Econ 302 Assignment 3 — Solution 1. (a) The monopolist solves: max Π(Q) = Q(a − bQ) − cQ. Q The first order condition is a − 2bQ − c = 0, or equivalently, a−c , 2b which is the monopolist’s optimal quantity; the associated price is Q= P (Q) = a − b a−c 2b = a+c . 2 (b) Fix a symmetric strategy profile in which every firm produces q units. The profit of any firm (say firm 1) when he produces q1 and the others each produce q is: Π1 (q1 ) = q1 P (q1 + (n − 1)q) − cq1 = q1 (a − b(q1 + (n − 1)q)) − cq1 . Given q, firm 1 wants to maximize Π1 (q1 ). The first order condition of firm 1 with respect to q1 is a − b(n − 1)q − 2bq1 − c = 0, which gives firm 1’s best-response to q of others: q1 = a − b(n − 1)q − c . 2b At a symmetric Nash equilibrium, we must have q1 = q, i.e., q= a − b(n − 1)q − c , 2b 1 or equivalently, q= a−c . (n + 1)b The market price given these quantities is P (nq) = a − n 1 n (a − c) = a+ c. n+1 n+1 n+1 a−c is the symmetric pure-strategy Nash equilibIn summary, each firm produces q = (n+1)b 1 n rium. The equilibrium price is n+1 a + n+1 c. Figure 1: Graph for Problem 1, part (c). (c) In the graph, P M and QM are the monopolist’s price and quantity, P C and QC are the price and total quantity from the Nash equilibrium in the quantity competition game (Cournot competition), and QP C = a−c is the quantity from perfect competition: b P (QP C ) = a − bQP C = c. 2 The deadweight loss for monopoly is 1 M 1 (P − c)(QP C − QM ) = 2 2 a+c −c 2 a−c a−c − b 2b = (a − c)2 . 8b The deadweight loss for Cournot competition is 1 C 1 (P − c)(QP C − QC ) = 2 2 1 n a+ c−c n+1 n+1 a − c n(a − c) − b (n + 1)b = (a − c)2 . 2(n + 1)2 b Notice that the deadweight loss for Cournot competition (n ≥ 2) is decreasing with n, and is always smaller than the deadweight loss for monopoly (and becomes the same when n = 1). In other words, competition reduces the deadweight loss. (d) Assume Cournot/quantity competition. As the number n of firms tends to infinity, in the Nash equilibrium the price tends to c and the deadweight loss tends to 0, i.e., we get convergence to perfect competition. 2. The profit of firm 1 when he produces q1 while firm 2 produces q2 is: Π1 (q1 ) = q1 (10 − (q1 + q2 )) − 2q1 . Given q2 , firm 1 wants to maximize Π1 (q1 ). The first order condition of firm 1 with respect to q1 is 10 − q2 − 2q1 − 2 = 0, which gives firm 1’s best-response to q2 : 8 − q2 . 2 Likewise, the profit of firm 2 when he produces q2 while firm 1 produces q1 is: q1 = (1) Π2 (q2 ) = q2 (10 − (q1 + q2 )) − (q2 )2 . Given q1 , firm 1 wants to maximize Π2 (q2 ). The first order condition of firm 2 with respect to q2 is 3 10 − q1 − 2q2 − 2q2 = 0, which gives firm 2’s best-response to q1 : 10 − q1 . (2) 4 At a Nash equilibrium, we must have mutually best responses, i.e., a solution to Equations (1) and (2). It is easy to show that the solution, and hence the Nash equilibrium, is q2 = 22 12 , q2 = . 7 7 The market price given these (Nash equilibrium) quantities is q1 = P (q1 + q2 ) = 10 − 34 36 = . 7 7 3. There are many pure-strategy Nash equilibria in this game. Below I describe all possible equilibria. (a) For any p1 ∈ [2.01, 3], it is a Nash equilibrium for firm 1 to set p1 as his price, and firm 2 to set p2 = p1 + 0.01; in this equilibrium, firm 1 captures the whole market and sells Q(p1 ) = 10 − p1 units. In the Nash equilibrium (p1 , p2 = p1 + 0.01) where p1 + 0.01 < 3, firm 2 sets his price below his marginal cost of 3, which seems irrational. However, this p2 = p1 + 0.01 is a best response to p1 because firm 2 never gets a chance to actually sell at this price, so he gets a profit of 0 in any case. You should check that for firm i, any pi < ci is weakly dominated by pi = ci ; this is a good exercise in reviewing the concept of dominance. This means that a weakly dominated strategy can still be a part of a Nash equilibrium, in contrast to strict dominance. However, a Nash equilibrium with a weakly dominated strategy is not very plausible in practice. (b) For any p1 ∈ [2.01, 3], it is a Nash equilibrium for firm 1 to set p1 as his price, firm j to set pj = p1 + 0.01 for some j between 2 and 5, and the rest of the firms to set pi > p1 , where i 6= j and i 6= 1; in this equilibrium, firm 1 captures the whole market and sells Q(p1 ) = 10 − p1 units. 4 (c) For this case it makes sense to distinguish between two classes of Nash equilibria: Class 1. It is a Nash equilibrium for firm 1 to set p1 = 6, and firm 2 to set any p2 > 6; in this equilibrium, firm 1 captures the whole market and sells Q(6) = 4 units. Class 2. For any p1 ∈ [2.01, 5.99], it is a Nash equilibrium for firm 1 to set p1 as his price, and firm 2 to set p2 = p1 + 0.01; in this equilibrium, firm 1 captures the whole market and sells Q(p1 ) = 10 − p1 units. Note that p1 = 6 is firm 1’s optimal price when he is the monopolist: max q(10 − q) − 2q ⇐⇒ q q = 4, P (q) = 6. In part (a) and (b), firm 1 also wants to have a price of 6, but he is forced to sell at a price of at most 3 because given p1 = 6 > 3 = c2 firm 2 would undercut this price, so p1 = 6 is not a sustainable price. 5