Consumer Inattention & Bill-Shock Regulation Michael D. Grubb October 2014 Boston College

advertisement

Consumer Inattention & Bill-Shock Regulation

Michael D. Grubb

Boston College

October 2014

Motivation

Firms frequently offer consumers contracts with “free” units and steep penalties for excessive usage

Cell phone service: Overages over 20% of US revenues 2003

Checking accounts: 2013 overdraft fees: US

$

32 Bn & UK

£

2.9 Bn,

Checking accounts: including

£

0.4 Bn paid item charges.

Credit cards

Often penalties are a surprise, causing bill shock.

Motivation

Firms frequently offer consumers contracts with “free” units and steep penalties for excessive usage

Cell phone service: Overages over 20% of US revenues 2003

Checking accounts: 2013 overdraft fees: US

$

32 Bn & UK

£

2.9 Bn,

Checking accounts: including

£

0.4 Bn paid item charges.

Credit cards

Often penalties are a surprise, causing bill shock.

Research Question

Firms often choose not to disclose whether or not a penalty fee is applicable at the point of sale.

Cell phone screen could flash “overage rate applies”

Debit card terminal could ask “overdraft applies: continue? yes/no”

Question : Would it be a good idea to require such disclosure?

Recent Regulatory Attention

Far too many Americans know what it’s like to open up their cell-phone bill and be shocked by hundreds or even thousands of dollars in unexpected fees and charges. But we can put an end to that with a simple step: an alert warning consumers that they’re about to hit their limit before fees and charges add up.

President Barack Obama, October 17 th

, 2011.

Recent Regulatory Attention

US cellphones : Since 2013, agreement with FCC requires US carriers to alert consumers when they approach and exceed usage allowances

(voice, text, data)

US Overdraft fees : Effective July 1st, 2010 the Fed requires opt-in for overdraft protection on ATM and debit card transactions.

The CFPB wants to do more (proposed “penalty fee box”)

UK Overdraft fees : In 2011 HMT Consumer Credit and Personal

Insolvency Review, major banks agreed to provide optional text/e-mail low balance alerts.

Today’s Talk

Theory

“Consumer Inattention and Bill-Shock Regulation”,

Review of Economic Studies 2014

“Overconfident Consumers in the Marketplace”

Draft in preparation for Journal of Economic Perspectives .

Applications

“Cellular Service Demand: Biased Beliefs, Learning, and Bill Shock”, with Matthew Osborne American Economic Review forthcoming.

Work in progress with Matthew Osborne: low balance alerts for checking accounts.

Theory Model (Grubb 2014)

1

Time t = 0: Hotelling duopolists offer contracts & risk neutral consumers choose:

P = M + p

1 q

1

+ p

2 q

2

+ ˆ · q

1 q

2

2

Time t ∈ { 1 , 2 } : Consumer makes a buy-or-not-buy decision, choosing quantity q t

∈ { 0 , 1 } given private value v t

∼ F ( v ).

3

ˆ > 0 → penalty fee

ˆ < 0 → loyalty discount

Rational Inattention

Between periods 1 & 2, consumer may pay cost k to look up past usage q

1

(to be attentive).

If choose to be inattentive: cannot recall q

1 at time 2 cannot condition time 2 purchase on past usage q

1 can only respond to E [ MP ]

Sophisticated: anticipates future inattention.

Naive: Believes k = 0, so fails to anticipate own inattention.

Rational Inattention

Between periods 1 & 2, consumer may pay cost k to look up past usage q

1

(to be attentive).

If choose to be inattentive: cannot recall q

1 at time 2 cannot condition time 2 purchase on past usage q

1 can only respond to E [ MP ]

Sophisticated: anticipates future inattention.

Naive: Believes k = 0, so fails to anticipate own inattention.

Bill-Shock Regulation(BSR)

Bill-Shock Regulation (BSR):

Firms must alert consumers at time 2 if ˆ applies.

Equivalence Result for Sophisticates

Proposition

If consumers are sophisticated then inattention and BSR do not affect welfare, profits, consumer surplus, allocations, or market shares.

Does not explain why firms charge surprise penalty fees or lobby against bill-shock regulation.

Equivalence Result for Sophisticates

Proposition

If consumers are sophisticated then inattention and BSR do not affect welfare, profits, consumer surplus, allocations, or market shares.

Does not explain why firms charge surprise penalty fees or lobby against bill-shock regulation.

Equilibrium with Naive Consumers

Naive Result

Two possible outcomes: a

1

Firms charge a surprise penalty fee ( ˆ > 0 ) & consumers underestimate chance of paying it

2 Firms offer a surprise loyalty discount ( ˆ < 0 ) & consumers overestimate chance of collecting it

In either case, consumers are inattentive & overvalue contracts by k.

a

Equally profitable but # 1 more robust to arbitrage by attentive consumers.

Welfare consequences in Hotelling duopoly?

None, because ρ = 1 &

D

= 0.

Welfare Consequences of Naive Inattention

Supply   and   Demand   for   Contracts   Delivering n

  Un

Perceived   price   decrease

True   price   increase

1 k =   contract   overvaluation

Bill ‐ Shock   Regulation   will   lower   contract   price   by: ρ   ) k

Q

1

Consequences depend on pass-through rate & elasticity

BSR: price down (1 − ρ ) k ; perceived price up ρ k

BSR Benefits:

D

= 0

D

< 0

ρ = 1 no one marginal cons.

ρ = 0 infra-marginal cons.

Overdraft fees: Jamie Dimon, CEO of JPMorgan Chase says ρ = 1:

If you’re a restaurant and you can’t charge for the soda, you’re going to charge more for the burger. Over time, it will all be repriced into the business.

Credit cards: Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, Mahoney, & Stroebel

(forthcoming) argue ρ ≈ 0 given Ausubel (1999) and their estimate that 2009 CARD act fee reductions save consumers

$

13Bn/yr.

Cellphone service : Genakos & Valletti (2011) find ρ < 1 but close to 1 in EU. Grubb & Osborne (forthcoming) est.

ρ ≈ 1 in US.

Consequences depend on pass-through rate & elasticity

BSR: price down (1 − ρ ) k ; perceived price up ρ k

BSR Benefits:

D

= 0

D

< 0

ρ = 1 no one marginal cons.

ρ = 0 infra-marginal cons.

Overdraft fees: Jamie Dimon, CEO of JPMorgan Chase says ρ = 1:

If you’re a restaurant and you can’t charge for the soda, you’re going to charge more for the burger. Over time, it will all be repriced into the business.

Credit cards: Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, Mahoney, & Stroebel

(forthcoming) argue ρ ≈ 0 given Ausubel (1999) and their estimate that 2009 CARD act fee reductions save consumers

$

13Bn/yr.

Cellphone service : Genakos & Valletti (2011) find ρ < 1 but close to 1 in EU. Grubb & Osborne (forthcoming) est.

ρ ≈ 1 in US.

Consequences depend on pass-through rate & elasticity

BSR: price down (1 − ρ ) k ; perceived price up ρ k

BSR Benefits:

D

= 0

D

< 0

ρ = 1 no one marginal cons.

ρ = 0 infra-marginal cons.

Overdraft fees: Jamie Dimon, CEO of JPMorgan Chase says ρ = 1:

If you’re a restaurant and you can’t charge for the soda, you’re going to charge more for the burger. Over time, it will all be repriced into the business.

Credit cards: Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, Mahoney, & Stroebel

(forthcoming) argue ρ ≈ 0 given Ausubel (1999) and their estimate that 2009 CARD act fee reductions save consumers

$

13Bn/yr.

Cellphone service : Genakos & Valletti (2011) find ρ < 1 but close to 1 in EU. Grubb & Osborne (forthcoming) est.

ρ ≈ 1 in US.

Consequences depend on pass-through rate & elasticity

BSR: price down (1 − ρ ) k ; perceived price up ρ k

BSR Benefits:

D

= 0

D

< 0

ρ = 1 no one marginal cons.

ρ = 0 infra-marginal cons.

Overdraft fees: Jamie Dimon, CEO of JPMorgan Chase says ρ = 1:

If you’re a restaurant and you can’t charge for the soda, you’re going to charge more for the burger. Over time, it will all be repriced into the business.

Credit cards: Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, Mahoney, & Stroebel

(forthcoming) argue ρ ≈ 0 given Ausubel (1999) and their estimate that 2009 CARD act fee reductions save consumers

$

13Bn/yr.

Cellphone service : Genakos & Valletti (2011) find ρ < 1 but close to 1 in EU. Grubb & Osborne (forthcoming) est.

ρ ≈ 1 in US.

Mix of Attentive & Naively Inattentive

Proposition

Bill-shock regulation ends cross-subsidies, helping the naive at the expense of the attentive.

Price Discrimination Between Sophisticates

Suppose that

All consumers are sophisticated

Ex ante there are types with low ( v t

Firms want to price discriminate

∼ F

L

) and high ( v t

∼ F

H

) demand

Surprise penalty fees are a tool for price discrimination they can relax incentive constraints without distorting allocations

Proposition

In fairly competitive markets: BSR strictly decreases welfare.

Firms and low types are losers but high types are winners.

Intuition: Firms discriminate less & substitute to quantity distortions lower markup on contract H lower allocation & raise markup on contract L

Price Discrimination Between Sophisticates

Suppose that

All consumers are sophisticated

Ex ante there are types with low ( v t

Firms want to price discriminate

∼ F

L

) and high ( v t

∼ F

H

) demand

Surprise penalty fees are a tool for price discrimination they can relax incentive constraints without distorting allocations

Proposition

In fairly competitive markets: BSR strictly decreases welfare.

Firms and low types are losers but high types are winners.

Intuition: Firms discriminate less & substitute to quantity distortions lower markup on contract H lower allocation & raise markup on contract L

Price Discrimination Between Sophisticates

Suppose that

All consumers are sophisticated

Ex ante there are types with low ( v t

Firms want to price discriminate

∼ F

L

) and high ( v t

∼ F

H

) demand

Surprise penalty fees are a tool for price discrimination they can relax incentive constraints without distorting allocations

Proposition

In fairly competitive markets: BSR strictly decreases welfare.

Firms and low types are losers but high types are winners.

Intuition: Firms discriminate less & substitute to quantity distortions lower markup on contract H lower allocation & raise markup on contract L

Theory Summary

Consequences of Bill-shock regulation depend on

Consumer sophistication or naivete

Consumer heterogeneity

Market pass-through rate

Elasticity of demand

Application: FCC Bill-Shock Agreement

Source : Grubb & Osborne (Forthcoming)

Question : Will the FCC Bill-Shock Agreement help or hurt consumers?

Timing : Asked before agreement implemented. Can we predict the policy’s affect?

Data : Panel of 15,000 student bills 2002-2004

Exercise : Estimate demand & Simulate policy

Application: FCC Bill-Shock Agreement

Source : Grubb & Osborne (Forthcoming)

Question : Will the FCC Bill-Shock Agreement help or hurt consumers?

Timing : Asked before agreement implemented. Can we predict the policy’s affect?

Data : Panel of 15,000 student bills 2002-2004

Exercise : Estimate demand & Simulate policy

5 Stylized Facts & Modeling Approach

Consumers are (1) price sensitive, (2) uncertain about the ex post marginal price, and (3) inattentive.

→ bill-shock alerts affect choice model inattentive (but sophisticated) consumption

Consumers (4) learn and switch plans but also (5) make predictable mistakes ⇒ We allow for biased beliefs:

Identify true distribution of tastes (from usage patterns)

Identify prior beliefs (from plan choices)

Biases measure systematic differences between the two, and lead to predictable mistakes

5 Stylized Facts & Modeling Approach

Consumers are (1) price sensitive, (2) uncertain about the ex post marginal price, and (3) inattentive.

→ bill-shock alerts affect choice model inattentive (but sophisticated) consumption

Consumers (4) learn and switch plans but also (5) make predictable mistakes ⇒ We allow for biased beliefs:

Identify true distribution of tastes (from usage patterns)

Identify prior beliefs (from plan choices)

Biases measure systematic differences between the two, and lead to predictable mistakes

Results

Overconfidence: underestimate uncertainty about usage by 62%

Bill shock regulation prices fixed: avg. annual consumer welfare rises

$

103 but prices vary: firms lower overage rates & adjust monthly fees and allowances to offset lost overage revenue

→ avg. annual consumer welfare falls

$

33

Unregulated

Bill−Shock Reg.

−2000 0 1000 2000

Annual Utility Change from Bill Shock

0 100 200 300 400 500

Monthly Overage Fee ($)

Results

Overconfidence: underestimate uncertainty about usage by 62%

Bill shock regulation prices fixed: avg. annual consumer welfare rises

$

103 but prices vary: firms lower overage rates & adjust monthly fees and allowances to offset lost overage revenue

→ avg. annual consumer welfare falls

$

33

Unregulated

Bill−Shock Reg.

−2000 0 1000 2000

Annual Utility Change from Bill Shock

0 100 200 300 400 500

Monthly Overage Fee ($)

Results

Overconfidence: underestimate uncertainty about usage by 62%

Bill shock regulation prices fixed: avg. annual consumer welfare rises

$

103 but prices vary: firms lower overage rates & adjust monthly fees and allowances to offset lost overage revenue

→ avg. annual consumer welfare falls

$

33

Unregulated

Bill−Shock Reg.

−2000 0 1000 2000

Annual Utility Change from Bill Shock

0 100 200 300 400 500

Monthly Overage Fee ($)

Conclusion

Bill-shock regulation may help or hurt consumers

FCC’s bill-shock agreement may be a nudge that back-fires and harms consumers (a little).

Similar regulation for overdraft fees is more promising

Banks price discriminate, but do not vary overdraft charges across accounts to do so.

US opt-in rates are suggestive of naivete.

evidence for heterogeneous attention.

pass-through rate likely to be low

Other applications: Frequent flyer perks, electricity, healthcare,...

Conclusion

Bill-shock regulation may help or hurt consumers

FCC’s bill-shock agreement may be a nudge that back-fires and harms consumers (a little).

Similar regulation for overdraft fees is more promising

Banks price discriminate, but do not vary overdraft charges across accounts to do so.

US opt-in rates are suggestive of naivete.

evidence for heterogeneous attention.

pass-through rate likely to be low

Other applications: Frequent flyer perks, electricity, healthcare,...

Download