistakes the role that democracy plays. Combined with growth and governance, democracy can provide the tools to address the causes of conflict and to uphold stability in the long term. Furthermore, the ability to maintain the necessary conditions of economic growth and good governance are built into the nature of democracy. In fact, when these conditions are met, dictatorships become more prone to conflict than democracies. If regime type is less important in the short term, but democracy is better in the long term, it is worthwhile to focus on ways to 142 Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?." American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50 – 56. 143 Ibid. 27 ensure the stability of democracy, instead of myopically choosing an authoritarian regime. While any number of the aforementioned variables can have tremendous effects on the prospects for peace, this is not due to an ill of democracy per se. The cases above have demonstrated that the approach to peacebuilding must be careful and country specific, and that democracy should not be discounted as a potential tool for forging stability. 28 Bibliography Acemoglu, Daron, Davide Ticchi, and Andrea Vindigni. “Persistence of Civil Wars.” NBER Working Paper No. 15378 (September 2009). Addison, T. and M. Murshed. “Explaining violent conflict: going beyond greed versus grievance.” Journal of International Development 15 (2003), 391 – 396. Addison, Tony and Tillman Bruck. “Achieving Peace, Participation and Prosperity,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 15 – 30. Barnes, Samuel H. “The Contribution of Democracy to Rebuilding Postconflict Societies. American Journal of International Law 95:1 (2001), 86 – 101. Bermeo, Nancy. “What the democratization literature says – or doesn’t say – about postwar democratisation.” Global Governance 9 (2003), 159 – 177. Besley, Timothy. Principled Agents: The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2006). Besley, Timothy and Torsten Persson. “The incidence of civil wars: Theory and Evidence.” NBER Working Paper No. 14585 (2008). Besley, Timothy and Masayuki Kudamatsu. “Making Autocracy Work,” in Institutions and Economic Performance, Elhanan Helpman (Ed.). Cambridge: Harvard University Press (2008), 452 – 510. Bhagwati, Jagdish N. “Democracy and Development” Cruel Dilemma or Symbiotic Relationship?” Review of Development Economics 6:2. (2002) 151 – 162 29 Bigombe, Betty, Paul Collier and Nicholas Sambanis. “Policies for building postconflict peace.” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 323 – 348. Brinkerhoff, D. “Rebuilding governance in failed states and post conflict societies: Core concepts and cross-cutting themes.” Public Administration and Development 25 (2005), 3 – 14. Call, C. And S. Cook. “On democractization and peacebuilding.” Global Governance 2 (2003), 233 – 246. Collier, Paul, V.L. Elliot, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta ReynalQuerol and Nicholas Sambanis. Breaking the Conflict Trap: Civil War and Development Policy. Oxford: Oxford University Press (2003). Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler. “Aid, policy and growth in post conflictsocieties.” European Economic Review 48 (2004), 1125 – 1145. Collier, Paul and Dominic Rohner. “Democracy Development and Conflict.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6:2-3 (2008), 531 – 540. Collier, Paul. Wars, Guns and Votes: Democracy in Dangerous Places. London: The Bodley Head, Random House (2009). Collier, Paul and Anke Hoeffler. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 1 - 34. Collier, Paul, Anke Hoeffler and Mans Soderbom. “Post-conflict risks,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 86 – 103. Collier, Paul and Lisa Chauvet. “Elections and economic policy in developing 30 countries,” in Conflict, Political Accountability and Aid, Paul Collier (Ed.). London and New York: Routledge (2011), 253 – 298. Diamond, Larry. "Three Paradoxes of Democracy." Journal of Democracy 1:3 (1990), 48 – 60. Doornbos, M. “State collapse and fresh starts: Some critical reflections.” Development and Change 33:5 (2002), 797 – 813. Elbadawi, Ibrahim and Nicholas Sambanis. “Why are there so many civil wars in Africa?” Journal of African Economies 9:3 (2000), 244 – 269. Fearon , James and David Laitin. “Ethnicity, insurgency, and civil war.” American Political Science Review 97:1 (2003), 75 – 90. Feng, Yi. “Democracy, political stability and economic growth.”British Journal of Political Science 27 (1997), 391 – 418. Francois, M and Inder Sud. “Promoting stability and development in fragile and failed states.” Development Policy Review 24:2 (2006), 141 – 162, Halperin, Morton H., Joseph T. Siegle and Michael M. Weinstein. The Democracy Advantage: How Democracies Promote Prosperity and Peace. New York and London: Routledge (2005). Hartzell, Caroline, Matthew Hoddie and Donald Rothchild. “Stabilizing the Peace After Civil War: An Investigation of Some Key Variables.” International Organization 55:1 (2001), 183–208. Hegre, Havard. “The Duration and Termination of Civil War.” Journal of Peace 31 Research 40:3 (2004), 243 – 252. Hellsten, Sirkku. “Ethics, Rhetoric, and Politics of Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009),75 – 100. Hippler, J. “Democratization after civil wars – key problems and experiences.” Democratization 15:3 (2008), 550 – 569. Jarstad, Anna K. “Dilemmas of war to democracy transitions: theories and concepts,” in From War to Democracy: Dilemmas of Peacebuilding. Anna K. Jarstad and Timothy D. Sisk (Eds). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (2008), 17 – 37. Kaufmann, Chaim. “Possible and Impossible Solutions to Ethnic Civil Wars.” International Security 20:4 (1996), 136 – 175. Murshed, S Mansoob, “Conflict, civil war and underdevelopment: an introduction.” Journal of Peace Research 4:39 (2002), 387 – 393. Ottoway, Marina. “Rebuilding state institutions in collapsed states.” Development and Change 33:5 (2002), 1001 – 1023. Paris, Roland. “Peacebuilding and the Limits of Liberal Internationalism.” International Security 22:2 (1997), 54 – 89. Paris, Roland. At War’s End: Building Peace After Civil Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (2004). Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini. "Democracy and development: The devil in the details." American Economic Review 96 (2006), 319-324. 32 Reynal-Querol, Marta. “Ethnicity, political systems and civil wars.”Journal of Conflict Resolution 46:1 (2002), 29 – 54. Rodrik, Dani and Romain Wacziarg. "Do Democratic Transitions Produce Bad Economic Outcomes?." American Economic Review 95 (2005), 50 – 56. Sen, Amartya. “Democracy as a Universal Value.” Journal of Democracy 10:3 (1999). 3 – 17. Snyder, Jack. From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist conflict. New York and London: Norton (2000). Stewart, Frances. “Policies towards Horizontal Inequalities in Post-Conflict Reconstruction,” in Making Peace Work: The Challenges of Social and Economic Reconstruction. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan (2009), 136 – 174. Tavares, Jose and Romain Wacziarg. “How democracy affects growth.” European Economic Review 45:8 (2001), Walter, Barbara F. “Does Conflict Beget Conflict? Explaining Recurring Civil War.” Journal of Peace Research 41:3 (2004), 371 – 388. Wittman, Donald. “Why Democracies Produce Efficient Results.” The Journal of Political Economy 97:6 (1989), 1395 – 1424. 33