School of Public Policy Working Paper Series: ISSN 1479-9472 Working Paper 15 REPRESENTATION AND COMMITTEE REPORTS IN THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT Pierre Hausemer Department of Government London School of Economics Houghton St London WC2A 2AE The support of UCL Friends Programme is gratefully acknowledged. School of Public Policy University College London The Rubin Building 29/30 Tavistock Square London WC1H 9QU, UK Tel 020 7679 4999, Fax 020 7679 4969 Email: spp@ucl.ac.uk Website: www.ucl.ac.uk/spp Date: June 2005 Representation and Committee Reports in the EP Pierre Hausemer LSE Department of Government June 10, 2005 Abstract The paper models the consequences of committee report allocation for political representation in the European Parliament. Both inter- and intra party group dynamics determine an individual legislator's ability to write reports on issues that are salient to his national party. First, party groups compete for salient reports on the basis of their delegation size. As a consequence, MEPs from smaller party groups are more constrained in their ability to represent the preferences of their national parties than their peers in the larger party groups. Second, the party group leadership distributes these reports among its MEPs in an attempt to maximize the cohesion of the group and the coherence of its policies. MEPs from larger national delegations, committee chairs and legislators whose policy preferences deviate from the rest of the group are allocated less salient reports than their fellow party members. The model is tested on data from the fifth European Parliament (1999-2001). The results confirm the importance of political representation in conditioning the legislative behaviour of MEPs. In policy areas governed by the co-decision procedure, the EP has evolved into a "normal" Parliament featuring intense competition along a left-right cleavage across party groups and a hierarchical allocation of legislative spoils within parties. In policy areas where the EP has less decision-making power, consensual politics characterised by a proportional distribution of legislative spoils prevail. 1 Introduction Over the past twenty years, the European Parliament has assumed increasing power within the EU’s political system. With political influence also came growing academic interest. A flurry of studies examines the so-called democratic deficit, European elections, or the “locus” of the EP within the EU’s institutional structure (See among others Moravcsik, 2002; Tsebelis and Garrett, 2000). Some more descriptive studies have addressed the workings and internal structure of the Parliament (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2001, 2003; Raunio, 1997, Corbett et al, 2003). With the notable exception of roll-call voting studies (see among others Hix, 2002, 2001, 2002, 2004; Carrubba and Gabel, 1999; Noury, 2002) and several recent papers on report allocation (e.g. Mamadouh and Raunio, 2001, 2003; Kaeding, 2004; Hoyland, 2005), most of this research treats the EP as a unitary actor. Yet, little is known about the legislative participation of individual MEPs outside roll-call voting sessions. This paper contributes to filling this gap by developing and testing a model of committee reports in the European Parliament. Which MEPs write which reports and what are the consequences for party representation in the European Parliament? The paper models committee reports as legislative tools used by individual legislators to represent the preferences of their national parties. Party groups bid on the most salient reports based on the size of their delegation in the EP. The leadership then allocates its reports to individual MEPs in a way that maximises group cohesion and policy coherence. The first section describes the report allocation procedure and discusses existing research on committee reports in the European Parliament. Section 2 introduces and operationalises a measure of political representation based on the legislative participation of individual MEPs. Section 3 specifies a theoretical model of representation in committee reports and derives a set of hypotheses to be tested in section 4. Finally, section 5 concludes with a summary of the results and an indication of possible areas for future research. Reports in the European Parliament Most scholars agree that the production of legislative reports is one of the most important elements of parliamentary committee work (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2003; Kaeding, 2004; Corbett et al, 2003; McElroy 2001; Kaeding, forthcoming; Mamadouh and Raunio, 2001). Indeed, the system of rapporteurships enables individual legislators to take responsibility for, and exert influence over, the policy position of the Parliament as a whole. This section describes the process of report allocation and discusses previous research on committee reports in the European Parliament. Committee reports have their origins in the parliamentary systems of continental Europe (Corbett et al., 2003). Topics for reports are either forwarded from the Council or the Commission under the different decision-making procedures or they arise at the initiative of an individual MEP. Bills forwarded to the Parliament by Commission or Council under the co-decision, co-operation, consultation or assent procedures are assigned to one of the parliamentary committees for consideration. Socalled own-initiative reports may address an entirely new policy area, a Commission communication on which the Parliament has not been consulted or a motion for a resolution tabled by an MEP in the plenary (Corbett et al., 2003). In order to limit committee workload, most motions for resolution are not taken up and MEPs must have prior approval from their committee before undertaking an own-initiative report. In 1994, quotas were introduced to reduce 2 committee workload to two own-initiative reports at any one point in time. As a result, during the 4th legislature, only 212 own initiative reports (or two per committee per year) were approved, down from 528 in the previous parliament. Table 1 lists the number of reports by committee in the fourth and fifth Parliaments. For each committee, the table also lists the number of co-decision reports adopted in each legislature. Reports that fall under the co-decision procedure are of particular importance because the European Parliament has most of its legislative power under this procedure (Tsebelis and Garrett, 1997, 2000; Crombez, 1997; Hoyland, 2005). The total number of reports includes co-decision reports, reports that fall under the consultation and assent procedures as well as non-legislative and owninitiative reports. In all of these cases, the Parliament has less decision-making power than under the co-decision procedure where it acts as an equal co-legislator with the Council of Ministers. While it is difficult to compare the data over time because of the 1999 committee reform, the aggregate numbers show that the workload of the Parliament as a whole as well as its policy influence have increased substantially in the past decade. Over the 10 year period, the number of reports has risen by 20 percent and the share of co-decision reports has increased by 50%. One in five reports in the fifth Parliament fell under the co-decision procedure. Most reports in the 5th Parliament are written in the environment committee followed by justice and home affairs. In the previous legislature, Economics and Environment were vastly more prolific than other committees. Table 1. Reports in Committees 4th and 5th Legislatures 1994-1999 Committee All Co-decision Economic 288 73 Environment 207 86 Transport 165 27 Ext Econ Rel 129 1 Foreign Affairs 127 0 Legal Affairs 117 45 Agriculture 115 3 Energy & Research 113 17 Fisheries 112 0 Budgets Employment Civil Liberties Budgetary Control Culture 104 99 97 84 75 2 12 4 2 30 Development 73 4 Regional Policy 70 2 Rules of Procedure 35 Women's Rights 32 Institutional Affairs 24 Petitions 12 TOTAL 2078 % Co-decision 15 0 2 0 0 310 1999-2004 Committee All Co-decision Environment 263 152 Justice & Home Affairs 254 19 Legal Affairs 229 82 Trade, Research & Energy 219 50 Economic 190 35 Budgetary Control 176 3 Foreign Affairs 153 2 Agriculture & Rural Dev. 147 15 Regional Policy, Transport 147 78 & Tourism Budgets 144 10 Fisheries 133 0 Social Affairs 109 30 Development 73 18 Constitutional Affairs 56 3 Culture, Youth, Education, 51 25 Media & Sport Women's Rights & Equal 45 8 Opps Petitions 23 0 TOTAL % Co-decision Sources: Corbett et al, 2003; www.europarl.eu.int 3 2412 22 530 Each time a committee takes on a report, a rapporteur is nominated to draw up a draft text for approval by the committee. The details of the procedure for nominating rapporteurs vary though all committees have instituted an auction system where every political group is allocated a certain number of points based on its size at the beginning of the Parliament. Committee coordinators fix the initial “price” of each report and make bids on behalf of their group. If more than one group is interested in a particular report, the group coordinators can raise their bids up to a certain maximum. This bidding system allows for a substantial amount of horse-trading among party groups. However, as Corbett et al. (2003) point out, most technical reports are referred to committee experts for very few points and only the most controversial reports are auctioned off along partisan lines. Once nominated, the rapporteur is in charge of researching, writing and defending his text in the committee. Rapporteurs, in theory, are “servants of the committee, not their Groups” and the committee has the power to withdraw their responsibility for the report (Corbett et al., 2003). Once a report has been approved by committee vote, the rapporteur presents the text in the plenary where he defends it on behalf of the committee. Rapporteurs also follow up on the evolution of the report throughout the decision-making procedures, make recommendations for a possible 2nd reading and, under the co-decision procedure, take part in the Conciliation Committee on behalf of the European Parliament. In sum, reports (whether legislative or own-initiative) require a substantial amount of involvement on the part of the rapporteur in return for significant power over the European Parliament’s policy position. By accumulating policy expertise, building consensus among party groups and negotiating with the Council and the Commission, individual rapporteurs can accumulate considerable leverage over policy outcomes at the European level (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2003). This is particularly the case for issues that fall under the co-decision procedures where the interinstitutional bargaining game can involve up to three readings and the EP has considerable influence over policy outcomes. Despite the importance of committee reports, there are few analytical studies of the allocation procedure and its consequences in the EP. All studies to date have focussed exclusively on the level rather than the quality of legislative participation in committee reports (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2001, 2003; Kaeding, 2004, forthcoming; Hoyland, 2005). In their contributions, Mamadouh and Raunio (2003) identify national party delegations as “key gatekeepers” for the distribution of reports within the party group and find that intra-party allocation is largely proportional to the size of national parties. Across party groups, “partisan interests drive the allocation process” (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2001). Kaeding (2004) focuses on the environment committee in the fourth Parliament to show that the group of rapporteurs does not mirror the composition of the Parliament as a whole. Rapporteurs tend to exhibit high demand for the policy in their jurisdiction, which is in line with a distributional explanation of report allocation (Kaeding, forthcoming). Finally, focusing on national parties in the EP, Hoyland shows that governing and opposition parties have different strategies for spending their rights to co-decision reports. He argues that governing parties aim to write as many reports as possible while “opposition parties choose their involvement more carefully” (Hoyland, 2005). This paper builds on these findings to analyse the consequences of committee report allocation for political representation in the European Parliament. The paper develops a theoretical model of report allocation as a function of competition across party groups and intra-party politics. Unlike most previous research, the dependent 4 variable takes into account both the quantitative and qualitative characteristics of legislative participation. The model is tested empirically on data from all seventeen committees in the fifth legislature. The next section discusses the concept and operationalisation of political representation in the European Parliament. Representation and Committee Reports Most research on the EP has either adopted a descriptive notion of political representation (Norris and Franklin, 1997; Kohn, 1981) or focused on the congruence between the stated preferences of represented and representatives (Thomassen & Schmitt, 1997; Katz, 1997; Marsh and Wessels, 1997). Behavioural scholarship has been limited to the analysis of various sets of roll-call votes (Hix, 2001, 2002, 2004). This lack of academic interest may be due to the fact that the specific political context of the EP offers only limited opportunity to directly test the most prominent existing behavioural theories of representation developed in the US. Indeed, unlike in the US Congress, the weak electoral connection in the EP and a rigorous candidate selection process commanded by national parties locate the representational focus of MEPs closer to the national party than in most national legislatures. As Hix and Lord (1997) for instance find, national parties guide the voting behaviour of MEPs, especially when their preferences contradict those of the European party group. Similarly, the pattern of committee memberships is more closely aligned with national parties than with the territorial constituency (Hausemer, 2004). Because parliamentary reports are an essential part of committee work, it is likely that national parties also play a large role in their allocation. Nevertheless, representation is an essential part of an MEP’s own role perception. Table 2 shows the results of a survey that asked MEPs who they think they should represent. As becomes clear immediately, the national party and the constituency/country are at the centre of most MEPs’ representational roles. More than 70% of MEPs see their role primarily in representing the people in their country followed by a close 67% who are very concerned about representing their national party. The narrowest (special groups) and the widest (all Europeans) representational foci are far less popular with 21 and 41 percent respectively. This paper focuses on national parties and countries as the main representational foci.1 1 The theoretical discussion focuses on national parties rather than the territorial constituency and the empirical section uses a dependent variable constructed from party level data. However, in order to account for the importance of country representation in Table 2, all empirical estimations include separate controls for country effects. 5 Table 2. Representational Foci of MEPs All people in All people in Party Constituency Europe Country Voters Austria Belgium Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Ireland Italy Luxembourg Netherlands Portugal Spain Sweden UK EU-15 30 39 25 18 44 63 73 44 65 . 48 31 42 21 29 40.86 70 44 63 91 56 57 91 89 74 75 76 81 67 64 54 70.13 60 72 13 73 31 59 55 89 41 75 5 56 69 57 79 55.6 80 67 75 73 61 50 64 89 50 75 86 38 78 71 50 67.13 Special Groups 50 11 . 9 14 17 27 33 20 25 14 19 28 14 14 21.07 Figures are percentages of representatives who indicated that the respective focus is of great importance to them (values 6 and 7 on a 7-point scale, where 1 indicates little importance and 7 great importance); Source: adapted from Wessels, 1999; Note that in the 1999 European elections most countries only had one electoral district with the exception of the UK (12) and Belgium (3) How can these role perceptions be operationalised from a behavioural perspective? First of all, representation increases with the engagement of the legislator in areas that are important to constituents and thus follows what others have called a “competence logic” (Schmitt and Thomassen, 2000). The more competently the representative addresses policy issues that are salient to the represented, the better his representational performance. The more energy the representative expends on reports that lack salience, the lower his representational performance. This is unlike most previous studies of representation where issue congruence is measured as the closeness of the policy positions of representatives and represented (see for instance Levitt, 1996). Mathematically, representational performance can be expressed as: REPy= q i =1 where q = Py,i = SALi = (P y ,i * SALi ) (1) number of policy issues, number of reports legislator y undertakes in issue i, salience of issue i to national party, In equation (1), q i =1 (P y ,i * SALi ) is the sum across issue areas of the product of the MEP’s legislative participation and the salience of each issue to his national party. For a given issue area Py,i * SALi is zero if the MEP either decides not to engage at all or if the issue area is not salient to the party. It rises as the MEP writes more reports on issues his party cares about. In other words, equation (1) operationalises political representation as a combination of the qualitative and quantitative characteristics of 6 legislative participation. The next section models representation on committee reports as a function of the allocation procedure and inter- and intra-party group politics. A Theory of Committee Report Allocation Previous studies have identified two modes of legislative politics (King, 1976; Sartori, 1976). The inter-party mode is where parties compete against one another for influence over policy, important offices within the legislature and/or the favours of the electorate. In the intra-party mode, hierarchy determines the interaction between the party’s rank-and-file members and the leadership (Weingast and Marshall, 1988; Boucek, 2002; Mueller, 2000). Like national legislatures, the European Parliament can only fulfill its role as a representative institution if party groups compete in elections and organize cohesively to implement their political platforms (Attinà, 1992; Andeweg,1995; van der Eijk and Franklin, 1996; Hix and Lord, 1997). This section uses the distinction between inter- and intra-party politics to develop a model of political representation on EP committee reports. It is the combination of both modes that determines the distribution of legislative benefits among individual representatives. Most observers including the media, academic researchers and the general public associate legislative politics primarily with the inter-party mode where governing parties and opposition confront one another, publicly debate policy issues and make decisions over a variety of policy alternatives. In order to win elections, political elites develop rival policy ideas which they promise to implement when in office. Elections provide voters with a mechanism to punish politicians who fail to implement their electoral promises or who are dishonest or corrupt (Fearon, 1999). As a consequence, the closer the legislature comes to a situation of perfect political competition, the more closely legislative behaviour mirrors the preferences of the represented. Representation in the European Parliament occurs because the largest party group seizes the largest share of legislative spoils to implement its political platform. Like economic competition, perfect political competition is an ideal rather than an accurate description of reality. In the EP, high majority thresholds and an institutional structure that defines the Parliament in opposition to the Council of Ministers and the Commission undermine competition among party groups. Indeed, much of the earlier research on the EP claims that it is dominated by ‘grand coalitions’ between the two main party groups (EPP and PES) (e.g., Bardi, 1994; Hix and Lord, 1997; Kreppel, 2001). However, more recent studies based on the analysis of roll-call votes have found that voting in the EP pits “minimum-winning majorities against minimum-losing-oppositions” along a left-right cleavage (Hix, 2004). In any case, if party groups need to coalesce in order to implement their policy platforms, the distribution of legislative spoils across party groups should reflect coalition patterns. Inter-party competition is not the only dynamic at work in Western political systems. Parties are composed of individual members with their own policy preferences, constituencies, and different status within the party hierarchy. As Boucek notes, “parties are not unitary actors but collections of individuals [...] with common but also divergent preferences and interests and with competing claims on party resources.” In these circumstances, the party group leadership must take measures to ensure the cohesion and policy coherence of the group. Weingast and Marshall (1988) point out that parties, “to the extent that they are able to influence the behaviour of their members through distribution of resources” can provide a means to enforce agreements in the legislature and secure desirable policy outcomes. In order to be 7 effective the party leadership must balance the claims of party elites and rank-and-file (cohesion) without endangering the “brand name” of the party (coherence) (Boucek, 2002). First, in the face of relatively high majority thresholds, only cohesive parties can garner the necessary votes to implement their policy platform. As Boucek (2002) points out, cohesion and unity are “perceived to be necessary to the delivery of efficient government”. In order to maintain loyalty, the leadership distributes party resources so as to ensure that the rank-and-file members have a stake in its continued and efficient operation. MEPs from smaller national delegations and those who have not been awarded prestigious office, such as committee chairmanships, have less power over, and a lower stake in, the group. The cohesion imperative predicts that rank-and-file members and MEPs from small national delegations are allocated a disproportionate share of non-office spoils within their party group. Second, in addition to cohesion, the leadership must also ensure a certain amount of policy coherence to maintain the credibility of the group or, as Boucek (2002) calls it, protect the party’s “brand name”. Janda (1980) defines coherence as the “degree of congruence in the attitudes and behaviour of party members”. Even though legislators, on average, are likely to have more in common with their fellow party members than with the members of other parties (otherwise they would switch parties), this is not the case on all issues all the time. On any specific issue, individual members may disagree with and defect from the policy position of their party. By screening its members before allocating important legislative spoils, the leadership can identify rebel backbenchers and reward representatives who toe (or at least are likely to toe) the party line. Thus, MEPs whose policy preferences are closest to the rest of their party group are most likely to be trusted with important legislative spoils. Table 3 summarises inter and intra-party factors that determine the distribution of legislative benefits among individual representatives. The distribution of seats among party groups and the legislative coalitions it encourages determine the allocation of legislative spoils across groups. Additionally, the leadership’s concern with ensuring the cohesion of the group and the coherence of its policies determines the distribution of legislative benefits within the party. In order to assess the representational performance of individual legislators, it is necessary to take into account not only the nature of political competition across parties but also the hierarchical organisation of the parties themselves. Table 3. Inter- and Intra-Party Politics in the European Parliament Level of Interaction Inter-Party Objective Distribution of Spoils by Competition Party Groups Size / Coalition Dynamics Intra-Party Coherence Policy Closeness Delegation Size / Office Status Cohesion As discussed in the previous section, committee reports are a highly desirable legislative spoil, the allocation of which is controlled by the party group leadership. Salient reports in particular allow legislators to engage in issues that are of relevance to their national party. Thus, an MEP’s legislative output can be measured as the ability to represent the preferences of his national party. It varies not only with the number of reports that he undertakes but also with their salience. This section has 8 shown that an MEP’s representational performance depends on the party group he belongs to, the leadership’s need to give him a stake in the party and the coherence of his policy preferences with the rest of the group. Hypotheses 1-4 summarise the theoretical discussion in this section. H1: MEPs from party groups that are far from the largest delegation on the leftright spectrum have lower representational performance. H2: MEPs whose policy preferences are close to the median of their party group have better representational performance than MEPs who are preference outliers within their party groups. H3: MEPs from smaller national parties have higher representational performance than MEPs from the larger delegations. H4: Committee chairs have lower representational performance than regular committee members. This section has developed a theoretical model of political representation on European Parliament committee reports and derived four empirically testable hypotheses. An MEP’s representational performance is controlled by the party group leadership and governed by both intra- and inter-party group dynamics. The next section presents the data used to estimate the model and discusses its operationalisation. Data The data for the study include all reports in all seventeen committees between September 1, 1999 and January 1, 2001. Because committee positions are assigned at the beginning of each parliament for a minimum of 2.5 years, the paper covers only the first half of the Parliament before mid-term committee turnover. Data on committee assignments and reports are available online from the European Parliament’s website (www.europarl.eu.int). The unit of analysis in the dataset is the individual committee member. For each committee, the dataset identifies members and the number of reports they wrote for the committee in the period under analysis. Because the European Parliament’s power over policy outcomes varies across the different decision-making procedures, the data also distinguish between the most influential (co-decision) reports and other types of reports. With most MEPs having joined two committees, the total number of observations (1,316) is around twice the size of the actual Parliament (626). MEPs who chose not to join any committees are excluded from the dataset because they could not write any reports a priori. National party positions for most major European parties are available on the data-CD accompanying Budge et al.’s (2001) cross-country study of party manifestos. Due to a lack of data for smaller national parties, all empirical tests are run separately, first, on the full sample of all MEPs for which there were national party data and, secondly, on the sub-sample of the two largest party groups, the EPP-DE and the PES. The results are very similar and the empirical analysis below only refers to the full sample. The coding frame used to match party positions with the different committees is in the Appendix. 9 National party manifestos are, of course, not a perfect measure of salience. Manifestos are political documents created for the specific purpose of convincing voters and winning elections. The manifesto dataset has been especially criticised for its interpretation of party policy positions (Laver, Benoit and Garry 2003; but see Klingemann et al. 1994 for a more positive assessment of party manifesto data). However, party manifestos are authoritative statements as to the policy areas that the party wants to focus on in government or in opposition and they are widely used in empirical research. The empirical analysis in this paper focuses not on policy positions but on salience. An area is salient if it is prominent in the manifesto, independently of the policy position that the party advocates. Using party manifestos makes it possible to include almost all MEPs in the fifth Parliament without having to rely on expert assessments or public opinion surveys.2 The dependent variable (representational performance) is constructed from national party manifestos and data on report allocation from the EP database. The score is high for MEPs who write reports on policy issues that feature prominently in the electoral manifestos of their national parties and low for MEPs who have not written salient reports. Salience is defined as the percentage of the electoral manifesto dedicated to a particular issue. In other words, REPy is an index that measures the extent to which the behaviour of a legislator matches the preferences of his national party. No data were available for reports on budgets, budgetary control, legal affairs and petitions. Mathematically, the score for MEP y can be expressed as follows REPy = j i =1 [REPORTS * % SALIENCE ] where %Salience varies across parties and Reports is the number of reports undertaken by MEP y in committee j. Incumbency is a dummy variable, which is coded 1 for MEPs who were reelected in 1999 and 0 for freshmen. The mean size of electoral districts is taken from Farrell and Scully’s (2002) paper on Electoral Systems and Representation, national party delegations are retrieved from the European Parliament’s homepage and party size is the number of MEPs for each party in the analysis. The distance between an MEP’s policy preferences and his party group is based on nominate scores which are available online at www.lse.ac.uk/Depts/eprg/. Nominate scores each legislator’s roll call voting record along two dimensions: left/right and pro/anti-EU. The distance measure for each dimension is the difference between an MEP’s Nominate score and the median score of his party group. Descriptive statistics and correlations for all variables are in the Appendix. The next section tests the model and its hypotheses empirically. Empirical Findings This section tests the inter- and intra-party predictions of the model using a combination of bivariate and multivariate statistical tools. Hypothesis 1 suggests that legislative spoils such as the ability to represent the preferences of one’s party should vary systematically across party groups. Figure 2 shows the difference between each party group’s share of the representational pie and its share of seats. 2 Both these alternative tools for measuring salience have their own disadvantages. Expert surveys are often less comprehensive both in the number of policy areas that they distinguish and in the number of parties covered. In addition, previous research has criticised both public opinion surveys and expert evaluations for a lack of reliability. 10 Figure 2. Party Representation and Share of Seats by Party Group and Type of Report % % OTH Rep % COD Rep % % % EPP PES ELDR GREEN EUL UEN IND - % - % - % Note: EDD not represented due to lack of data; COD Rep is the difference between a party group’s share of salient codecision reports and its share of seats; OTH Rep is the difference between a party group’s share of salient non -codecision reports and its share of seats. Clearly, salient co-decision reports are not distributed proportionally to the size of a party group’s delegation. Some party groups obtain more salient co-decision reports than their share of seats whereas others get a lower percentage than their size in the EP would justify. The largest party group in the 5th Parliament (EPP) is 12% over-represented followed by its closest coalition partner on the left-right spectrum, the Liberal ELDR. The main opposition to the EPP, the centre-left PES, on the other hand is under-represented. The Greens obtain a larger share of salient co-decision reports than their seats would allow, which may be because they focus their activity on the influential environment committee. The smaller groups on both edges of the political spectrum (EUL, UEN and Independents) are most under-represented. However, what is true for co-decision reports does not extend to all types of reports. Rather, as Figure 2 illustrates, the distribution of salient non co-decision reports is proportional to delegation size. The EPP is again most over-represented with 8%, followed this time by PES and ELDR. The smaller groups of the Greens, EUL, UEN and Independents also have smaller shares of salient non co-decision reports than their share of seats. Clearly, for non co-decision reports, the legislative output of each party group is a direct function of its size within the EP. Co-decision reports are not allocated in the same way as other reports. Party group location on the policy spectrum matters for the allocation of co-decision reports but not for other types of reports. Thus, the party group competition hypothesis (H1) is borne out only for co-decision reports. The distribution of legislative spoils is determined not only by the size of each party group but also by coalition patterns along the left-right spectrum. In other words, the legislative output of each party group depends on its value as a coalition partner to the largest party group. This finding confirms recent research on roll-call votes which has identified Left-Right politics as the predominant cleavage pattern in the EP (Hix, 2004). However, the Parliament remains governed by strict rules of proportionality in areas where it does not have much power. Regardless of policy influence, extremists on the left and right obtain a lower share of legislative spoils than their share of seats. As Figure 2 has shown for party groups, the emphasis on delegation size and proportionality in previous research (Mamadouh and Raunio, 2003) is justified only in 11 the case of non co-decision reports. Figure 3 looks at national delegations to investigate the validity of this argument within party groups. The bars represent the average representational score on all reports for each member state. On the same graph, Share Cod plots the share of representational performance attributable to codecision reports. Figure 3. Representational Performance by Country and Type of Report . . . . ALL . Share COD . . . . LU FI GR NL DK SW GE UK AT PO SP IR BE FR IT Notes: Bars are the average representational scores on all reports by country; the line represents the percentage of representational performance attributable to codecision reports. Clearly, delegation size does not have a positive effect on the allocation of legislative spoils. If anything, the opposite seems to be true. MEPs from Luxembourg and Finland are most successful in writing reports that are salient to their parties. In addition, they are the only two countries that have managed to obtain more salient codecision reports than salient other reports (i.e. Share Cod>0.5). The Netherlands, Greece and the Scandinavian member states also do well on total representation though only Sweden and Ireland have COD/OTH ratios around 0.4. France and Italy, two of the largest member states, have the worst scores on both measures. The other two EU giants, Germany and the UK, have very similar scores at positions 7 and 8. While the size of the national delegation might affect the purely quantitative aspects of report allocation, Figure 3 suggests that MEPs from smaller member states are assigned a disproportionate number of high quality reports. This finding corroborates the predicted compensatory logic at the basis of the allocation of legislative spoils within party groups (H3 and H4). The bivariate analysis so far has presented some support for hypotheses 1, 3 and 4. Figure 2 shows that inter-party competition affects the distribution of salient reports among party groups, though it does so differently for co-decision and non codecision reports. Similarly, Figure 3 indicates that MEPs from smaller national delegations tend to engage in issues that are more salient to their party than MEPs from larger member states. However, a purely bivariate analysis does not allow to assess the explanatory power of the model or the relative importance of each of the four hypotheses. Table 2 summarises the output of three OLS regressions with representation as dependent variable. Regressions (1) and (2) focus exclusively on co-decision reports while model (3) includes only reports that do not fall under the co-decision procedure. An MEP’s ability to write salient reports depends in large part on the committees that he has joined. Therefore, all regressions incorporate dummies for committee membership with the Foreign Affairs committee as a reference category. A 12 continuous proxy for committee salience led to very similar results. Regressions (2) and (3) use country dummies to control for nationality (dummies not shown). With the UK as a reference, the coefficients for Portugal and Belgium are negative and significant at the 10% level, the coefficient for Finland is positive and significant at the 10% level in regression (2) whereas none of the dummies assumed any significance in regression (3). Regression (1) replaces the country dummies with a continuous variable that measures the size of electoral districts in European elections. Table 4. OLS Regression - Dependent Representation Score (Constant) Party Competition PES ELDR GREEN EUL UEN IND Coherence Left-Right Dist Pro-Anti Dist Cohesion Chairman Party Size Control Variables Total Reports Share Co-decision Incumbent District Budget Budget Ctrl JHA Economics Legal Research/Trade Social Environment (1) (2) (3) 3.517* (2.037) 1.822 (1.214) 1.090 (2.423) -1.434** (.731) -3.064** (1.293) -2.115 (1.309) -3.355** (1.424) -1.347 (1.588) -1.925 (1.835) -1.324* (.685) -2.218** (1.107) -2.139* (1.148) -2.618** (1.231) -1.865 (1.431) -2.024 (1.702) .365 (.870) 2.083 (1.538) -.400 (1.557) -.782 (1.694) .839 (1.889) -2.680 (2.183) -6.827* (3.611) .243 (3.145) -6.951** (3.171) 1.344 (2.864) -.482 (4.295) -2.863 (3.741) -4.973** (2.414) -.112*** (.042) -4.942** (2.412) -.076*** (023) -3.138 (2.871) .018 (.050) 1.435*** (.183) 11.072*** (.968) .509 (.505) - 1.459**** (.183) 11.302*** (.959) .417 (.502) -.007 (.009) -.122 (.983) -.661 (1.581) -.104 (.836) 2.220**** (.799) .291 (.977) .171 (.734) 1.474** (.718) -.160 (.692) 4.821*** (.218) -9.194*** (1.151) -.598 (.601) - -.196 (.989) -.746 (1.584) .025 (.848) 2.112*** (.803) .481 (.982) -.014 (.744) 1.460** (.732) .008 (.699) 13 -.380 (1.176) 1.512 (1.884) 2.778*** (1.008) 6.202*** (.955) 1.412 (1.168) -.271 (.884) -.485 (.871) -1.053 (.831) Agriculture N -.071 (.856) -.364 (.934) -1.298* (.767) .578 (.888) .067 (.925) -.226 (.985) .339 (.725) -.057 (1.097) 858 .167 (.851) -.756 (.919) -1.449* (.747) .429 (.870) -.079 (.912) -.231 (.967) .048 (.703) -.007 (1.085) 858 -1.309 (1.018) -1.849* (1.110) -1.058 (.913) .750 (1.056) -.618 (1.100) -.228 (1.171) -1.140 (.862) 1.220 (1.305) 858 Adj R-square 0.286 0.280 0.457 Fisheries Regional Culture Development Constitution Women’s Petitions Notes: *** significant at 0.01 level, ** significant at 0.05 level, * significant at 0.1 level, reference category for party group dummies: EPP; the EDD was excluded due to a lack of data; regression 1 includes country dummies (not shown) reference category: UK; standard errors in parentheses The results of regression (1) and (2) broadly support the hypotheses developed in the previous sections and qualify some of the bivariate results presented above. First, in line with the party competition hypothesis, both estimations show that MEPs from the largest party group (EPP) have the highest representational performance scores. The coefficients for all other party groups are negative though they do not always assume statistical significance. In all three models the extreme left EUL has the lowest representational scores followed by Greens and ELDR. The scores for the Socialist PES are also negative and statistically significant though the gap between PES and EPP is less than that between EPP and party groups to the left of the PES. There is no representational discrepancy between the EPP and the anti-European UEN and Independents. Somewhat surprisingly, in light of Figure 2, the regression results do not support the hypothesised explanation of representational performance based on policy proximity to the largest party group (H1). Indeed, the EPP’s closest coalition partner on the left-right spectrum (ELDR) has a lower representational score than its main competitor (PES). In addition, the smallest party groups UEN and Independents have representational scores that are as high as that of the EPP. The national parties that form the UEN and the Independents distinguish themselves from other parties in the EP by their euroscepticism. The results in Table 4 show that legislators from smaller groups which are preference outliers are more successful in gaining salient rapporteurships than mainstream MEPs who have to compete with members of other parties with similar preferences. The results of the first two regressions unequivocally support H2, which stipulates that the party group leadership’s concern for policy coherence has an impact on the allocation of salient committee reports. In both models, an MEP’s policy distance from his party group negatively affects his ability to be allocated salient reports. Because the leadership is concerned with protecting the brand name of the party group and maintaining credibility, legislators who often defect from their group in roll-call votes are less likely to be assigned salient co-decision reports than their colleagues. In order to preserve group coherence, the leadership screens candidates ex ante to make sure their reports reflect the opinion of the group as a whole. In addition, party leaders use their power to allocate reports ex post to reward MEPs who have toed the party line and sanction defectors. Rebel MEPs are less likely to be assigned 14 reports that are salient to their national parties than MEPs who have policy preferences in line with the rest of the party group.3 The results also strongly support H3 and H4, which address the party group’s concern with maintaining loyalty by giving individual legislators a stake in its operation. In order to maintain unity, the leadership compensates rank-and-file members who have little influence over the operation of the group with a disproportionate number of salient reports. In all three estimations reported in Table 4, MEPs from smaller national parties have higher representational scores than legislators from larger parties (H3). In addition, committee chairs have lower representational scores than regular committee members (H4). Indeed, often committee chairs take responsibility for reports that no other committee member is willing to take on (Corbett et al, 2003). The third column in Table 4 replicates model (1) for non–codecision reports. As the descriptive analysis in this section has shown already, report allocation depends not only on their salience but also on the power they convey over policy. Table 4 strongly supports this conclusion. Indeed, none of the independent variables discussed in this section assumes any significance for non-codecision reports. The lack of significance of the party group dummies indicates that these reports are allocated on a purely proportional basis. Membership in one of the larger party groups does not constitute an representational advantage for non-co-decision reports. Similarly, reports that have little effect on policy outcomes cannot be used by the party group leadership to whip members into toeing the party group line. Neither leftright nor pro/anti-EU policy distance have any effect on the allocation of salient noncodecision reports. Finally, an MEP’s national party size and his committee status do not affect the allocation of these reports. In sum, the allocation of non-codecision reports follows purely proportional lines. There is no systematic variation in representational performance across or within party groups for these reports. The findings in Table 4 show empirical evidence of competition for codecision reports across party groups as well as for the “management dilemma” that affects the leadership within each group. First, a concern with policy coherence mandates that important legislative spoils be allocated to representatives whose policy preferences are close to the rest of the group. At the same time, the party’s efforts to encourage group cohesion means that rank-and-file members with little stake in the party are compensated with salient and influential policy tasks. Conclusion This paper models the consequences of committee report allocation for political representation in the European Parliament. Both inter- and intra party group dynamics determine an individual legislator's ability to represent the preferences of his national party. First, party groups compete for salient reports on the basis of their delegation size and left-right policy preferences. For co-decision reports, there is some evidence of minimum winning coalitions along a left-right spectrum. Second, the party group leadership distributes these reports among its MEPs in an attempt to maximize the policy coherence of the group while maintaining the loyalty of its members. MEPs from large national delegations, committee chairs and legislators whose policy preferences deviate from the rest of the group are allocated less salient reports than their party group colleagues. 3 At the same time, the lack of significance for the pro/anti EU distance measures support Hix (2004) claim that European politics in the EP has gradually become structured along a left-right spectrum similar to domestic politics. 15 Methodologically, the paper shows that political representation can and must be measured in terms of legislative behaviour. Studies of participation in the EP have only just begun and they have so far been limited to purely quantitative assessments (e.g. the number of reports allocated to each MEP) and a small range of legislative activities (e.g. roll call votes). Ultimately, political scientists are not only interested in the workload of representatives but in their influence over policy and the representational quality of their work. This paper indicates how these less directly observable characteristics of legislative participation can be systematically analysed. From a theoretical perspective, scholars of the democratic deficit in the EU have mostly focused on the European Parliament’s evolving nature and complex institutional setup in comparison with domestic political systems. The findings in this paper suggest that inter-party competition in the EP is strongest on issues over which the Parliament has a lot of policy power. At the same time, fragmentation of party groups along national lines accounts for the importance of cohesion and policy coherence in the distribution of legislative spoils. Rather than assessing its “normality” in comparison with national legislatures, academic scholarship on the European Parliament should investigate the conditional nature of party group competition and its implications for democratic representation. This paper develops a theoretical framework for addressing these questions that can be adapted to a large number of national and supra-national legislatures. References Andeweg, R. (1995) ‘The Reshaping of National Party Systems’, in Jack Hayward (ed.) The Crisis of Representation in Europe, London: Frank Cass. Attinà, Fulvio (1992) ‘Parties, Party Systems and Democracy in the European Union’, International Spectator, 27: 67-86. Bardi, Luciano (1994) ‘Transnational Party Federations, European Parliamentary Party Groups, and the Building of Europarties’, in Richard S. Katz and Peter Mair (eds) How Parties Organize: Change and Adaptation in Party Organizations in Western Democracies, London: Sage. Boucek, Francoise, the Structure and Dynamics of Intra-Party Politics in Europe, Perspectives on European Politics and Society, 3:3, (2002): 453-492. Budge, Ian, Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andreas, Bara, Judith and Eric Tanenbaum, Mapping Policy Preferences, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2001. Carrubba, C. J. and M. Gabel (1999). Roll-Call Votes and Party Discipline in the European Parliament: Reconsidering MEP Voting Behavior. EPRG Working Paper(2): (www.lse.ac.uk/Depts/eprg/dpf/Working%Paper%2.pdf. Corbett Richard, Francis Jacobs and Michael Shackleton, The European Parliament, 5th ed., London: John Harper, 2003. Crombez, C. (1997). The Co-Decision Procedure in the European Union. Legislative Studies Quarterly 22(1): 97-119. van der Eijk, Cees and Mark Franklin, (eds.), Choosing Europe The European Electorate and National Politics in the Face of Union, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1996. James Fearon. 1999. “Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance.” In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, Adam Przeworski, Susan Stokes, and BernardManin (eds.). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. pp. 55-97. 16 Hausemer, Pierre, Representation and Committee Assignments in the European Parliament, Paper presented at Midwest Political Science Association Annual Conference, Chicago, April 2005. Hix, Simon, Legislative Behavior and Party Competition in European Parliament: An Application of Nominate to the EU. Journal of Common Market Studies 39 (2001), 663-688.Hix, Simon, Parliamentary Behaviour with Two Principals: Preferences, Parties, and Voting in the European Parliament, American Journal of Political Science, v. 46 (2002) 688-98. Hix, Simon, Noury, Abdul and Gerard Roland, 'Power to the Parties: Competition and Cohesion in the European Parliament, 1979-2001', British Journal of Political Science, 34(4), (2004) 767-93. Hix, Simon and Christopher Lord, Political Parties in the European Union, London: MacMillan, 1997. Hoyland, Bjorn, Government – Opposition in Bicameral Negotiations: DecisionMaking in European Union’s Codecision Procedure, EPRG Working Paper N.12, (2005), available: http://www.lse.ac.uk/Depts/eprg Janda, Kenneth, Political Parties: A Cross-National Survey. New York: The Free Press, 1980 Kaeding, Michael, Rapporteurship Allocation in the European Parliament. Information or Distribution. European Union Politics 5 (3) (2004): 355-373. Kaeding, Michael, The world of committee reports: Rapporteurship assignment in the European Parliament, Journal of Legislative Studies, forthcoming. Katz, Richard, Representational Roles, European Journal of Political Research 32 (1997): 211–226. King, A. 1976. Modes of Executive-Legislative Relations: Great Britain, France, and West-Germany. Legislative Studies Quarterly 1 (1):11-36. Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Richard I. Hofferbert, Ian Budge, Parties, Policies, and Democracy, Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1994. Kreppel, Amie (2001) The European Parliament and the Supranational Party System, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Laver, Michael, Kenneth Benoit, and John Garry. ``Extracting Policy Positions from Political Texts Using Words as Data.'' American Political Science Review 97(2, May 2003):311-331. Levitt, Steven D., How Do Senators Vote? Disentangling the Role of Voter Preferences, Party Affiliation, and Senator Ideology, American Economic Review, Vol. 86, n. 3, (1996) 425-41. Mamadouh, Virginie and Tapio Raunio, The Committee System: Power, Appointments, and Report Allocation, Journal of Common Market Studies, vol. 41, No. 2 (2003) pp. 333-51. Mamadouh, Virginie and Tapio Raunio, Allocatiung Reports in the European Parliament: How parties Influence Committee Work, EPRG Working Paper N.7, (2001) available: http://www.lse.ac.uk/Depts/eprg. Marsh, Michael and Bernhard Wessels, Territorial Representation, European Journal of Political Research 32: ( 1997): 227–241. McElroy, Gail, Committees and Party Cohesion in the European Parliament, EPRG Working paper no.8, (2001), available: http://www.lse.ac.uk/Depts/eprg 17 Moravcsik, Andrew, In Defence of the Democratic Deficit: Reassessing Legitimacy in the European Union, Journal of Common Market Studies, Vol. 40, n. 4 (2002). Muller, Wolfgang, Political Parties in Parliamentary Democracies: Making Delegation and Accountability Work, European Journal of Political Research, vol 37 (2000): 309-333. Norris, Pippa and Mark Franklin, Social Representation, European Journal of Political Research 32, (1997): 185–21. Noury, A. (2002). Ideology, Nationality and Euro-Parliamentarians. European Union Politics 3(1): 33-58. Raunio, Tapio, The European Perspective: Transnational Party Groups in the 19891994 European Parliament, Aldershot: Ashgate, 1997. Sartori, Giovanni (1976) Parties and Party Systems: A Framework for Analysis, Volume I, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Schmitt, Hermann and Jacques Thomassen, Dynamic Representation: The Case of European Integration, Arbeitspapiere – Mannheimer Zentrum fuer Sozialforschung, n. 21 (2000). Thomassen, Jacques and Herrmann Schmitt, Policy Representation, European Journal of Political Research 32, (1997) 165–184. Tsebelis, G and Garrett, G. (1997). “Agenda-Setting, Vetoes and the European Union’s Co-decision Procedure”, Journal of Legislative Studies, Vol. 3, n.3, 74-92. Tsebelis, G. and G. Garrett (2000). Legislative Politics in the European Union. European Union Politics 1(1): 9-36. Weingast, Barry and William J Marshall, The Industrial Organization of Congress; or Why Legislatures, Like Firms, Are Not Organized as Markets, Journal of Political Economy, vol 96 (11) (1988): 132-163. Wessels, Bernhard, Whom to Represent? Role Orientations of Legislators in Europe, in Hermann Schmitt and Jacques Thomassen (eds.) Political Representation and Legitimacy in the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999. 18 Appendix – Descriptive Statistics EPP PES ELDR GREEN EUL UEN EDD IND Party Size Foreign Affairs Budgets Budgetary Ctrl JHA Economics Legal Affairs Research Social Affairs Environment Agriculture Fisheries Regional Affairs Culture Development Constitution Women’s Affairs Petitions Incumbent District Austria Belgium Germany Spain France Greece Italy Denmark Luxembourg Netherlands Finland Portugal Ireland Sweden UK Representation Score (Codecision) Left-right Dist (PG) Representation Score (Other) Pro-anti dist (EPG) # Reports Chair Influence Valid N (listwise) N 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 1316 Min 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 901 1254 901 1254 1316 1316 1316 858 19 Max 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 53 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 99 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 Mean .38 .27 .08 .08 .06 .04 .03 .05 16.74 .1900 .14 .07 .14 .14 .12 .18 .18 .20 .13 .09 .19 .11 .11 .09 .14 .10 .50 53.10 .04 .04 .15 .11 .12 .04 .14 .03 .01 .06 .03 .04 .03 .03 .14 Std Dev. .49 .45 .28 .27 .25 .19 .17 .22 15.68 .39 .35 .26 .34 .34 .3 .38 .39 .40 .34 .28 .39 .31 .31 .29 .35 .30 .50 36.35 .19 .19 .36 .31 .33 .19 .35 .16 .10 .23 .16 .20 .16 .17 .34 0 185.96 1.66 8.28 0 0 0 0 0 0 - .89 109.17 1.11 24 1 1 - .09 4.79 .15 .84 .01 .10 - .15 11.35 .15 1.56 .12 .27 - Party Manifestos – Coding Frame No. Description Committee 101 Foreign Relations: Positive 1 102 Foreign Relations: Negative 1 103 Anti-imperialism 1 104 Military: Positive 1 105 Military: Negative 1 106 Peace 107 Internationalism: Positive 1 108 European Community: Positive 15 109 Internationalism: Negative 1 110 European Community: Negative 15 201 Freedom & Human Rights 1,4 1,14 202 Democracy 4 203 Constitutionalism: Positive 4 204 Constitutionalism: Negative 4 301 Decentralisation 12 302 Centralisation 12 304 Political Corruption 4 401 Free Enterprise 5 402 Incentives 5 403 Market Regulation 5 404 Economic Planning 5 405 Corporatism 406 Protectionism: Positive 5,7 5 5,7 407 Protectionism: Negative 410 Productivity 5 411 Technology & Infrastructure 7 412 Controlled Economy 5 413 Nationalization 5 414 Economic Orthodoxy 5 501 Environmental Protection 9 502 Culture 13 503 Social Justice 16 504 Welfare State Expansion 8 505 Welfare State Limitation 8 506 Education Expansion 13 507 Education Limitation 13 605 Law & Order 4 606 Social Harmony 8 607 Multiculturalism: Positive 8 608 Multiculturalism: Negative 8 703 Agriculture & Farmers 10,11 Note: See pp. 222-8 in Budge et al., (2001) for more detailed descriptions of Variables 20