WORKING PAPER Job Insecurity, Unemployment Insurance and Onthe-Job Search Evidence from Older American Workers Italo Gutierrez RAND Labor & Population WR-1085-1 August 2015 This paper series made possible by the NIA funded RAND Center for the Study of Aging (P30AG012815) and the NICHD funded RAND Population Research Center (R24HD050906). RAND working papers are intended to share researchers’ latest findings and to solicit informal peer review. They have been approved for circulation by RAND Labor and Population but have not been formally edited or peer reviewed. Unless otherwise indicated, working papers can be quoted and cited without permission of the author, provided the source is clearly referred to as a working paper. RAND’s publications do not necessarily reflect the opinions of its research clients and sponsors. RAND® is a registered trademark. Job Insecurity, Unemployment Insurance and Onthe-Job Search Evidence from Older American Workers Italo A. Gutierrez, RAND italo@rand.org August, 2015 Abstract In this study I estimate that about 23% to 47% of older American on-the-job seekers search for another job because they feel insecure at their current employment. I also analyze whether unemployment insurance (UI) affects this relationship between job insecurity and on-the-job search. I find evidence that UI discourages on-the-job search, which in turn reduces the probability of starting a new job at a different employer. The average estimated effects are moderate but they mask important heterogeneities. On one hand, UI does not affect the search behavior of workers who do not believe to be at risk of job loss. These workers make up the majority of the employed population over 50. On the other hand, however, the effects can be substantial for workers with high levels of job insecurity. JEL Classification Codes: J64, J65, D84 Keywords: on-the-job search; unemployment benefits; job loss expectations; control function methods 1. INTRODUCTION The effects of unemployment insurance (UI) on job search behavior have been extensively studied for the case of unemployed individuals. In contrast, we know little about the effects of UI on the job search behavior of employed workers. To address this issue we first need to acknowledge job insecurity as an important factor for explaining on-the-job search (OJS). This is usually overlooked in the standard job search literature, where OJS and job transitions are explained only by a job ladder motivation. In other words, OJS is motivated by the workers' desire to improve their utility, usually defined in terms of a combination of wages, promotion opportunities and job amenities. However, in reality, job insecurity can be the main reason for OJS for a non-trivial fraction of job seekers. For example, Fujita (2011) documents that the primary reason for OJS for 12% of job seekers in the United Kingdom (2002-2009) is the fear of losing their jobs. 1 Similarly, Rosal (2003) documents that 27% of onthe-job seekers in Spain (2000) engaged in OJS because of their job instability. 2 Furthermore, acknowledging the importance of job insecurity for job search decisions might help explain the substantial share of job-to-job transitions with wage cuts observed in OECD countries. 3 In order to explore the importance of the job insecurity motivation for OJS I use information from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS). Although the HRS only surveys individuals who are 50 year and older, its main advantage is that it collects information on OJS and on job loss expectations. I find that among older American workers job insecurity can explain 23% to 47% (depending on the estimation method) of the incidence of on-the-job search. To the best of my knowledge, this is the first study that estimates the importance of job-insecurity for OJS decisions in the U.S. (either for older workers or for other age groups). Given the important role that job insecurity plays in explaining OJS, I also examine whether that effect is moderated by the availability of UI. Because UI reduces the financial cost of unemployment, it can also reduce the effect of job insecurity on OJS. As a consequence, workers experiencing job insecurity may be less likely to look for alternative jobs and thus at higher risk of entering 1 The source is the United Kingdom Labour Force Survey and the sample period is from the first quarter of 2002 to the first quarter of 2009. 2 The source is the Spanish Survey of Economically Active Population (Encuesta de Poblacion Activa) from the second quarter of 2000. 3 According to Jolivet et al. (2006) “between 25% and 40%, with substantial variation across countries, of job-to-job transitions are associated with wage cuts.” 1 unemployment. Understanding better this potential interaction between job insecurity, UI and job search is important given the substantial evidence that job displacement has persistent negative effects on earnings (Couch and Placzek, 2010; Fallick, 1996; Jacobson et al., 1993; Kletzer, 1998) and in the case of older workers it can lead to early exit from the labor force (Chan and Stevens, 1999, 2001). Only a couple of papers have specifically focused on how UI can alter workers' OJS decisions in the face of job insecurity (Burgess and Low, 1998; Light and Omori, 2004). 4 This research contributes to this literature by using information on workers' job loss expectations and potential UI benefits (expressed in terms of replacement rates) to test two predictions from a simple job search model: i) UI discourages job search but only for workers who feel at risk of job loss and ii) the effect is larger the higher is the risk of job loss perceived by the worker. The data provides empirical support for both of these predictions. I also find supportive evidence from the analysis of employment transitions. I find that UI reduces the probability that workers move to a new job at a different employer, and this effect is stronger for workers that report higher levels of job insecurity. In sum, the evidence presented in this research implies that UI reduces the probability of OJS and therefore affects employment transitions. It also highlights the importance of taking into account individuals' job insecurity levels as a significant source of heterogeneity in those effects. The next section describes more in detail the few previous studies that have looked at how workers react towards the risk job loss and unemployment and how this behavior can be changed by UI benefits. Section 3 presents a simple model of OJS and describes the main predictions that I test in the data. Section 4 describes the data sources and econometric strategy to estimate the effect of UI on both the probability of OJS and on employment transitions. Section 5 presents the estimation results and sensitivity analysis, and Section 6 concludes. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Workers' job search behavior change with their expectations of job loss, as first evidenced in the studies on the effects of advanced layoff notifications. Burgess and Low (1992) found that 60.6% of male workers who received layoff notification searched for alternative jobs before their employment 4 Other research have studied the effect of UI on the risk of unemployment, but do not focus on workers' OJS decisions (Anderson and Meyer, 1993; Card and Levine, 1994; Christofides and McKenna, 1995, 1996; Feldstein, 1976, 1978; Green and Riddell, 1997; Green and Sargent, 1998; Jurajda, 2002, 2003; Lalive et al., 2011; Rebollo-Sanz, 2012; Topel, 1983; Winter-Ebmer, 2003). 2 were terminated. In comparison, only 38.9% of workers who did not receive such notification searched for a job before termination. Addison and Blackburn (1995) found that the main benefit of providing advanced layoff notifications is increasing the probability of finding a job before displacement (especially for white collar males) rather than reducing the length of jobless spells. More recent evidence from firm closures also indicates that workers' job loss expectations affect their job search behavior. Lengermann and Vilhuber (2002) found that in the U.S. highly qualified workers tend to voluntarily separate early from distressed firms before they close. Schwerdt (2011) founds similar evidence for the Austrian labor market. Fallick and Fleischman (2001) also document, using information from the Current Population Survey (CPS), that OJS predicts not only job-to-job transitions but also job-to-unemployment transitions. They report that the probability of transitioning from employment into unemployment in one month was 5.6% for active searchers versus 0.9% for nonsearchers. This finding indicates that OJS can be motivated by a higher probability of separation. In the theoretical ground, Tudela and Smith (2012) have developed an equilibrium model to formalize the idea that workers engage in job search not only to find better paying jobs but also to insure themselves against the possibility of non-employment. In their model past search experiences becomes capital that (partially) insures workers against displacement. In other words, if workers get displaced, they can use their network of contacts as a fallback to avoid unemployment. The strength of the relationship between job insecurity and job search behavior can be affected by different institutional arrangements. For example, severance pay requirements and UI benefits reduce the financial cost of unemployment. Thus, they can also discourage workers from searching for alternative jobs and avoiding unemployment. These potential effects have been understudied in the literature. In the case of UI most previous studies focus on the unemployed and on the effects of UI on the duration of unemployment spells (Krueger and Meyer, 2002; Meyer, 1995). For employed individuals, previous research has also found an increase in the risk of exiting employment either after qualifying for UI benefits (Christofides and McKenna, 1995, 1996; Green and Riddell, 1997; Green and Sargent, 1998; Jurajda, 2002; Rebollo-Sanz, 2012) or after extensions in the duration of potential benefits (Fitzenberger and Wilke, 2009; Haan and Prowse, 2010; Lalive et al., 2011; Winter-Ebmer, 2003). 3 Although the effects of UI on job search effort could partly explain some of these findings, only a couple of papers have directly studied this mechanism. 5 The first study on the effect of UI on OJS was done by Burgess and Low (1998). Using data from displaced workers in Arizona, they found that UI benefits strongly discouraged pre-displacement job search for workers who received advanced layoff notification and did not expect to be recalled by their employers. In their study a $10 increase in weekly UI benefits above the sample mean reduced the likelihood of OJS by 8 percentage points from 59.7% to 51.7%. Conversely, they found no statistically significant effect of UI on the likelihood of OJS for non-notified workers or for notified workers who expected to be recalled by their employers. In other words, UI did not change the search behavior of workers who felt less job-insecure (either because they were not notified about being laid off or because they believed that unemployment would be only temporary). Although these results are sensible, two limitations threaten their validity as acknowledged by the authors. First, there is a selection problem because the study sample was comprised of workers with at least five weeks of unemployment. Therefore, workers who performed more OJS were less likely to be part of the sample. Second, since all respondents were unemployed individuals in Arizona in the years 1975-1976 there is no variation in UI benefits other than that due to the workers’ earnings histories. In other words, there is no exogenous variation in UI benefits that could be used to identify their effects on OJS. The second study of the effect of UI on OJS is Light and Omori (2004). They formulated a theoretical model linking UI benefits to OJS and to employment transitions. They tested the predictions from the model using the 1979 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY79). If UI reduces incentives to perform OJS then higher UI benefits would be associated with a decline in job-to-job (JTJ) transitions and an increase in job-to-non-employment (JTN) transitions. The authors find evidence of this effect, although its size is very small. They find that a one standard deviation increase above the mean in weekly UI benefits reduced the probability of a JTJ transition in the next 15 weeks (for a worker with 30 weeks of tenure) from 0.047 to 0.045 (or an elasticity of -0.09). A shortcoming in their study is the lack of a measure of the workers' beliefs about job security. As I discuss in the next section, UI only reduces the value of OJS if the worker feels vulnerable to job loss. Furthermore, the higher the 5 There is also a relatively well-developed literature on the effect of the imperfect rated UI payroll tax on the probability of layoff (Anderson and Meyer, 1993; Card and Levine, 1994; Feldstein, 1976; Topel, 1983, 1984), although in this case UI is postulated to affect employers' layoff decisions rather than workers' job search behavior. 4 risk of job loss, the stronger is the negative effect of UI on the value of job search. Thus, without allowing the effect of UI to change with the level of job insecurity one would capture the effect for the average worker, which can be very small. In fact, as suggested by the responses in the Survey of Economic Expectations (SEE) and in the HRS, the average worker feels relatively secure in the job. 6 Hence, it is not surprising that the effects in Light and Omori (2004) were relatively small. In this paper, I use the HRS to add new evidence on whether OJS is discouraged by the generosity of UI. There are two main advantages of using the HRS. First, it contains information on worker’s expectation of job loss, which allows testing the theoretical prediction that UI have stronger effects for workers who feel more job-insecure. Second, HRS contains information on OJS and -given its panel structure- it also contains information on workers’ employment transitions. Therefore, I can estimate the effect of UI on both outcomes. 3. THEORY AND TESTABLE PREDICTIONS Mortensen (1977) showed that in a fully dynamic setting the effect of UI benefits on unemployed individuals' job search effort is ambiguous. An increase in benefits has two opposing effects: 1) it increases the value of being unemployed, and 2) it increases the value of future employment since better paying jobs come with better UI benefits – known as the “entitlement effect”. Mortensen (1977) showed that the first effect reduces the incentives to search for a job and increases the length of the unemployment spell. This effect is more dominant at the beginning of the spell. Conversely, the entitlement effect creates incentives for workers to search more because there is higher reward (in terms of better UI benefits) for finding a good-paying job. This effect decreases the length of the unemployment spell and dominates when the worker is near the end of the benefit period. UI has the same ambiguous effect on OJS. On one hand, UI reduces the cost of falling into unemployment. On the other hand, it increases the payoff from getting a higher-paying job since it comes with better UI benefits. Therefore, in theory the effect of more generous UI on OJS would be ambiguous. However, for older workers the second effect is less important for two reasons: First, since the entitlement effect is a forward-looking effect its importance decreases as the remaining working years also decrease. In my analysis sample, the average worker is 56 years old. Thus, the length of the remaining working years 6 In the SEE, the average value of the respondent’s expected probability of job loss in the next twelve months is 11% for workers aged 50 years or older (years 1994 through 1998). In the HRS, the average value is 18% (years 1996 through 2012). 5 until retirement is relatively short. Second, each state in the U.S. sets a maximum level of weekly unemployment benefits. The entitlement effect does not exist for workers whose potential UI benefits are already limited by that maximum level. Because earnings usually increase with experience and age, about 50% of the older workers in my sample have earnings that would put their UI benefits above their state's maximum level. For these two reasons, I use a simple model that abstracts from the entitlement effect. I borrow the model originally proposed by Light and Omori (2004), with a few modifications, to derive theoretical predictions that I test in the data. 7 The proposed model consists of two periods. 8 In the first period, the worker is employed and earns . The maximization problem of the worker is to decide whether to search on-the-job or not. If the worker decides to search then has to pay a fixed cost of , which is distributed among workers with probability function ( ). In each period, the flow utility is given by the logarithm of the available earnings and the fixed cost of search (if the worker searches on the job). If a worker searches, the probability of receiving an offer in the second period equals . Offers come from a known distribution ( ), with density function ( ), and at most one offer can be received. The worker faces a probability of layoff in period 2 equal to ; and if laid off, the worker can collect UI benefits equal to , where is the replacement rate. If the worker decides not to search for a job, there are two possible scenarios for the second period: 1) with probability (1 and 2) with probability ) does not lose the job and continuous receiving earnings equal to loses the job and takes unemployment benefits equal to ; . Four different scenarios can occur in the second period if the worker decides to search for a job: 1) with probability (1 )(1 ) does not lose the job and does not receive an offer. In this scenario the worker continues receiving earnings equal to ; 2) with probability (1 ) the worker loses the job and does not receive an offer. In this scenario, the worker takes unemployment benefits equal to probability (1 ; 3) with ), the worker does not lose the job and receives an offer. In this scenario the worker takes the new job as long as the offered wage is greater than 7 ; and 4) with probability , the worker Light and Omori (2004) model OJS as a continuous outcome, whether in my specification it is modeled as a binary decision (yes/no) and I introduce a fixed cost of search. I do this modification to fit the available data from HRS (see next section). Light and Omori (2004) measure the generosity of the unemployment insurance system by the potential UI benefits that a worker is entitled to if the job is lost. My measure of generosity is the replacement rate, i.e. the fraction of lost earnings that UI benefits would replace. 8 In a two-period model, there is no entitlement effect by construction since only the immediate future (period 2) matters for the period 1 decision. 6 loses the job and receives an offer. In this scenario, the worker takes the offer as long as the offered wage is greater than . Thus, the maximization problem for the worker in period 1 consists of deciding whether to search on the job or not, as described below (where denotes the worker’s time discount factor): { ; {log( )= [(1 (1 ) + [(1 )(1 ) log( {log( ) {log( ) log( )+ ) + (1 ) log( log( ) , log( )} ( ) ) , log( )} ( ) )]; log( ) + )) + + } (1) Note that in this model the reservation wage to take a job offer in the second period if the worker does not lose the job is , whereas the reservation wage if the worker loses the job is . Thus, the expected value of a job offer is larger if the worker loses the job. As a consequence, workers with higher expectations of layoff are willing to bear a higher maximum search cost to engage in OJS. This analysis leads to the first testable prediction from the model (the formal proofs of all predictions are deferred to the Appendix): Prediction 1: Other things equal, workers with greater probability of job loss are more likely to search on the job. Note also that an increase in the replacement rate ( ) reduces the expected value of a job offer because it increases the reservation wage in case of unemployment, or . However, this effect does not matter if there is zero probability of job loss. Conversely, for workers with a positive probability of job loss, an increase in reduces the maximum search cost that workers are willing to accept to engage in OJS and therefore they are less likely to search on the job. Moreover, increases in have a larger impact on search decisions the more likely it is that job offers will be measured against the reservation wage in period 2. In other words, the effects are larger the higher is the probability of job loss. This analysis brings the next two predictions from the model: Prediction 2: An increase in the replacement rate leads to a decrease in the probability of OJS but only for workers with non-zero probability of layoff (i.e. > 0). Prediction 3: The higher the probability of layoff (p), the larger is the negative effect that the replacement rate has on the probability of OJS (under plausible conditions on ). 7 The model also provides interesting predictions regarding the effect of the replacement rate on employment transitions, either from the current job to another job or from the current job to nonemployment. Since an increase in the replacement rate decreases the probability of OJS, it will also decrease the probability of JTJ transitions and, as a result, increase the probability of entering nonemployment. As in the case with OJS, these effects are at work only if the worker has a non-zero risk of job loss and the effects get stronger the larger is the risk of job loss. Thus, the next prediction from the model that I test in the data is: Prediction 4: The replacement rate does not affect the probabilities of employment transitions if the worker is not at risk of job loss (i.e. = 0 ). For workers with a non-zero risk of job loss, an increase in the replacement rate increases the likelihood of falling into non-employment and decreases the likelihood of moving to a new job. These effects are stronger the larger is the risk of job loss. Finally, changes in the OJS decision affects the probability of a job-to-job (JTJ) transition regardless of whether the worker is laid off or not. In comparison, changes in OJS only affect the job-tonon employment (JTN) transition if the worker is laid off. Thus, the final testable prediction from the model is: Prediction 5: Given that the worker has a positive probability of job loss ( > 0), the effect of an increase in the replacement rate is larger (in absolute value) on JTJ transitions than on JTN transitions. 4. DATA AND EMPIRICAL SPECIFICATION The main data source is the HRS, a nationally representative longitudinal dataset of Americans over the age of 50. 9 This survey, conducted every two years since 1992, collects information about work status, earnings, and several job characteristics, among other variables. The HRS also elicits the subjective probability of job loss through the following question: “Sometimes people are permanently laid off from jobs that they want to keep. On the (same) scale from 0 to 100 where 0 equals absolutely no chance and 100 equals absolutely certain, what are the chances that you will lose your job during the next year?.” The median response is zero, which indicates that most workers feel relatively safe in their jobs. Besides 9 The Health and Retirement Study (HRS) data is sponsored by the National Institute on Ageing (grant number U01AG009740) and was conducted by the University of Michigan. 8 zero, there are also important bunching of responses at 10% and 50%, and to a lesser extent around 90%, which is indicative that responses might be rounded around some focal points (see Figure 1).10 [Figure 1about here] I include in my analysis workers who are between 50 and 62 years old, but exclude those who are self-employed. I also exclude observations from states with small sample sizes to avoid convergence problems in the bootstrapped maximum likelihood. 11 The sample covers the period 19962006 and 2010-2012, since the question on the subjective probability of job loss was not included in the 2008 wave. The resulting initial sample size included 12,526 respondents and 32,309 respondent-year observations. I dropped 4,229 observations because of missing information regarding on-the-job search, subjective job loss probability or weekly wages. In order to minimize the number of workers who are ineligible for UI benefits due to low earnings, I follow Gruber (1997) and drop those cases where the estimated weekly benefits would be below the state's weekly minimum UI benefits amount. This accounts only for additional 4 observations being excluded. Finally, I drop observations with missing values on other controls. The final sample for the analysis includes 10,440 respondents and 23,906 respondent-year observations. Table 1 shows the mean and the standard deviation of outcomes and selected covariates of interest in the final sample. The average individual is 56 years old and women represent 57% of the sample. On average, the subjective probability of job loss is 18% and about 12% of workers report to be looking for a new job. The average potential replacement rate (i.e. the fraction of lost earnings that UI benefits would replace) is 42%. This variable is constructed using the worker’s weekly earnings ( ), the states' nominal replacement fraction ( ) and the state's limit on weekly benefits in each year ( ). Given that I previously excluded workers with calculated benefits below the state statutory minimum amount, each worker potential replacement rate is determined by equation (2) below: 12 10 Manski and Molinari (2010) and Kleinjans and van Soest (2010) found evidence of rounding responses for subjective probability questions in the HRS, with the extent of rounding differing across respondents. 11 States included in the analysis are Alabama, Arizona, Arkansas, California, Colorado, Connecticut, Florida, Georgia, Illinois, Indiana, Iowa, Kansas, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maine, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Minnesota, Mississippi, Missouri, Nebraska, Nevada, New Hampshire, New Jersey, New York, North Carolina, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, Oregon, Pennsylvania, South Carolina, Tennessee, Texas, Virginia, Washington, West Virginia, Wisconsin and Wyoming. 12 Note that I use pre-tax levels of earnings and benefits, whereas Gruber (1997) uses after-tax levels. I use pre-tax levels so that the replacement rate is only a function of the two main legislated parameters regarding UI benefits in a state/year: the nominal replacement rate and the maximum level of weekly benefits. Pre-tax levels avoid bringing into the calculation other household characteristics that can affect the tax rate. It is also worth noticing that Gruber uses after-tax dollars to 9 { × , = } (2) [Table 1 about here] To test the theoretical predictions from Section 3, I start by modelling the probability that an employed individual at time is looking for another job. Denote by , the latent index in a probit model for the likelihood that an employed individual is looking for another job. As shown in equation (3), I model , as a function of the subjective probability of job loss ( replacement rate if the job is lost ( , = + , ), the potential wage ) and the interaction of these two variables. , , + , + , × , + , + (3) , Since the replacement rate is a function of the worker’s earnings, I need to disentangle the effect of earnings from the effect of the replacement rate itself on the probability of OJS. Thus, I also added a fifth-order polynomial in wages to the model to account for the fact that wages determine nonlinear way. In addition to wages, vector in a , controls for other characteristics that may affect job , search decisions such as age, gender, race and ethnicity, education attainment, occupation category (white, pink or blue collar), self-reported health, part-time employment, industry, employer-sponsored health insurance, job-related stress and physical requirements (heavy lifting). It also contains a set of state and year dummy variables. The theoretical model not only gives predictions about the effect of , on the probability of OJS, but also on how it affects employment transitions. This is of particular importance for understanding the extent to which UI might affect unemployment and the rate of transitions between jobs. In order to test the predictions from the theoretical model, I use a multinomial probit to analyze how , , , and their interaction predicts employment in the next wave ( + 1). I define three possible employment outcomes in + 1: i) non-employment, ii) employment at a new employer, and iii) continued employment at the current employer. Denote by likelihood of each employment outcome ,, > for all ,, the latent variable that measures the ,, in the next wave. Outcome . The empirical specification for , ,, will occur in the next wave if is similar to the one for , , as shown in equation (4): ,, = + , + , + , × , + , + ,, (4) account for the fact that UI benefits became taxable within his period of analysis (1968-1987). In contrast, in my period of analysis (1996-2012) there was no change in the tax treatment status of UI benefits. 10 Addressing potential endogeneity Both , and , can be determined by unobserved factors that also affect job search decisions or employment transitions. For example, pessimism). In the case of can correlate with unobserved personality traits (such as , , a shortcoming of controlling for wages is that they are endogenous and , can correlate with other workers’ and jobs’ unobserved characteristics (e.g. high productivity). To address the potential endogeneity in , and , (and their interaction) I employ a control function (CF) approach (and drop wages from the controls vector , ). An advantage of the CF approach is that it can be more efficient than standard instrumental variables (IV) approaches, albeit at the cost of assuming that one has modelled correctly the conditional mean of the error term (Wooldridge, 2007; Wooldridge, 2015). Another advantage is that an IV approach cannot be applied directly in some non-linear models like the multinomial probit. Conversely, CF methods can be easily applied in non-linear models and are computationally simple (Wooldridge, 2015). To apply CF methods, I need to model the conditional mean for the error terms in equations (4) and (5). I start by modelling the reduced-form equation for and , , as: , , The terms , and , = = + + , , + + + , + , , , + + (5) , (6) , in equations (5) and (6) are exogenous variables in the sense that are uncorrelated with the unobserved components , , ,, , , and , . The variable , measures whether the employer has downsized recently. Downsizing is posited to increase subjective expectations of job loss by reasons that are exogenous to the workers. The HRS asks respondents whether their employers have downsized since the last interview or since they started working if they were hired between waves. 13 The fraction of workers in the sample that reports downsizing is around 25% in the late 1990s and early 2000s and increases sharply to 40% in the 2010 wave. In Gutierrez and Michaud (2015), we document that the average rates of downsizing reported in the HRS are consistent with the available information in studies that use firms’ employment records. Table 2 shows that, as 13 The question is worded as follows: “Has your employer experienced a permanent reduction in employment since [last interview month and year/ month and year respondent started job/ 2 years ago]?,” with interviewers coding references to downsizing and permanent layoffs as “yes” and those to temporary layoffs as “no”. 11 expected, workers whose employer has downsized recently report on average a subjective probability of job loss that is 7.4 percentage points higher than that for workers at non-downsizing employers, after controlling for observed characteristics. The variable , measures states’ generosity in UI benefits for workers above 50. I construct it following Gruber (1997) simulated instrument approach (see also Currie and Gruber (1996a, b)). To attain a large enough sample per state of workers above 50, I pool three waves (2001, 2003 and 2005) of the Current Population Survey (CPS) Annual Social and Economic Supplement (ASEC) and keep the employed individuals in each state that are over 50 years old. Then I use this pooled sample and the information on each state’s UI rules to calculate the average potential replacement rates (APRR) for the working population over 50 years old, for each state and year in the period 1996-2012. In other words, I keep the sample of workers within a state fixed across years and use the corresponding state-year UI benefit rules for calculating the APRR. 14 I calculate separate APRR for men and women in each stateyear combination because men on average have higher earnings. Therefore, men are more likely to be affected by the limit on weekly benefits and to have lower replacement rates. Table 2 shows that the APRR is a strong predictor of , , even after controlling for observed characteristics including gender, year and state dummies. Notice that after controlling for these characteristics, the remaining variation in the APRR that is used for identification purposes comes from changes in the benefits rules (i.e., the nominal replacement rate and the maximum weekly benefits) over time within a state and from a stategender interaction. To illustrate the first source of variation, Table 3 shows a selection of states with small, medium and large range in their APRR over the sample period. A potential concern is that the variation in benefit rules is correlated with economic conditions that can also affect job search decisions or employment transitions. To deal with this potential problem of “legislative endogeneity”, I follow Gruber (1997) and control for states’ unemployment rates (although the empirical results are robust to whether they are included in the analysis). Regarding the second source of variation, I also run separate models for men and women obtaining similar results. 14 I use the sample of workers in each state to calculate the APRR rather than a national sample as in Gruber (1997). I do this because the effect of the UI maximum weekly benefits on the replacement rate will depend on the average income of workers (over 50), which can differ significantly across states. 12 Next, following Rivers and Vuong (1988) and Petrin and Train (2010) in their application of CF methods to probit and multinomial probit models, respectively, I assume that , , , ,, , and , are joint normally distributed, such that: , | , , | ,, , , , , = , , , , | = , , , ,, , , | , , , , , , , = , , , , , , , , | = , , = , ,, , | , , + (7) , = , , + , (8) The first equality in equations (7) and (8) follows from the reduced-form relationships for the endogenous variables in equations (5) and (6). The second equality in equations (7) and (8) holds because , , , , are independent of the unobserved components , (7) and (8) suggest that we can control for the endogeneity in , and , , , ,, , , , . Equations , by having , and as , additional controls in the model specifications of equations (3) and (4). This leads to the following twostep estimation procedure (Wooldridge, 2015). First, estimate equations (5) and (6) and obtain the residuals , and , . Then add these residuals to the main probit and multinomial probit equations. I bootstrap this two-step procedure to obtain valid standard errors for all of the coefficients. 5. RESULTS 5.1. Probability of OJS Table 4 shows the probit coefficients (column 1 to 3) and the CF probit coefficients (column 4 to 6) for modelling the probability of OJS. In both approaches, I start with a model that does not include the interaction term significant effect of , , × , . This model allows me to test whether I am able to detect a statistically without modelling any heterogeneity in that effect. I found that, as predicted by the model, an increase in , reduces the probability of OJS on average. However, the effects are statistically indistinguishable from zero. This does not come as a surprise since most individuals in the sample report a zero or very small subjective probability of job loss (Figure 1) and for them changes in , should have no effect on their OJS decisions (Prediction 2). Conversely, the coefficient for , is positive and strongly significant both in the probit and in the CF probit models. This suggests that workers with higher expectation of job loss are more likely to be searching for other jobs, as predicted by the theory (Prediction 1). Although technically the coefficients in the probit and the CF probit models cannot be compared directly since they are standardized by different standard deviations (Wooldridge, 2007; Wooldridge, 2015), it is interesting to notice that the main effect for 13 , is substantially larger in the CF probit model whereas the coefficient for , is relatively similar in both approaches. The same conclusion arises from computing the marginal effects that I present later, which are comparable across models. This pattern implies that controlling for a polynomial in wages (and state dummies) in the probit models eliminates much of the endogenous variation in is still endogenous variation in , , , but that there , even after controlling for observed worker and employer characteristics. Next, I introduce the interaction term , × , to the probit and CF probit models. Their coefficients are negative and statistically significant in both models, while the main effects for , smaller than before and remain not statistically significant. These results imply that increases in get , decreases the probability of OJS but only for workers with non-zero expectations of job loss (i.e., , > 0) and that the effect is larger the higher the subjective probability of job loss. These findings were also predicted by the theoretical model (Predictions 2 and 3). Given the supporting empirical evidence for the predictions from the theory, I estimate next a model that imposes no effects of main effect for and × , , , , on workers with , = 0. Notice that this amounts to restricting the to be zero. In both the probit and the CF probit models, the new coefficients for , in the restricted models (columns 3 and 6) are very close to those in the unrestricted models (columns 2 and 5). Moreover, in the probit as in the CF probit, likelihood ratio tests confirm that the unrestricted and restricted models fit the data equally well. [Table 4 about here] Table 5 shows the marginal effects. For simplicity, I only show the marginal effects from the restricted models. I chose these models because the theory and the empirical evidence indicate that the effect of , should be zero when , = 0. Furthermore, as discussed above, the restricted models fits the data equally well as the unrestricted models, but provides more precise marginal effect estimates. I find that an increase of 25 percentage points in , (about one standard deviation) increases the average probability of OJS by 3.51 percentage points (or by about 29%) in the probit model, and by 11.31 percentage points (or by 93.3%) in the CF probit model. As seen in Table 4, the effect is much larger in the CF probit model, although it is still of considerable magnitude in the probit model. In fact, I calculate that the average probability of OJS if I eliminate the job insecurity mechanism (i.e. if I set , = 0 for everyone) is 9.4% in the probit model and 6.4% in the CF probit model. When compared to 14 the proportion of workers in the sample who claim to be searching for a job (about 12%), it implies that job-insecurity might be the main motivation for job search for about 23% to 47% (depending on the estimation approach) of older on-the-job seekers in the U.S. Thus, job insecurity is clearly an important factor for OJS. I also calculate the effect on the probability of OJS of an increase of 12.5 percentage points in , (about one standard deviation). I calculate the sample average effect and also the predicted average effects at different levels of , . The results are shown in panel B of Table 5. The sample average effects are relatively small, a decrease of around 0.52 to 0.62 percentage points in the probability of searching. As predicted by the theoretical model and suggested by the coefficients in Table 4, the effects are larger, albeit still moderate, when job insecurity levels are higher. For example when in , , = 0.90, the increase is predicted to decrease the probability of searching on the job by 3.8 percentage points (or by 15%) in the probit model and by 3.29 percentage points (or by 4.8 %) in the CF probit model. [Table 5 about here] 5.2. Employment transitions Now I turn to the estimation of the effects of , and , on employment transitions between waves. As discussed earlier, I use a multinomial probit approach and a CF multinomial probit approach to model the probability of three outcomes in the next wave: i) non-employment, ii) employment at a new employer, and iii) continued employment at the current employer. I define the last outcome as the base scenario for fitting the models. Table 6 shows the estimated multinomial probit coefficients. Note that the sample size is smaller than before because there is no information available on next period outcomes for the 2012 wave. The estimation results highlight again the importance of modelling the heterogeneity in the effects of term , × , , . Specifically, I find that the coefficient on the interaction in the equation for employment at a new employer (in the next wave) is strongly significant. Also, as with the probit models, the coefficients in the restricted model (that restrict the main effects of , to be equal to zero) are similar to the ones in the full model and the likelihood-ratio test confirms that both models explain the data just as well. This supports the theoretical prediction that , should only affect employment transitions when , > 0 (Prediction 4). I use the restricted model to estimate the marginal effects, which are presented in Table 7. I find that , is a predictor of both the risk of non-employment and of having a job at a new employer in the next wave, even after 15 controlling for observed characteristics. Although not explicitly considered among the testable predictions in Section 3, these finding are also supported by the theoretical model. I find that a 25 percentage points increase in , raises the probability of transitioning into non-employment by the next wave in 1.88 percentage points and of having a job at a new employer in 2.52 percentage points. In other words, per each percentage point increase in , , the actual probability of separation (adding both outcomes) increases by 0.18 percentage points. This effect, albeit statistically strong, seems small. An explanation might be that individuals tend to be pessimistic about their job loss probabilities. This was pointed out by Stephens (2004) who finds that although , has a strong predictive power of actual job separation, individuals in the HRS tend to overstate that probability. This is particularly true for individuals that report high probabilities of job loss (see Figure 2) I also find that increases in , are associated with lower probabilities of moving to a new employer (panel B in Table 7). The sample average effect is moderate, but the predicted average effects become substantial at higher levels of job insecurity, in accordance to Prediction 4 from the theoretical model. On average, a 12.5 percentage points increase in , reduces the probability of changing jobs by 0.77 percentage points (or -7.2%). In comparison, when , = 0.90, a similar increase in , is predicted to reduce the probability of having a job at a new employer by 4.9 percentage points (or -24.3%). Opposite to these results, the effects of values of , , on the on the probability of non-employment are low at all . These findings are a direct consequence of the interaction term , × , having a small coefficient on the latent risk for transitioning into non-employment and a much larger coefficient on the latent risk for having a job at a new employer (see Table 6). Prediction 5 from the theoretical model provides the insight for understanding this difference. A reduction in the probability of OJS (caused by an increase in , ) has an impact on the probability of finding a new job regardless of whether the worker is laid off or not. In comparison, a reduction in the probability of OJS only has an impact in the probability of transitioning into non-employment if the worker is actually laid off. If the worker is not laid off, there are not consequences in terms of non-employment. Thus, even though changes in , can significantly affect workers’ job search decisions and job changes, they will have a small effect on entering non-employment if individuals tend to overstate their actual risk of jobs loss. As discussed earlier, this seems to be the case for HRS respondents. This finding is robust to alternative specifications of the non-employment outcome, in particular including any reported non-employment spell between waves. 16 [Table 6 and Table 7 about here] Table 8 presents the CF multinomial probit coefficients. The main difference with the multinomial probit coefficients in Table 6 is that , has a stronger effect on the risk of being non- employed by the next wave, and a smaller, negative (opposite sign) and statistically significant effect on the probability of changing employers (see for example the model with no interactions). The marginal effects presented in Table 9 confirm these findings. A 25-percentage points increase in , leads to an increase of 8.89 percentage points (or 60.5%) in the probability of being non-employed by the next wave and to a reduction of 5.25 percentage points (or 49.3%) in the probability of working at a different employer. These are much larger effects than the marginal effects found in the multinomial probit model (Table 7) and of opposite sign in the case of the probability of changing employers. A possible explanation is that downsizing may be associated with fewer job opportunities (for example, if downsizing is associated with weaker local economies or lower demands for a specific industry or occupation). Evidence towards this explanation arises from that fact that workers at downsizing employers report a lower subjective probability of being able to find a similar job. The HRS asks workers “Suppose you were to lose your job this month. What do you think are the chances that you could find an equally good job in the same line of work within the next few months?” The sample mean answer is 47% and downsizing is associated with a reduction of 7.1 percentage points, after controlling for observed characteristics. Also, if I control for the expected job finding probability in the CF multinomial probit model, the effect of , on the probability changing employers is still negative but much smaller and statistically significant only at the 10% level. However, I prefer not to control for this variable in the main specifications since it can be endogenous. The fewer employment opportunities associated with downsizing can also explain why the effects of also smaller –at all levels of , , on the probability of moving to a new employer are - in the CF multinomial probit model than in the multinomial probit. Notice, however, that this is true when the effects are measured in percentage points, but not when measured in percentage change. An increase in , still leads to a substantial decrease in the probability of moving to a new job when measured in percentage change for individuals with high levels of job insecurity (for example when , = 0.90). Finally, the effects of , on the probability of being non- employed by the next wave continue to be not statistically significant, as it was in the multinomial probit model. [Table 8 and Table 9 about here] 17 5.3. Specification checks I test the robustness of the findings to alternative estimation approaches and model specifications. First, I model the probability of OJS using four alternative linear models: i) an ordinaryleast-squares (OLS) model where I control for wages; ii) a CF OLS model that follows the same approach describe earlier; iii) a individuals’ fixed effects (FE) model; iv) and a standard two-step leastsquares (2SLS) model. Table 10 shows the estimation results for the four models. I find that the main effects for , are positive as predicted by the theory and statistically significant in the OLS, CF OLS and FE models. I also find that the interaction terms , × , are negative as predicted by the theory, but they are not statistically significant in any model. This might be explained by the loss in efficiency and higher standard errors resulting from using linear approaches to model a binary outcome. Evidence in favor of this explanation comes from the fact that if I extend the sample to include workers up to 65 years old (an additional 3,473 observations), the interaction terms remain negative, are of similar magnitudes, and become statistically significant at the 10% confidence level in the OLS and FE models. This finding highlights the attractiveness of CF methods for controlling endogeneity when modelling non-linear outcomes. The coefficients for , , and , × , are not statistically significant in the 2SLS model (even if I expand the sample size by including individuals up to 65 years old). Note that the standard errors in the 2SLS approach increase substantially in comparison to the other models. This highlights another advantage of CF methods, already discussed earlier. CF methods can be more efficient than standard IV approaches, albeit at the cost of assuming that one has modelled correctly the conditional mean of the error term. Next, I test whether the estimation results in the CF probit method and in the CF multinomial probit method are sensitivity to the inclusion of controls. I do this because although employer downsizing can be consider an exogenous event from the workers’ perspective, the selection of workers that remain employed at downsizing employers is likely to be non-random. In Gutierrez and Michaud (2015) we found suggestive evidence of positive selection of “survivor” workers at downsizing employers. They tend to be younger, more educated, more likely to be white-collar and full-time employees, and have higher tenure at their jobs. Also, downsizing employers are more likely to provide health insurance and pension benefits, which might indicate higher-quality jobs and thus reinforce a positive selection of workers at these employers. I find similar effects of , and , on the probability of searching for another job and on employment transitions regardless of whether I control 18 for observed characteristics. Thus, to the extent that effects are similar with and without controls, omitted confounders are unlikely to significantly bias the results in the CF models. I also estimate separate models for men and women. 15 Table 11 presents the reduced-form regressions for , and , , and Table 12 presents the marginal effects from the CF restricted models. We observe that increases in , have similar strong effects on the probability of OJS for both men and women. I also find that increases in , reduce the probability of OJS in similar magnitudes for men and women, although the effects are only statistically significant for men. Interestingly, however, I find that increases in , reduce the probability of transitioning to a new job in similar magnitudes for men and women and are statistically significant for both groups. As with the case of the pooled sample, I find that , do not affect the probability of transitioning into non-employment by the next wave for either men or women. 6. CONCLUSION In this study I document that about 23% to 47% of older American on-the-job seekers search for another job because they feel insecure at their current employment. I also analyze how unemployment insurance (UI) affects the relationship between job insecurity and job search. The theoretical model presented in Section 3 predicts that an increase in the generosity of UI, measured by a higher replacement rate (or the fraction of lost wages replaced by UI benefits), reduces the value of OJS because it reduces the financial burden of unemployment. Thus, an increase in the replacement rate should reduce the probability that a worker searches for another job. The model also predicts that this effect should exist only for workers who believe that are at risk of job loss. Even more, the effect should be larger the higher is the worker's perceived risk of job loss. Using information on workers' subjective probability of job loss, job search activity and potential replacement rates (based on earnings and state of residency), I find that the empirical evidence supports these predictions. I find that an increase in the potential replacement rate discourages OJS, which in turn reduces the probability of starting a job at a new employer. These effects are only statistically significant for workers who report a non-zero subjective probability of job loss and they increase as the subjective probability of job loss gets larger. 15 I dropped observations from the state of Maine (2 observations) in the gender-specific analysis to avoid convergence problems. 19 I also find that because older American workers feel relative secure in their jobs, the sizes of the average estimated effects are moderate. For example, an increase of 12.5 percentage points in the potential replacement rate (about one standard deviation) reduces the probability of OJS by 4.3% or 5.1% (depending on the estimation approach), and reduces the probability of moving to a new job by about 7%. Thus UI have a moderate effect on the average rate at which older workers change jobs. However, these moderate effects mask important heterogeneities. On one hand, as discussed above, UI does not affect the search behavior of workers who do not believe to be at risk of job loss. On the other hand, the effects can be substantial for workers with higher levels of job insecurity. Depending on the estimation approach, a similar increase in the potential replacement rate is predicted to reduce the probability of OJS by 4.8% or 15.0% for workers with a subjective probability of job loss of 90%; and their probability of changing employers is predicted to decrease by 24.3% or 32.8%. It is also worth noticing that I do not find that changes in UI potential replacement rates affect the probability of older workers transitioning into non-employment, even for those who report high levels of job insecurity. This finding is robust to whether employment is measured in the next wave or by looking at any non-employment spells between waves. A plausible explanation is that older American workers tend to overestimate their actual job loss probability. Therefore, the effects of UI potential replacement rates on workers’ decision to search on-the-job matter more for the likelihood of changing employers than for becoming unemployed. Still, it is plausible that the effects of UI on transitioning into unemployment might be larger for younger workers who are less attached to their employers. The evidence presented here warrants more study on the interaction between job insecurity, job search and UI benefits, particularly for young and prime-age workers. ACKNOWLEDGMENTS This paper has been funded in part with federal funds from the U.S. Department of Labor under contract number DOLJ111A21738. It has also been supported by a grant from the National Poverty Center at the University of Michigan, which is supported by award #1 U01 AE000002-03 from the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation. The contents of this publication do not necessarily reflect the views or policies of the Department of Labor or of any agency of the Federal Government, nor does mention of trade names, commercial products, or organizations imply endorsement of same by the U.S. Government. 20 I thank Jeffrey Smith, Charlie Brown, Melvin Stephens, Brian McCall and Daniel Hamermesh for comments on earlier versions of this paper. I also thank seminar participants at the University of Michigan for helpful suggestions. Special thanks to Michael Nolte, Janet Keller and all the staff at the Health and Retirement Survey at the Institute for Social Research for their help and assistance through this project. All errors are my own. REFERENCES Addison, J.T., Blackburn, M. Advance Notice and Job Search: More on the Value of an Early Start. Industrial Relations. 1995;34;242-262. Anderson, P.M., Meyer, B.D. Unemployment Insurance in the United States: Layoff Incentives and Cross Subsidies. Journal of Labor Economics. 1993;11;S70-S95. Burgess, P.L., Low, S.A. Preunemployment Job Search and Advance Job Loss Notice. Journal of Labor Economics. 1992;10;258-287. Burgess, P.L., Low, S.A. How do Unemployment Insurance and Recall Expectations Affect On-The-Job Search among workers who Receive Advance Notice of Layoff? Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 1998;51;241-252. Card, D., Levine, P.B. Unemployment Insurance Taxes and the Cyclical and Seasonal Properties of Unemployment. Journal of Public Economics. 1994;53;1-29. Chan, S., Stevens, A.H. Employment and Retirement Following a Late-Career Job Loss. American Economic Review. 1999;89;211-216. Chan, S., Stevens, A.H. Job Loss and Employment Patterns of Older Workers. Journal of Labor Economics. 2001;19;484-521. Christofides, L.N., McKenna, C.J. Unemployment Insurance and moral hazard in employment. Economics Letters. 1995;49;205-210. Christofides, L.N., McKenna, C.J. Unemployment Insurance and Job Duration in Canada. Journal of Labor Economics. 1996;14;286-312. Couch, K.A., Placzek, D.W. Earning Losses of Displaced Workers Revisited. American Economic Review. 2010;100;572-589. Currie, J., Gruber, J. Health Insurance Eligibility, Utilization of Medical Care, and Child Health. The Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1996a. Currie, J., Gruber, J. Saving Babies: The Efficacy and Cost of Recent Changes in the Medicaid Eligibility of Pregnant Women. Journal of Political Economy. 1996b;1263-1296. Fallick, B.C. A Review of the Recent Empirical Literature on Displaced Workers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 1996;50;5-16. Fallick, B.C., Fleischman, C.A. The Importance of Employer-to-Employer Flows in the U.S. Labor Market. 2001. Feldstein, M. Temporary Layoffs in the Theory of Unemployment. Journal of Political Economy. 1976;84;937958. Feldstein, M. The Effect of Unemployment Insurance on Temporary Layoff Unemployment. American Economic Review. 1978;68;834-846. 21 Fitzenberger, B., Wilke, R.A. Unemployment Durations in West Germany Before and After the Reform of the Unemployment Compensation System during the 1980s. German Economic Review. 2009;11;336-366. Fujita, S. Reality of on-the-Job Search. Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. 2011. Green, D.A., Riddell, W.C. Qualifying for Unemployment Insurance: An Empirical Analysis. Economic Journal. 1997;107;67-84. Green, D.A., Sargent, T.C. Unemployment Insurance and Job Durations: Seasonal and Non-Seasonal Jobs. Canadian Journal of Economics. 1998;31;247-278. Gruber, J. The Consumption Smoothing Benefits of Unemployment Insurance. American Economic Review. 1997;87;192-205. Gutierrez, I.A., Michaud, P.-C. 2015. Employer Downsizing and Older Workers' Health. Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA), Discussion Paper 9140. 2015. Haan, P., Prowse, V. The Design of Unemployment Transfers: Evidence from a Dynamic Structural Life-Cycle Model. IZA Discussion Paper Series. 2010. Jacobson, L.S., LaLonde, R.J., Sullivan, D.G. Earning Losses of Displaced Workers. The American Economic Review. 1993;83;685-709. Jolivet, G., Postel-Vinay, F., Robin, J.-M. The Empirical Content of the Job Search Model: Labor Mobility and Wage Distributions in Europe and the US. European Economic Review. 2006;50;877-907. Jurajda, S. Estimating the effect of unemployment insurance compensation on the labor market histories of displaced workers. Journal of Econometrics. 2002;108;227-252. Jurajda, S. Unemployment Insurance and the Timing of Layoffs and Recalls. Labour. 2003;17;383-389. Kleinjans, K.J., van Soest, A. Nonresponse and Focal Point Answers to Subjective Probability Questions. IZA Discussion Paper No. 5272. 2010. Kletzer, L.G. Job Displacement. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 1998;12;115-136. Krueger, A.B., Meyer, B.D., 2002. The Labor Supply Effects of Social Insurance, in: Auerbach, A., Feldstein, M. (Eds.), Handbook of Public Economics. North-Holland, pp. 2327-2392. Lalive, R., van Ours, J.C., Zweimüller, J. Equilibrium unemployment and the duration of unemployment benefits. Journal of Population Economics. 2011;24;1385-1409. Lengermann, P.A., Vilhuber, L. Abandoning the sinking ship: The composition of worker flows prior to displacement. Center for Economic Studies, US Census Bureau. 2002. Light, A., Omori, Y. Unemployment Insurance and Job Quits. Journal of Labor Economics. 2004;22;159-188. Manski, C.F., Molinari, F. Rounding Probabilistic Expectations in Surveys. Journal of Business \& Economics Statistics. 2010;28;219-231. McCall, B.P. The Impact of Unemployment Insurance Benefit Levels on Recipiency. Journal of Business \& Economic Statistics. 1995;13;189-198. Meyer, B.D. Lessons from the U.S. Unemployment Insurance Experiments. Journal of Economic Literature. 1995;33;91-131. Mortensen, D.T. Unemployment Insurance and Job Search Decisions. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. 1977;30;505-517. Petrin, A., Train, K. A Control Function Approach to Endogeneity in Consumer Choice Models. Journal of Marketing Research. 2010;47;3-13. 22 Rebollo-Sanz, Y. Unemployment insurance and job turnover in Spain. Labour Economics. 2012;19;403-426. Rivers, D., Vuong, Q.H. Limited information estimators and exogeneity tests for simultaneous probit models. Journal of Econometrics. 1988;39;347-366. Rosal, O.D. La Busqueda De Empleo De Los Ocupados. Intensidad Y Motivos. Estudios de Economia Aplicada. 2003;21;151-174. Schwerdt, G. Labor turnover before plant closure: Leaving the sinking ship vs. Captain throwing ballast overboard. Labour Economics. 2011;18;93-101. Stephens, M.J. Job Loss Expectations, Realizations, and Household Consumption Behavior. Review of Economics and Statistics. 2004;86;253-269. Topel, R.H. On Layoffs and Unemployment Insurance. American Economic Review. 1983;73;541-559. Topel, R.H. Experience Rating of Unemployment Insurance and the Incidence of Unemployment. Journal of Law and Economics. 1984;27;61-90. Tudela, C.C., Smith, E. Search Capital. CESifo Working Papers. 2012. Winter-Ebmer, R. Benefit duration and unemployment entry: A quasi-experiment in Austria. European Economic Review. 2003;47;25-273. Wooldridge, J. 2007. What’s New in Econometrics? Lecture 6: Control Functions and Related Methods. NBER Summer Institute. 2007. Wooldridge, J.M. Control Function Methods in Applied Econometrics. Journal of Human Resources. 2015;50;420445. 23 50% 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% 0% 1% - 5% 6% - 10% 11% - 15% 16% - 20% 21% - 25% 26% - 30% 31% - 35% 36% - 40% 41% - 45% 46% - 50% 51% - 55% 56% - 60% 61% - 65% 66% - 70% 71% - 75% 76% - 80% 81% - 85% 86% - 90% 91% - 95% 96% - 100% % of observations Figure 1: Distribution of the Subjective Probability of Job Loss Reported Probability of Job Loss Data Source: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 91% - 100% 81% - 90% 71% - 80% 61% - 70% 51% - 60% 41% - 50% 31% - 40% 21% - 30% 11%-20% 0% 0% - 10% Probability leaving employer Figure 2: Subjective Probability of Job Loss and Average Probability of Job Separation Subjective Probability of Job Loss Non-Downsizing Downsizing 24 45° line Table 1: Sample means of outcomes and selected covariates Mean Standard Deviation 0.12 0.15 0.75 0.11 0.33 0.35 0.43 0.31 0.18 0.42 0.25 0.13 0.40 56.38 0.57 0.06 3.33 0.49 Outcomes: On-the-Job Search (1=yes; 0=no) Employment transition: to non-employment Employment transition: same employer Employment transition: Different employer Covariates: Subjective probability of job loss (from 0 to 1) Potential replacement rate (from 0 to 1) State average potential replacement rate (from 0 to 1) Age (in years) Female Data source: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Note: Other controls include race and ethnicity, weekly earnings, education, occupation, part-time employment status, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Table 2: Reduced form regressions for endogenous variables Downsizing ( , ) State average potential replacement rate (APRR or , ) # Observations Subjective probability of job loss ( ,) Potential replacement rate ( , ) 0.074*** (0.004) -0.008*** (0.001) 0.054 (0.054) 23,906 0.792*** (0.060) 23,906 Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partlyretired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 25 Table 3: Variation in States Average Potential Replacement Rates All State Min ND 33.9% AR Median Males Max Min 37.3% 38.9% 33.9% 40.0% 42.2% 46.9% PA 41.8% 43.9% NC 39.9% 42.5% Median Females Max Min Median Max 34.3% 37.3% 37.3% 38.0% 38.9% 40.0% 41.3% 42.3% 42.1% 46.2% 46.9% 49.1% 41.8% 43.3% 44.2% 43.6% 48.5% 49.1% 47.7% 39.9% 41.9% 42.6% 42.4% 47.0% 47.7% TX 38.2% 40.3% 46.1% 38.2% 39.0% 40.3% 40.3% 44.9% 46.1% NJ 42.2% 45.5% 53.0% 42.2% 44.7% 45.9% 45.2% 51.8% 53.0% CO 40.2% 44.5% 51.5% 40.2% 43.3% 44.6% 44.1% 49.8% 51.5% FL 32.2% 37.6% 43.5% 32.2% 36.0% 38.1% 32.2% 41.8% 43.5% TN 31.9% 36.9% 43.6% 31.9% 35.4% 37.1% 31.9% 42.4% 43.6% KS 37.6% 40.4% 50.0% 37.6% 39.2% 40.7% 40.0% 48.7% 50.0% VA 28.3% 35.5% 44.6% 28.3% 32.9% 37.0% 33.0% 40.5% 44.6% CA 27.6% 37.6% 44.6% 27.6% 36.0% 39.7% 32.2% 38.3% 44.6% KY 40.1% 46.8% 57.5% 40.1% 45.1% 47.2% 43.6% 56.2% 57.5% NH 29.2% 38.2% 46.8% 29.2% 37.0% 39.1% 35.9% 44.9% 46.8% MI 16.1% 37.7% 47.3% 16.1% 36.0% 38.2% 16.1% 45.5% 47.3% Note: Author calculations using the CPS March Supplement (2001, 2003 and 2005) Table 4: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on On-the-Job Search (Probit Coefficients) Probit Subjective prob. of job loss ( , ) Potential rep. rate ( ,) Probit CF Main effects only Main and interactio n effects 0.756*** (0.042) -0.336 (0.286) 1.237*** (0.171) -0.113 (0.309) 1.258*** (0.156) -1.078*** (0.353) -1.127*** (0.327) Interaction term ( , × ,) Restricte d Model Main effects only Main and interactio n effects 2.467*** (0.411) -0.308 (0.760) 2.863*** (0.469) -0.103 (0.764) 2.877*** (0.448) -0.931*** (0.353) -0.942*** (0.338) Restricte d Model , -1.737*** (0.416) -1.717*** (0.414) -1.726*** (0.394) , 1.674** (0.733) 23,906 1.652** (0.714) 23,906 1.551*** (0.172) 23,906 # Observations 23,906 23,906 23,906 Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. Standard errors for the Probit CF approach were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level; *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 26 Table 5: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on On-the-Job Search (Marginal Effects- Restricted Model) Probit CF Probit Percentage Percentage points change Percentage Percentage points change A. Effect of 25 percentage points increase in Average effect 3.51*** 29.0% (0.18) 93.3% (1.75) B. Effect of 12.5 percentage points increase in Average effect , 11.31*** , -0.62*** (0.18) -5.1% -0.52*** (0.18) -4.3% If , = 0.25 -0.68*** (0.20) -5.4% -0.67*** (0.24) -4.0% If , = 0.50 -9.8% , = 0.75 If , = 0.90 -1.94*** (0.71) -3.07*** (1.07) -3.29*** (1.17) -5.7% If -1.66*** (0.49) -2.92*** (0.87) -3.80*** (1.13) -13.3% -15.0% -5.5% -4.8% Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. Standard errors for the Probit CF approach were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level; *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 27 Table 6: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on Employment Transitions (Multinomial Probit Coefficients) Main effects only Subjective prob. of job loss ( , ) Potential rep. rate ( , ) Interaction term ( , × , # Observations Main and interaction effects Restricted Model Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer 0.636*** 0.896*** 0.949*** 1.991*** 1.052*** 1.957*** (0.065) (0.067) (0.241) (0.360) (0.238) (0.340) -0.747* (0.430) -0.261 (0.368) -0.635 (0.435) 0.216 (0.399) -0.709 -2.483*** -0.941* -2.405*** (0.505) (0.738) (0.500) (0.691) 18,910 18,910 18,910 18,910 ) 18,910 18,910 Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 28 Table 7: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on Employment Transitions (Marginal Effects – Multinomial Probit Restricted Model) Outcome: Non-employment Percentage Percentage points change Outcome: Different Employer Percentage Percentage points change A. Effect of 25 percentage points increase in , 12.8% Average effect 1.88*** 2.52*** (0.25) 23.7% (0.20) B. Effect of 12.5 percentage points increase in , -0.9% Average effect -0.13 -0.77*** (0.20) (0.25) -1.5% If , = 0.25 -0.23 -0.95*** (0.26) (0.30) -2.4% If , = 0.50 -0.41 -2.23*** (0.57) (0.73) -2.5% If , = 0.75 -0.48 -3.82*** (0.93) (1.28) -2.3% If , = 0.90 -0.46 -4.90*** (1.17) (1.67) -7.2% -8.4% -15.6% -21.4% -24.3% Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. Standard errors for the Probit CF approach were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level; *** denotes pvalue <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 29 Table 8: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on Employment Transitions (CF Multinomial Probit Coefficients) Main effects only Subjective prob. of job loss ( , ) Potential rep. rate ( , ) Interaction term ( , × , Main and interaction effects Restricted Model Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer Outcome: Nonemployment Outcome: Different Employer 2.113*** -0.920* 2.397*** 0.157 2.235*** -0.054 (0.534) 0.908 (1.788) (0.516) 0.782 (1.183) (0.596) 1.029 (1.739) (0.632) 1.357 (1.167) (0.516) (0.637) -0.670 (0.544) -2.561*** (0.704) -0.587 (0.514) -2.450*** (0.705) ) , -1.494*** (0.532) 1.856*** (0.541) -1.481*** (0.533) 1.909*** (0.574) -1.356*** (0.453) 2.071*** (0.559) , -0.890 (1.833) 18,910 0.201 (1.204) 18,910 -0.918 (1.766) 18,910 0.086 (1.219) 18,910 0.098 (0.190) 18,910 1.424*** (0.263) 18,910 # Observations Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level. *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 30 Table 9: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on Employment Transitions (Marginal Effects – CF Multinomial Probit Restricted Model) Outcome: Non-employment Percentage Percentage points change Outcome: Different Employer Percentage Percentage points change A. Effect of 25 percentage points increase in , 60.5% Average effect 8.89*** -5.25*** (1.93) (1.77) B. Effect of 12.5 percentage points increase in , 0.1% Average effect 0.02 -0.82*** If , = 0.25 If , = 0.50 If , = 0.75 If , = 0.90 -49.3% (0.20) -0.12 (0.28) -0.46 (0.72) -0.98 (1.24) -1.31 (1.52) -0.6% -1.5% -2.2% -2.5% (0.18) -0.85*** (0.19) -1.16*** (0.31) -1.07*** (0.37) -0.91** (0.38) -7.7% -8.0% -17.0% -26.7% -32.8% Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. Standard errors for the Probit CF approach were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level; *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 31 Table 10: Effect of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on OJS (Linear Models) Subjective prob. of job loss ( , ) Potential rep. rate ( , ) Interaction term ( , × ,) OLS CF OLS FE 2SLS 0.215*** (0.040) 0.014 (0.056) 0.525*** (0.097) -0.011 (0.137) 0.166*** (0.049) 0.029 (0.080) 0.604 (0.480) 0.023 (0.234) -0.104 (0.085) -0.091 (0.079) -0.158 (0.109) -0.280 (1.121) , -0.321*** (0.084) , 0.279** (0.134) # Observations 23,906 23,906 23,906 23,906 Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, gender, education, occupation, part-time employment, partlyretired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. Standard errors for the CF approach were calculated from 500 bootstrap replications clustered at the state level; *** denotes pvalue <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. Table 11: Reduced form regressions for endogenous variables, by gender Males Females Subjective Potential probability replacement of job loss rate ( , ) ( ,) Subjective Potential probability replacement of job loss rate ( , ) ( ,) 0.061*** -0.011*** 0.082*** -0.007*** State average potential replacement rate (APRR or , ) (0.006) -0.030 (0.002) 1.066*** (0.006) 0.102** (0.002) 0.869*** (0.089) (0.055) (0.045) (0.037) # Observations 10,225 10,225 13,640 13,640 Downsizing ( , ) Data: HRS, 1996-2006 and 2010-2012. Notes: Controls include age, education, occupation, part-time employment, partly-retired employment, industry, whether employer provides health insurance, levels of stress at job, requirements of lifting heavy loads at work, and state and year dummies. Standard errors (in parentheses) were clustered at the state level. *** denotes p-value <0.01, ** denotes p-value <0.05, * denotes p-value<0.1. 32 Table 12: Effects by Gender of Job Insecurity and Potential Replacement Rate on OJS and Employment Transitions (Marginal Effects – Restricted Model) Probability of OJS Pct. points Pct. change Employment Transitions Outcome: Outcome: Different Non-employment Employer Pct. Pct. Pct. Pct. points change points change I. Males Avg. effect I.A. Effect of 25 percentage points increase in 61% 13.24*** 104.3% 9.01** (2.44) Avg. effect , -6.86** (3.39) -59.4% -0.78*** (0.27) -6.7% (3.59) I.B. Effect of 12.5 percentage points increase in 0.6% -0.57** -4.5% 0.09 (0.23) , (0.27) If , = 0.50 -2.17** (0.87) -5.1% -0.20 (1.02) -0.6% -0.99** (0.43) -14.5% If , = 0.90 -2.97** (1.37) -3.7% -0.75 (2.17) -1.3% -0.72 (0.47) -30.8% -3.98** -39.9% II. Females Avg. effect II.A. Effect of 25 percentage points increase in 9.51*** 64.6% 10.53*** 90.2% (2.45) Avg. effect If , = 0.50 If , = 0.90 (2.26) (2.02) II.B. Effect of 12.5 percentage points increase in -0.3% -0.43 -3.7% -0.04 (0.38) -1.57 (1.40) -2.87 (2.51) , (0.30) -0.63 (1.10) -1.62 (2.24) -4.9% -4.5% 33 -2.0% -3.0% , -0.88*** (0.26) -1.33*** (0.47) -1.13* (0.62) -8.8% -20.0% -38.4% A. APPENDIX: THEORETICAL MODEL AND PREDICTIONS Model set up The following model is an adaptation of the model initially proposed by Light and Omori (2004). The model consists of two periods. In the first period, the worker is employed and earns . The maximization problem of the worker is to decide whether to search on-the-job (OJS) or not. If the worker decides to search, then has to pay a fixed cost of , which is distributed among workers with probability function ( ). In each period, the flow utility is given by logarithm of the available earnings and the fixed cost of job search (if the worker searches on the job). If a worker searches, the probability of receiving an offer in the second period equals . Offers come from a known distribution ( ) and at most one offer can be received. The worker faces a probability of layoff in period 2 equal to ; and if laid off, the worker can collect UI benefits equal to , where is the current wage of the worker in period 1 and is the effective replacement rate. If the worker decides not to search for a job, there are two possible scenarios for the second period: 1) with probability (1 and 2) with probability ) does not lose the job and continuous receiving earnings equal to ; . Four different loses the job and takes unemployment benefits equal to scenarios can occur in the second period if the worker decides to search for a job: 1) with probability (1 )(1 ) does not lose the job and does not receive an offer. In this scenario the worker continues receiving earnings equal to ; 2) with probability (1 ) the worker loses the job and does not ; 3) with receive an offer. In this scenario, the worker takes unemployment benefits equal to probability (1 ), the worker does not lose the job and receives an offer. In this scenario the worker ; and 4) with probability takes the new job as long as the offered wage is greater than , the worker loses the job and receives an offer. In this scenario, the worker takes the offer as long as the offered . Thus, the maximization problem for the worker in period 1 consists of wage is greater than deciding whether to search on the job or not. More formally, the maximization problem of the worker can be formulated as described below (where { ; {log( )= [(1 (1 is the worker’s discount factor) : ) + [(1 )(1 ) log( {log( ) {log( ) log( )+ ) + (1 ) log( log( ) , log( )} ( ) ) , log( )} ( ) 34 } )]; log( ) + )) + + (A.1) The optimal decision for the worker is to search in period 1 if the fixed search cost reservation level is below a , which is a function of the worker’s wage, job loss expectations and the is given by equation (A.2) below, where replacement rate. An expression for [log( ) ( )= )] ( ) log( + (1 [log( ) ) Hence, the probability that a worker engages in OJS is given by =( , log( , , , , ): )] ( ) (A.2) ( ) , or the probability that the idiosyncratic fixed cost of search is below the maximum cost the worker is willing to accept to search on the job. Model predictions The following predictions hold in the model: Prediction 1: Other things equal, workers with greater probability of job loss are more likely to search on the job. Proof. Equation (A.3) below shows that the derivative of with respect to the expected probability of job loss ( ) is unambiguously positive: ( ) = × [log( ) log( × [log( ) )] ( ) log( Given that the probability of performing OJS is given by density function )] ( ) >0 (A.3) ( ) , and that the probability ( ) is always positive, then equation (A.4) below completes the proof of Prediction 1: ( ) ( ) ( ) × = >0 (A.4) Prediction 2: An increase in the replacement rate leads to a decrease in the probability of OJS but only for workers with non-zero probability of layoff (i.e. > 0). Proof. Equations (A.5) and (A.6) below show the derivative of and of the probability of OJS with respect to : ( ) [1 = ( ) = ( × )] ( ) ( ) × 35 0 (A.5) 0 (A.6) The derivatives are zero if = 0. Thus, changes in the replacement rate have no effect on the probability of OJS if the worker is not at risk of job loss. If is positive, then an increase in the replacement rate will decrease the maximum search cost an employed worker is willing to accept, everything else equal, and thus will reduce the probability that the worker engages in OJS. Prediction 3: The higher the probability of layoff (p), the larger is the negative effect that the replacement rate has on the probability of OJS (under plausible conditions on ). Proof. Equation (A.7) below shows the cross-derivative of ( ) with respect of equation (A.8) shows the cross-derivative of the probability of OJS with respect to ( ) [1 = ( ) = ( × ( ) × and : )] < 0 ( ) and , whereas (A.7) ( ) + ( ) × ( ) × ( ) (A.8) Equation (A.7) shows that the effect of an increase in the replacement rate ( ) on reducing the maximum search cost an individual is willing to accept gets larger (more negative) at higher levels of job loss expectations ( ). However, the effect of with higher levels of on the probability of OJS can be larger or smaller . In other words, the sign of equation (A.8) is ambiguous. However, under condition (A.9) below, the sign of ( ) would be unambiguously negative. ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) > ( ) × ( ) (A.9) Condition (A.9) is a smoothness condition requiring that if the rate of change in the probability density function () is negative, then it should be bounded by the right-hand side term of condition (A.9). In other words, condition (A.9) requires that () varies smoothly around ( ). Prediction 4: The replacement rate does not affect the probabilities of employment transitions if the worker is not at risk of job loss (i.e. = 0 ). For workers with a non-zero risk of job loss, an increase in the replacement rate increases the likelihood of falling into non-employment and decreases the likelihood of moving to a new job. These effects are stronger the larger is the risk of job loss. Proof. Equations (A.10) and (A.11) state the probabilities that workers experience a job-to-job (JTJ) transition or a job-to-non-employment (JTN) transition in period 2, respectively: 36 ( ( ) { [1 | )= ( | )= ( × ( ) [1 1 )] + (1 ( × )[1 ( )]} (A.10) )] (A.11) After taking the derivatives of (A.10) and (A.11) with respect to the replacement rate , the ( ) is the probability density function of the wage offer following equations are obtained, where distribution ( ): ( | ) ( ) = ( | ) ( | ) [1 ( × )[1 )] ( ( × ( ) = 0, and negative if is zero if ( × ( ) )]} ) (A.12) ) (A.13) ( > 0. Similarly, | ) is zero if = 0, and > 0. Now, I take the cross-derivatives of equations (A.12) and (A.13) with respect to : positive if | ) ( ) = { [1 | ) ( ) = ( ) ) [1 ( × )] + (1 ( × ( × ( ) ( )] + (1 ( × ( ) = Thus, ( { [1 ( ) + ( × )[1 ( ( × )] ( ) ( ) )]} + { ( ) ) ( × ( × )} (A.14) ( ) ) [1 ) ( × )] (A.15) Under the smoothness condition in equation (A.9), and as long as derivatives in equations (A.14) and (A.15) as ( | ) < 0 and ( | ) > 0, we can sign the cross- > 0. Prediction 5: Given that the worker has a positive probability of job loss ( > 0), the effect of an increase in the replacement rate is larger (in absolute value) on JTJ transitions than on JTN transitions. Proof. We can re-write the absolute value of (A.12) as: ( | ) ( ) = { [1 )] + (1 ( × )[1 ( )]} + ( ) ( × ) (A.16) Subtracting (A.13) from (A.16) we have: ( | ) ( | ) = ( ) (1 37 )[1 ( )] 0 (A.17) Again, equation (A.17) equals zero when is zero and is positive when 38 is positive.