WORKING PAPER NUMBER 32 M A Y 2007 The Anarchy of Numbers: Aid, Development, and Cross-country Empirics By David Roodman Abstract Recent literature contains many stories of how foreign aid affects economic growth: aid raises growth in countries with good policies, or in countries with difficult economic environments, or mainly outside the tropics, or on average with diminishing returns. The diversity of these results suggests that many are fragile. I test 7 important aid-growth papers for robustness. The 14 tests are minimally arbi- trary, deriving mainly from differences among the studies themselves. This approach investigates the importance of potentially arbitrary specification choices while minimizing arbitrariness in testing choices. All of the results appear fragile, especially to sample expansion. The Anarchy of Numbers: Aid, Development, and Cross-country Empirics David Roodman1 Research Associate, Center for Global Development Center for Global Development Working Paper #32 Final version: May 2007 Abstract: Recent literature contains many stories of how foreign aid affects economic growth: aid raises growth in countries with good policies, or in countries with difficult economic environments, or mainly outside the tropics, or on average with diminishing returns. The diversity of these results suggests that many are fragile. I test 7 important aid-growth papers for robustness. The 14 tests are minimally arbitrary, deriving mainly from differences among the studies themselves. This approach investigates the importance of potentially arbitrary specification choices while minimizing arbitrariness in testing choices. All of the results appear fragile, especially to sample expansion. Keywords: Foreign assistance; economic growth; economic development; robustness testing JEL codes: F350, O230, O400 1 The author thanks William Easterly and Michael Clemens for advice, Craig Burnside, Lisa Chauvet, Jan Dehn, and Henrik Hansen for data and assistance, and Stephen Knack, Patrick Guillaumont, anonymous reviewers, and participants in an August 2003 seminar at the Center for Global Development for valuable comments. Responsibility for the final product rests with the author. Address for correspondence: David Roodman, Center for Global Development, e-mail: droodman@cgdev.org. This paper has appeared in the World Bank Economic Review 21(2), pp. 255– 77, May 2007. The final version differs from the July 2004 one in two major respects. It no longer attempts to correct specification problems such as autocorrelation, focusing purely on the issue of fragility. And it now tests GMM regressions for robustness to outlier removal, by picking outliers from parallel 2SLS regressions. These changes in method explain the changes in results since the previous version. In early 1981, economist Edward Leamer gave a speech at the University of Toronto in which he bemoaned the state of econometrics. Econometrics sought the status of a science, with regressions its analogue for the reproducible experiments of chemistry or physics. Yet an essential part of econometric “experimentation” was too often arbitrary, opaque, and unrepeatable. “The econometric art as it is practiced at the computer terminal involves fitting many, perhaps thousands, of statistical models….This search for a model is often well intentioned, but there can be no doubt that such a specification search invalidates the traditional theories of inference” (Leamer 1983). The way out of the quagmire, he argued, was for econometricians to explore larger regions of “specification space,” systematically analyzing the relationship between assumptions and conclusions. One econometric debate with hallmarks of the syndrome Leamer describes is that on the effectiveness of foreign aid in developing countries. Since Griffin and Enos (1970), econometricians have parried over the question of how aid affects economic growth in receiving countries. Prominent in the contemporary work, Burnside and Dollar (2000) conclude, “aid has a positive effect on growth in a good policy environment.” Their evidence: the statistical significance in cross-country panel growth regressions of an interaction term of total aid received and an indicator of the quality of recipient economic policies (aid×policy). But Burnside and Dollar is just one voice among many. Collier and Dehn (2001), Collier and Dollar (2002, 2004), and Collier and Hoeffler (2004), corroborated their finding, while others challenged it. From the ongoing debate emerge several stories of the relationship between aid and growth, each of which turns on a particular quadratic or interaction term involving aid. The stories are not incompatible, but most papers support only one. Hansen and Tarp (2001) find that entering the square of aid drives out aid×policy, and makes the simple aid term significant too: aid works on average, but with dimin- 1 ishing returns. Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) also fail to find significance for aid×policy, and instead offer evidence that aid works best in countries with difficult economic environments, characterized by volatile and declining terms of trade, low population, and natural disasters. In the same vein, Collier and Dehn (2001) find that increasing aid cushions countries against negative export price shocks. Collier and Hoeffler (2004) offer a triple-interaction term: aid works particularly well in countries that are recovering from civil war and that have good policies. Last, Hansen and Tarp, with Dalgaard, say that aid raises growth outside the tropics but not in them (Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp 2004). These papers differ not only in their conclusions but their specifications too. Within the group, there are two different choices of period length in the panel data sets, three definitions of “policy,” three of aid, and four choices of control variable set. Though probably none of the choices is made on a whim, these differences appear to be examples of what Leamer called “whimsy.” From Leamer’s point of view, the studies taken together represent a small sampling of specification space. And few include much robustness testing. Without further analysis, it is hard to know whether the results reveal solid underlying regularities in the data or are fragile artifacts of particular specification choices. This paper examines the possibility of fragility systematically. Since by the laws of chance any regression can be broken with enough experimentation, it is essential for credibility that the testing suite itself be minimally arbitrary. The tests derive from two sources: the various choices already present in the original specifications; and the passage of time, which allows expansion of data sets (as in Easterly, Levine, and Roodman 2004). In all, regressions from 7 of the most prominent studies are subjected to this systematic test suite. 2 Section 1 reviews the approaches and conclusions of the studies that are tested for robustness. Section 2 describes the tests. Section 3 reports the results. Section 4 concludes. I. History The hope has often arisen that a turn to the numbers would shed light on the questions of whether and when foreign aid works. In the view of Hansen and Tarp (2000), this literature has gone through three generations. The first generation essentially spans 1970–72, and mainly investigates the aid-savings link. Influenced by the Harrod-Domar model, in which savings is the binding constraint on growth, aid-induced saving is assumed to lead directly to investment, thence to growth via a fixed incremental capital-output ratio. The second generation runs from the early 1970s to the early 1990s and directly investigates whether aid affects investment and growth. Hansen and Tarp argue that the preponderance of the evidence from these first two generations shows that 1) aid increases total savings, but less than one-to-one; and 2) that aid increases investment and growth. They suggest that studies with more pessimistic results, such as Mosley, Hudson, and Horrell (1987), have gained disproportionate attention precisely because they are contrarian. The third generation commences with Boone (1994) and continues to this day; it is the focus of this paper. The current generation has brought several innovations. The data sets cover more countries and years. Reflecting the influence of the new growth theory, regressors are typically included to represent the economic and institutional environment (sometimes together called the “policy environment”). The potential endogeneity of aid is addressed through instrumenting. And the marginal aid-growth slope is allowed to vary, through incorporation of such regressors as aid2 and aid×policy. The data sets are almost always panels. Burnside and Dollar (2000) test whether an interaction term of aid and an index of recipient economic policies is significantly associated with growth. Their panel is drawn from devel3 oping countries outside the former Eastern bloc, covering the six four-year periods in 1970–93. They incorporate some controls found significant in the general growth literature, namely: initial income (log real GDP/capita) to capture convergence; ethno-linguistic fractionalization (Easterly and Levine 1997), assassinations/capita, and the product thereof; the Knack-Keefer (1995) institutional quality variable, “ICRGE”; M2/GDP, to indicate financial depth, lagged one period to avoid endogeneity (King and Levine 1993); and dummies for sub-Saharan Africa and fastgrowing East Asia. Burnside and Dollar use a measure of aid called Effective Development Assistance (EDA, Chang, Fernandez-Arias, and Serven 1998). EDA differs in two major respects from the usual net Overseas Development Assistance measure (net ODA) tabulated by the Development Assistance Committee (DAC). First, EDA excludes technical assistance, on the grounds that it funds not so much recipient governments as consultants. Second, it differs in its treatment of loans. Net ODA counts disbursements of concessional (low-interest) loans only, but at full face value.1 As a capital flow concept, it nets out principal but not interest payments on old loans. In contrast, EDA includes development loans, regardless how concessional (for example, nearcommercial loans by the World Bank to middle-income countries such as Brazil), but counts only their grant element—that is, their net present value. Concerned about limited statistical power, Burnside and Dollar combine their economic policy indicators into a single variable. They first run a growth regression without aid terms, but with all controls and three indicators of economic policy—log (1+inflation), budget balance/GDP, and the Sachs-Warner (1995) openness variable. All three policy variables differ 1 DAC considers a loan concessional if it has a grant element of at least 25% of the loan value, using a 10% discount rate. 4 from 0 at the 0.05 level, so Burnside and Dollar form a linear combination of the three using their coefficients as weights.2 When Burnside and Dollar run their base specification, including aid and aid×policy the term of central interest, aid×policy, does not in fact enter significantly. However, they find that it becomes significant after either of two possible changes. Five outlier observations can be excluded (giving Burnside and Dollar’s preferred specification). Or a quadratic interaction term can be added—aid2×policy, in which case both aid×policy and aid2×policy appear significantly different from 0, the first with positive sign, the second negative. Burnside and Dollar famously conclude that aid raises growth in a good policy environment, but with diminishing returns. Burnside and Dollar’s work has triggered responses, some critical, some supportive. Hansen and Tarp (2001) make one prominent attack. They modify the Burnside and Dollar two-stage least-squares (2SLS) regressions in several ways, most importantly by adding aid2. Aid×policy is not significant in their results, but aid and aid2 are, the first positive and the second negative. The implication is that aid is effective on average, but with diminishing returns—regardless of recipients’ policies as far as the evidence goes. Hansen and Tarp then criticize both the Burnside and Dollar regressions and their own for failing to handle several standard concerns. There may be country-level fixed effects that correlate with both policies and growth. Failing to purge or control for all such effects could give spurious explanatory power to policies and aid×policy. Also, variables other than aid and its interaction terms, such as fiscal balance, could be endogenous and need instrumenting too. They deploy the Arellano-Bond (1991) Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) estimator, which is designed to handle these problems in short panels. Hansen 2 They also add a constant term to the index, but this has no effect on the regression results of interest here. 5 and Tarp also add Δaid and Δ(aid2) as regressors.3 Their results on aid and aid2 hold. And Δaid and Δ(aid2) are significant too, again, the first with positive sign and the second negative. Guillaumont and Chauvet (2001) tell a third story. They hypothesize that the economic vulnerability of a country influences aid effectiveness. They call economic vulnerability the “environment,” not to be confused with Burnside and Dollar’s “policy environment.” In this story, aid flows stabilize countries that are particularly buffeted by terms of trade difficulties, other sorts of external shocks, or natural disasters. Guillaumont and Chauvet build an environment index out of four variables: volatility of agricultural value added (to proxy for natural disasters), volatility of export earnings, long-term terms of trade trend, and log of population (small countries being more vulnerable to external forces). Their specification is distinctive in using 12-year periods, and in its controls, which include population growth, mean years of secondary school education among adults, the Barro-Lee (2000) measure of political instability based on assassinations and revolutions, ethno-linguistic fractionalization, and lagged M2/GDP. In their OLS and 2SLS regressions, aid×environment appears with the predicted negative sign, indicating that aid works better in countries with worse environments. The term also drives out aid×policy. Collier and Dollar (2002) corroborate Burnside and Dollar with a quite different data set and specification. Unlike Burnside and Dollar, they perform OLS only. They include former Eastern bloc countries, the Bahamas, and Singapore. They use net ODA rather than EDA. They study 1974–97 instead of 1970–93. They drop all Burnside and Dollar controls except log initial GDP/capita, ICRGE, and period dummies. But they add region dummies.4 And they define policy as the overall score from the World Bank’s Country Policy and Institutional Assessment 3 This is equivalent to adding lagged aid and lagged aid2 since the regressions also control for aid and aid2. The regions are Europe and Central Asia, Middle East and North Africa, Southern Asia, East Asia and Pacific, Sub-Saharan Africa, and Latin America and the Caribbean, as defined by the World Bank. 4 6 (CPIA), which is a composite rating of countries on 20 aspects of policies and institutions.5 Thye add aid2 but then drop the linear aid term from their preferred specification as insignificant. After all the changes, aid×policy is again significant, as is aid2, with a negative sign. Stargin from the Collier and Dollar core regression, Collier and Hoeffler (2004) analyze how recent emergence from civil war influences aid effectiveness. Sticking to the four-year panel, they create three dummies to indicate how recently civil war ended. “Peace onset” is 1 in the period when a country goes from civil war to peace. “Post-conflict 1” is 1 the following period, and “post-conflict 2” the period after that—assuming civil war does not recur. Aid×policy×post-conflict 1 is significant in Collier and Hoeffler’s preferred (OLS) specification: aid works particularly well in a good policy environment a few years after civil conflict. Also corroborating Burnside and Dollar, Collier and Dehn (2001) hew closely to the Burnside and Dollar specification and data set, and tell a story that incorporates elements from Guillaumont and Chauvet. They find that adding variables incorporating information on export shocks renders Burnside and Dollar’s preferred specification—the one with aid×policy but not aid2×policy—more robust to the inclusion of Burnside and Dollar’s five outliers. First, they add two variables indicating the magnitude of any positive or negative commodity export price shocks. They report that aid×policy is then significant at 0.01 for a regression on the full data set. The negative-shock variable is significant too, with the expected minus sign.6 Then Collier and Dehn add four aid-shock interaction terms: lagged aid×positive shock, lagged aid×negative shock, Δaid×positive shock, and Δaid×negative shock. The first and last prove positive and sig- 5 Collier and Hoeffler (2002) make a small correction to the Collier and Dollar data set, excluding 5 observations where a missing value had been treated as 0. The Collier and Hoeffler version of the Collier and Dollar regression is tested here. 6 However, the reproduction using their data gives a t statistic of only 0.42 to aid×policy despite having the same R2 and sample size, so their result may be an error. But the same, negative sign does appear on the negative-shock variable. 7 nificant in OLS, and the last, Δaid×negative shock proves particularly robust in their testing. The study buttresses Burnside and Dollar while suggesting that well-timed aid increases ameliorate negative export shocks. This matches the Guillaumont and Chauvet result in spirit. But where Guillaumont and Chauvet interact the amount of aid with the standard deviation of an index of export volume and other variables, Collier and Dehn’s significant term involves the change in aid and the change in export prices. Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp (2004) tell a novel aid-growth story. They focus on the share of a country’s area that is in the tropics, as a determinant of both growth and the influence of aid on growth. This variable surfaces as a growth determinant in Bloom and Sachs (1998), Gallup and Sachs (1999), and Sachs (2001, 2003). The causal links may include institutions and economic policies (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001; Easterly and Levine 2003). Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp thus see tropical area as an exogenous “deep determinant” of growth. In the regressions, aid and aid×tropical area fraction are quite significant, the first with positive sign, the second with negative sign and similar magnitude. For countries situated completely in the tropics, the derivative of growth with respect to aid (the sum of the two coefficients) is indistinguishable from 0. Thus, on average, aid seems to work outside the tropics but not in them. The authors report that their new interaction term drives out both aid×policy and aid2. There are other third-generation studies (Hadjimichael et al. 1995; Durbarry, Gemmell, and Greenaway 1998; Lensink and White 2001; Svensson 1999; Chauvet and Guillaumont 2002; Burnside and Dollar 2004). This paper focuses on those already highlighted as being among the most influential and, with one exception, having been published. The exception is Collier and Dehn (2001) which is a pillar of the published Collier and Dollar (2004). 8 The testing here applies to what appear to be authors’ preferred regressions. (See Table 1.) Country by country, the tested regressions generate a diversity of conclusions about the slope of growth with respect to aid at the margin. (See Table 2, illustrating for the 20 largest aid recipients in 1998.) As an example of the calculations here, the Burnside and Dollar structural equation is ΔY = αA + β A × P + γP + xδ + ε , where Y is GDP/capita, A is aid, P is policy, x is a vector of controls, including initial GDP/capita, and ε is the error term. So the implied slope of growth respect to aid is d (ΔY ) dA = α + βP, which depends on the recipient’s policy level. Applying such formulas to 1998 data, the Burnside and Dollar regression generally predicts benefits from increasing aid while, at the other extreme, the Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp and Guillaumont and Chauvet regressions express pessimism. The question is what to make of such conclusions. II. The Test Suite There is some robustness testing in the recent literature on aid-growth connections, albeit focusing on Burnside and Dollar. Lu and Ram (2001) introduce fixed effects into the Burnside and Dollar regressions. Ram (2004) splits the aid variable into the components coming from bilateral and multilateral donors, and also tests alternative definitions of policy. Dalgaard and Hansen (2001) modify the choice of excluded outliers. Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004) extend the Burnside and Dollar data set to additional countries and an additional period, 1994–97. All these tests eliminate the key Burnside and Dollar result. The present study expands Easterly, Levine, and Roodman along two dimensions. It applies more tests. And it tests more studies. 9 In addition to fragility, the other bugaboo of econometrics is misspecification. Important questions can be raised about the validity of the regressions tested here. Some exhibit serial correlation in the errors.7 The excludability and relevance of instruments are a legitimate concern. Regressors treated as exogenous may not be. And term pairs such as aid and aid2 may be multicollinear. But for the sake of concision, this paper focuses on the problem of fragility. The Tests The tests applied to these third-generation aid-growth regressions constitute a more systematic sampling of “specification space” than has hitherto been made. To limit complexity and minimize arbitrariness, each test ideally involves changing just one aspect of the estimations at a time. The tests are summarized in Table 3. The first four groups of tests, relating to the controls, the definition of aid and policy, and period length, transfer one specification’s choices to the others.8 Last are tests that modify the sample by dropping outliers and/or expanding to new countries and periods. The tests are: 1. Changing the control set. In his worries over whimsy, the specification choice that conerns Leamer is that of regressors. The studies examined use four different control sets, which give rise to four robustness tests, detailed in Table 3. Each substitutes an alternative control set for the original one and examines the effect on the significance of key terms. Like the authors of the original regressions, and in the spirit of avoiding arbitrariness, the robustness tests here use all complete observations available for developing countries (in7 An earlier version of this paper attempted to address autocorrelation by further modifying the tested specifications, at the expense of complexity in presentation, and, arguably, “whimsy.” In particular, most of the test regressions included the log of population as a control since Sargan-type tests suggested it was an improperly excluded instrument. This explains the difference in results between this and the earlier version. 8 Those papers that instrument the variables of interest also differ in their choice of instruments. But since different variables (aid×policy in one regression, say, versus aid2 in another), ought to be instrumented differently, the various instrument sets are less interchangeable and of less use for the approach in this paper. 10 cluding the countries of Eastern Europe). Because different variables are available for different subsets of countries, changing the regressor set changes the regression sample. One could perform variants of the tests that are restricted to the intersections of the old and new samples in an attempt to distinguish the effects of changing sample and changing variables. This course is not taken here because it would add to the complexity, would still cause sample changes, and would not answer the hypothetical, “What would the results have been if the original authors had used alternative controls?” The authors almost certainly would have used all available observations. 2. Redefining aid. All the studies take total aid received as a share of recipient GDP. But there are differences in defining both the numerator and denominator of the ratio. Burnside and Dollar, Collier and Dehn, and Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp use Effective Development Assistance in the numerator while the rest use net ODA. On the choice of denominator, there is also a split. Hansen and Tarp and Guillaumont and Chauvet use GDP converted to dollars using market exchange rates. The others use real GDP from the Penn World Tables. A country’s relative price level strongly correlates with income per head, with the poorest countries having price levels 20–25% of that of the United States. Thus using purchasing power parities instead of exchange rates will cause the GDPs of the poorest countries to be measured as relatively larger and aid to them as relatively smaller as a share of GDP. This might have a significant effect on coefficient estimates for aid and its interactions With two options each for measuring aid and GDP, there are four possible combinations for aid/GDP. The literature includes all but EDA/exchange rate GDP, and these are the bases for three tests.9 In fact, EDA/real GDP and ODA/real GDP are highly correlated (Dalgaard 9 The published EDA data (Chang, Fernandez-Arias, and Serven 1998) cover only 1975–95. EDA as used here is extrapolated to the rest of 1970–2001 via a regression of EDA on net ODA. 11 and Hansen 2001), so switching from one to the other may not stress results much. (See Table 4.) 3. Redefining good policy. Three sets of “good policy” variables appear among the tested regressions: 1) Burnside and Dollar’s combination of budget balance, inflation, and SachsWarner openness; 2) inflation and Sachs-Warner only (Hansen and Tarp GMM); and 3) CPIA alone (Collier and Dollar, Collier and Hoeffler). These generate three robustness tests. Using Burnside and Dollar’s coefficients to form policy indexes (6.85 for budget balance, – 1.40 for inflation, and 2.16 for Sachs-Warner), the first two policy definitions are correlated 0.98, but the third varies more distinctly. (See Table 4.) But in actually application of the tests, the Burnside-Dollar–style index-forming regression is rerun each time; it includes all regressors except aid and its interaction terms, and the coefficients on the policy variables are used to make the index, regardless of statistical significance.10 4. Changing periodization. All but Guillaumont and Chauvet use four-year periods. The lack of higher-frequency observations of the Guillaumont and Chauvet environment variable prevents adapting their 12-year regressions to a 4-year-period panel. But the other regressions can be tested on 12-year panels. Notably, key cross-section studies in the growth literature use periods of 10–25 years despite the small samples that result (Barro 1991; Mankiw, Romer, and Weil 1992; Sachs and Warner 1995). 5. Removing outliers. The tested Burnside and Dollar specification excludes five observations that are a) outliers in aid×policy and b) highly influential on the coefficient on that term. This raises a general question about the importance of outliers. To investigate, one robustness test reruns the reproductions of the original regressions after excluding outliers. Another does the 10 The constant term in the policy index is computed in the same manner as in Burnside and Dollar. It is the predicted growth rate in the model when the policy variables and the period dummies are zero, and all other variables 12 same for the expanded-sample versions. (See below.) Following Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004), outliers are chosen by applying the Hadi (1992) procedure for identifying multiple outliers to the partial scatter of growth and a regressor of interest, using 0.05 as the cut-off significance level.11 In 2SLS estimatations, regressors are first projected onto instruments.12 Outliers are not synonymous with influential observations. But even outliers that do not greatly influence coefficients of interest can substantially affect reported standard errors. In addition, outliers are the observations most likely to signal measurement problems or structural breaks beyond which the core model does not hold—both of which seem better reasons for exclusion than high influence. That said, outliers do not necessarily signal measurement problems or structural breaks. This is especially possible when the variable of interest is highly non-normal, such as the Collier and Dehn export price shock variable. In such cases, outliers may contain valuable information about the development process under rare circumstances. Since the two-dimensional partial scatter plot is not well-defined for GMM regressions, in those cases, analogous 2SLS regressions are run for the purposes of identifying outliers. 6. Expanding the sample. Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004) develop a dataset that extends that of Burnside and Dollar from 1970–93 to 1970–97 and adds six countries. For the present study, that data set has been extended to 2001 and improved in other respects. (See Appendix 1.) This allows a net expansion in both years and countries for all but Guillaumont and take their sample-average values. 11 Applying the Hadi procedure directly to a full, many-dimensioned data set typically identified 20% or more of observations as outliers. 12 This test is even run on the Burnside and Dollar 5/OLS regressions, from which one set of outliers is already excluded. Regardless of the genesis of these regressions’ results, it is interesting whether they are driven by a few observations in the remaining sample. 13 Chauvet regression, whose 12-year periods and unusual environment variable hinder expansion. Issues in Interpreting Results If Leamer’s (1983) extreme bounds analysis is applied to the results of this testing, then a coefficient will be deemed robustly different from 0 only if it is significantly different from 0 in every test. However, as Sala-I-Martin (1997) argues, this definition of robustness seems extreme. For example, one could test robustness by averaging together all observations for each global region, generating samples of some 6 observations. Almost no regression would pass this test. One could argue that this test would be “unfair,” i.e., too weak to generate meaningful results. But there is no sharp division between fair and unfair tests. Indeed, in this test suite, the 12-year-period test destroys every regression it can be applied to. It is not obvious whether the test is too strong or the regressions too weak. Thus robustness should be a continuous rather than dichotomous concept. Sala-I-Martin offers his own procedure for assessing robustness. In essence, he estimates the cumulative distribution function for a coefficient of interest by running a large number of variants of the regression it comes from. The robustness of a coefficient is then the fraction of the density that is on one or the other side of zero. The validity of this concept is based on the assumption, however informal, that the set of regressions actually run is a representative of all possible variants of the original regression. For the collection of tests assembled here, that assumption is not valid. For example, one important subset of tests, those expanding the sample, cannot be applied to the Guillaumont and Chauvet regression. It does not seem plausible that the test results are representative both with and without this important subset of tests. 14 The sampling of specification space that is made here is minimally arbitrary, but cannot be assumed to be representative of all possible tests. Thus while Leamer’s definition of robustness may be too harsh for this context, Sala-I-Martin’s has its own limitations. This will be true even if one performs every possible combination of tests in the suite rather than just one at a time. In the end, it seems that human judgment applied to the full set of results must substitute for mechanical definitions of robustness. This in turn means there is some value in keeping the tests few enough for the human mind to embrace. III. Results The first step in the testing is to use the authors’ data sets to reproduce their original results (see columns 1 of Table 5 and Table 6). All the reproductions exhibit the same pattern of results as the originals and all but one have the same sample size.13 The Burnside and Dollar, Collier and Dehn, and Hansen and Tarp reproductions are perfect, and the rest are close. Since the purpose of the paper is to test robustness, the inexact matches are not a concern. If the results from the tested regressions are robust, they should withstand whatever minor changes in data or specification cause the discrepancies in the reproductions. Table 5 and Table 6 report results on key terms in all tested regressions.14 Blank cells indicate inapplicable tests. The test involving the definition of aid as EDA/real GDP, for example, is not applicable to regressions that originally use it. Using 12-year periods does not work for the Collier and Hoeffler regression, because the definition of their post-conflict 1 variable assumes 13 The Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp regression was executed with the DPD for Ox package (Doornik, Arellano, and Bond 2002). It turns out that an undocumented limitation in this software—incomplete observations that create gaps in the time series must always be included in the data file rather than deleted—led to a slight mishandling of the data. The xtabond2 module for Stata (Roodman 2006), used here, does not have this limitation. This explains the difference in samples. 14 Full results are available upon request. 15 4-year periods. Lack of higher-frequency data for Guillaumont and Chauvet’s environment variable prevents short-period tests. A total of 77 robustness checks are run.15 Results for tests inspired by differences among the original regressions are in Table 5. The Collier and Hoeffler result on post-conflict 1×aid×policy (or the collinear post-conflict 1×aid) and the Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp results for aid and aid×tropical area fraction do best. Interestingly, all of these center on sharply bimodal variables: The Collier and Hoeffler postconflict 1 dummy is 1 for only 13 of the 344 observations in their original sample, and there are negative shocks in 38 of the 234 Collier and Dehn observations. In the Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp sample, 233 of the 371 observations are 100% tropical and 68 are 0%, leaving 70 in between. Evidently regularities involving such variables are more resilient to specification changes. Results from sample-modifying tests appear in Table 6. The first two result columns are based on regressions on the original authors’ datasets—first for their full sample, second for the sample excluding outliers. The next pair of columns is analogous, for the expanded data set. The figures in Appendix 2 illustrate the sample-modifying results, and are reminders of the importance of checking for outliers. Except for Guillaumont and Chauvet, all the original OLS and 2SLS results depend on outliers for some or all of their significance. The dependence is particularly heavy for the regressions involving aid×policy. On the other hand, the lack of significance of most of the coefficients under the sample-expansion test is not driven by outliers. It is worth noting that the Collier and Dehn result on Δaid×negative shock, another interaction term involving a variable with a highly non-normal distribution, is arguably stronger than it looks. The coef- 15 Initial testing revealed multicollinearity in the Collier and Hoeffler regression. In their preliminary regression 3.1 (not regression 3.4, which is tested here), they include the variables post-conflict 1, post-conflict 1×policy, and postconflict 1×aid2, along with the favored post-conflict 1×aid ×policy. In the reproduction of 3.1, post-conflict 1×aid×policy and post-conflict 1×aid have a partial correlation of 0.985, making the two statistically indistinguishable. Thus the Collier and Hoeffler results ought to be interpreted as pertaining to either post-conflict 1×aid ×policy or post-conflict 1×aid. Occam’s razor argues for the latter. 16 ficient is reversed by the exclusion of outliers from the original sample. But it is arguably fallacious to draw conclusions about the role of shocks having excluded many of the most dramatic examples. The overall pattern is clear-cut. The 12-year test is the toughest, probably because of the small samples, failing all regressions. The new-data test is not far behind, an important point given that the surgery it involves—a moderate sample expansion—is much less radical. Reading the tables by rows (test subjects) instead of columns (tests), we see that the Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp result on the aid-tropics link is the only one to come through the specificiationmodifying tests strongly. But it too falls down on the sample-modifying tests after outliers are removed. Four of the nine outliers are for the Jordan, covering 1974–89, a period in which that non-tropical country experienced high growth and received much aid from its neighbors. This confirms the conclusion of Rajan and Subramanian (2005) that the aid×tropics result is fragile too. IV. Conclusion Each of the papers examined here embodies a set of choices about model specification and data. Aid is measured a certain way. A certain epoch is studied. Periods have a certain length. And so on. Some of these choices imply assumptions about the world, such as, say, that aid is exogenous to growth. All limit the scope of a strict interpretation of the results. A question of great importance for the literature is, how many of such implied assumptions can be dropped without harming the conclusions? The results reported here suggest that the fragility found in Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004) for Burnside and Dollar is the norm in the cross-country aid effectiveness literature. Indeed, in a counterpoint to the focus of Leamer (1983), Levine and Renelt (1992), and Sala-I- 17 Martin (1997) on the choice of controls as a source of fragility, it turns out that modifying the sample generally affects results most. For example, in the Collier and Dollar regression, half of the specification-modifying tests leave the t statistic at 1.49 or higher and two more lower it to near 1.00. (See Table 5.) But adding more years sends it to –0.19—and, after dropping outliers, to –0.81. (See Table 6.) Does this mean that the various stories of aid effectiveness should be summarily dismissed? Are recipient policies, exogenous economic factors, and post-conflict status irrelevant to aid effectiveness? Are there no diminishing returns to aid? Is helping the neediest countries a hopeless task? No. There can be no doubt that some aid finances investment, and that domestic policies, governance, external conditions, and other factors these authors study influence the productivity of investment. Why then do such stories of aid effectiveness not shine through more clearly? The reasons are several. Aid is probably not a fundamentally decisive factor for development, not as important as, say, domestic savings, inequality, or governance. Moreover, foreign assistance is not homogeneous. It consists of everything from food aid for famine-struck countries to technical advice on building judiciaries to loans for paving roads. And much aid is poorly used—or, like venture capital, is good bets gone bad. Thus the statistical noise tends to drown out the signal. Perhaps researchers will yet unearth more robust answers to the fundamental questions of aid policy. Or perhaps they have hit the limits of cross-country empirics. Either way, robust, valid generalizations have not and will not come easily. Despite decades of trying, cross-country growth empirics have yet to teach us much about whether and when aid works. 18 Table 1. Regressions Tested Regression Estima- Former East tor bloc? Burnside & Dollar 5/OLS OLS No Collier & Dehn 3.4 ““ ““ Collier & Dollar 1.21 OLS Yes Collier & Hoeffler 3.4 OLS ““ Hansen & Tarp 3.2 Difference GMM Dalgaard, Hansen, System and Tarp GMM 3.5 Definition of Study Years/ Outliers Key significant Aid Policy Controls period period out? term(s) LGDP, ETHNF, ASSAS, BB, EDA/real ETHNF×ASSAS, 1970– 4 Yes INFL, aid×policy GDP ICRGE, M2, SSA, 93 SACW EASIA, period dummies aid×policy, ““ 1974– ““ ““ ““ No ×negative Δaid 93 shock LGDP, ICRGE, 1974– ODA/real aid×policy, ““ CPIA ““ policy, period and 97 GDP aid2 region dummies ““ ““ ““ ““ ““ ““ aid×policy× post-conflict 1 No LGDP, ASSAS, ETHNF×ASSAS, 1978– 93 ICRGE, M2, period dummies ““ ODA/ INFL, exchange SACW rate GDP ““ aid, aid2, Δaid, Δaid2 Yes LGDP, policy, pe- 1970– riod dummies 97 ““ EDA/real GDP2 BB, INFL, SACW ““ aid, aid×tropical area fraction GuillauLGDP, ENV, SYR, aid, ODA/ mont & POPG, M2, PIN- 1970– 2SLS No 12 exchange ““ ““ aid×environChauvet STAB, ETHNF, 93 rate GDP ment 5.2 period dummy 1 2 As revised in Collier & Hoeffler 1.1. As extrapolated to 1970–74 and 1996–97 in Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004). Abbreviations: LGDP=log initial real GDP/capita; ETHNF=ethno-linguistic fractionalization, 1960; ASSAS=assassinations/capita; ICRGE=composite of International Country Risk Guide governance indicators; M2=M2/GDP, lagged; SSA=Sub-Saharan Africa dummy; EASIA=fast-growing East Asia dummy; ENV=Guillaumont & Chauvet “environment” variable; SYR=mean years of secondary schooling among adults; PINSTAB=average of ASSAS and revolutions/year; BB=budget balance/GDP; INFL=log(1+inflation); SACW=Sachs-Warner openness; EDA=Effective Development Assistance; ODA=Net Overseas Development Assistance. Source: Author’s analysis based on sources described in the text. 19 Table 2. Marginal Impact of Aid According to Preferred Regression, Various Studies, for 20 Largest Aid Recipients of 1998 Country Bangladesh Bolivia China Cote d'Ivoire Egypt Ethiopia Haiti India Indonesia Kenya B&D 5-OLS 0.20 (0.15) 0.56 (0.22) 0.16 (0.15) 0.56 (0.22) 0.59 (0.23) 0.30 (0.16) 0.15 (0.15) 0.13 (0.15) 0.61 (0.23) 0.46 (0.19) Collier & Dehn –0.04 (0.15) 0.15 (0.22) –0.06 (0.14) 0.15 (0.22) 0.16 (0.22) 0.01 (0.16) –0.07 (0.14) –0.08 (0.14) 0.17 (0.23) 0.09 (0.19) 0.57 (0.22) 0.61 (0.23) 0.54 (0.21) –0.03 (0.17) 0.44 (0.19) 0.62 (0.23) 0.50 (0.20) 0.19 (0.15) 0.08 (0.15) 0.64 (0.45) 0.17 (0.23) 0.13 (0.21) –0.17 (0.13) 0.99 (0.78) 0.18 (0.23) 1.56 (1.24) –0.05 (0.14) –0.11 (0.13) Mozambique Nicaragua Philippines Poland Russia Tanzania Thailand Uganda Vietnam Zambia Collier & Dollar 0.43 (0.20) 0.29 (0.16) 0.53 (0.25) 0.11 (0.10) 0.30 (0.15) 0.20 (0.12) –0.23 (0.13) 0.48 (0.22) 0.51 (0.24) 0.33 (0.16) 0.06 (0.08) –0.09 (0.12) 0.43 (0.20) 0.42 (0.20) 0.36 (0.17) 0.09 (0.08) 0.57 (0.27) 0.16 (0.11) 0.45 (0.21) –0.38 (0.21) Collier & Hoeffler 0.37 (0.20) 0.24 (0.15) 0.46 (0.24) 0.07 (0.09) 0.25 (0.14) 0.71 (0.15) –0.25 (0.12) 0.41 (0.22) 0.44 (0.24) 0.28 (0.16) 0.53 (0.12) 0.51 (0.18) 0.37 (0.20) 0.36 (0.20) 0.32 (0.17) 0.05 (0.08) 0.49 (0.26) 0.11 (0.11) 0.39 (0.21) –0.40 (0.19) Hansen & Dalgaard et Guillaumont Tarp GMM & Chauvet al. 0.14 0.29 –0.72 (0.13) (0.18) (0.37) –0.02 –0.29 –0.33 (0.08) (0.33) (0.17) 0.20 0.66 (0.15) (0.14) –0.05 –0.29 –0.23 (0.08) (0.33) (0.13) 0.13 0.53 –0.55 (0.13) (0.14) (0.28) –0.08 –0.29 0.04 (0.08) (0.33) (0.12) –0.28 –0.29 (0.10) (0.33) 0.20 0.19 –0.97 (0.15) (0.20) (0.51) 0.19 –0.29 –0.68 (0.15) (0.33) (0.35) 0.06 –0.29 –0.48 (0.10) (0.33) (0.25) –1.04 –0.20 –0.26 (0.39) (0.30) (0.14) –0.65 –0.29 –0.18 (0.24) (0.33) (0.11) 0.18 –0.29 –0.86 (0.14) (0.33) (0.45) 0.17 0.69 (0.14) (0.14) 0.20 0.69 (0.15) (0.14) –0.21 –0.29 (0.09) (0.33) 0.20 –0.29 –0.80 (0.15) (0.33) (0.42) –0.09 –0.29 –0.13 (0.08) (0.33) (0.10) 0.12 –0.29 0.00 (0.12) (0.33) (0.00) –0.43 –0.29 –0.32 (0.15) (0.33) (0.17) Robust standard errors in parentheses. All figures are based on reproductions of the original regressions. All pertain to 1994-97, except those the the Guillaument & Chauvet regression, which pertain to 1982-93. Aid is taken as a share of exchange rate GDP in the Hansen & Tarp and Guilaumont & Chauvet regressionis and of PPP GDP in the rest. Blank cells are causing by missing observations of underlying indicators. Source: Authors' analysis based on sources described in the text. 20 Table 3. Robustness Tests Test Changing controls BD controls CD controls GC controls DHT controls Changing aid definition EDA/real GDP ODA/real GDP ODA/exchange rate GDP Changing policy definition INFL, BB, SACW INFL, SACW CPIA Description Control for LGDP, ETHNF, ASSAS, ETHNF×ASSAS, ICRGE, M2, SSA, EASIA, period effects, as in Burnside & Dollar, Collier & Dehn, Hansen & Tarp Control for LGDP, ICRGE, period and region effects, as in Collier & Dollar, Collier & Hoeffler Control for LGDP, ENV, SYR, POPG, M2, PINSTAB, ETHNF, period effects, as in Guillaumont & Chauvet Control for LGDP, ICRGE, SSA, EASIA, period effects, as in Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp Effective Development Assistance/real GDP, as in Burnside & Dollar, Collier & Dehn, Dalgaard, Hansen, & Tarp Net Overseas Development Assistance/real GDP, as in Collier & Dollar, Collier & Hoeffler Net Overseas Development Assistance/exchange rate GDP, as in Hansen & Tarp, Guillaumont & Chauvet Inflation, budget balance, and Sachs-Warner openness, as in Burnside & Dollar, Collier & Dehn Inflation and Sachs-Warner, as in Hansen & Tarp Country Policy and Institutional Assessment, as in Collier & Dollar, Collier & Hoeffler Changing period length 12-year Aggregate over 12-year periods, as in Guillaumont & Chauvet Changing sample and data set No outliers Remove Hadi outliers in the partial scatter of the dependent variable and the independent variable of greatest interest Expanded sample New data set. Carried to 2001, except shocks data end in 1997 and Guillaumont & Chauvet environment variable not updated Expanded sample, no outCombine above two changes liers Abbreviations as in Table 2. 21 Table 4. Simple Correlations of Aid and Good Policy Measures, Respectively, Four-Year Periods, on Available Observations EDA/real GDP ODA/real GDP ODA/exchange rate GDP EDA/real GDP 1.00 ODA/real GDP 0.97 1.00 ODA/exchange rate GDP 0.78 0.82 1.00 Inflation, budget bal- Inflation, Sachs-Warner CPIA ance, Sachs-Warner Inflation, budget balance, Sachs-Warner 1.00 Inflation, Sachs-Warner 0.98 1.00 CPIA 0.53 0.52 1.00 Source: Author’s analysis based on sources described in the text. 22 Table 5. Coefficients on key terms under specification-modifying tests (original data set) Changing controls Specification key term Original Aid × 0.19 Burnside & policy (2.61) Dollar Collier & Dehn Collier & Dollar Collier & Hoeffler Aid × policy Δaid × negative shock Aid × policy Postconflict 1 × aid × policy Aid 2 Aid Hansen & Tarp BD Aid 0.06 0.20 0.16 0.05 (1.07) (2.31) (2.07) (1.96) 0.29 –0.03 (3.12) (–0.25) 279 263 276 275 275 296 264 0.02 0.05 0.07 0.02 0.12 0.11 (1.70) (0.47) (0.43) (0.84) (1.19) (1.39) (2.02) (0.83) 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.02 0.04 0.01 0.03 0.02 (3.17) (1.12) (1.53) (1.06) (2.67) (4.27) (2.04) (0.82) 234 242 227 242 234 234 256 268 0.14 0.12 –0.07 0.12 0.17 0.03 0.05 0.06 (2.15) (1.84) (–1.91) (1.87) (1.70) (1.50) (1.00) (1.10) 344 337 374 349 349 347 365 388 0.18 0.18 0.13 0.18 0.29 0.04 0.18 0.18 (3.92) 344 (3.89) 337 (2.82) 374 (3.81) 349 (3.75) 349 (4.07) 347 (3.97) 365 (4.23) 388 0.90 1.10 1.00 1.10 –0.36 1.85 0.94 0.69 (4.22) (1.56) (2.57) (1.56) (–0.25) (1.30) (2.02) (1.53) –0.02 –0.02 –0.03 –0.02 –0.04 –0.17 –0.02 –0.02 (–1.19) (–2.81) (–1.19) (–0.18) (–2.48) (–1.81) (–1.76) –0.47 –0.47 –0.47 –1.46 –0.71 –0.69 (–1.42) (–1.56) (–1.42) –0.58 (–0.70) (–1.74) (–2.63) (–2.48) 0.01 0.01 0.02 0.01 0.07 0.12 0.01 0.01 (3.64) (1.10) (1.66) (1.10) (0.53) (2.24) (1.86) (2.11) 213 214 213 215 213 Dalgaard, Hansen, & Tarp 0.15 (2.09) 0.03 –0.70 2 DHT 270 (–4.91) Δ(Aid ) GC 0.10 (–3.83) ΔAid CD Changing policy Changing aid EDA/ ODA/ ODA/ INFL, INFL, real real XR BB, SAC CPIA W GDP GDP GDP SAC 213 181 0.69 1.17 1.34 1.33 1.10 214 0.46 (5.09) (6.44) (6.62) (5.72) (5.23) (4.04) Aid × –0.98 –1.49 –1.79 –1.66 –1.17 –0.45 tropical (–3.16) (–8.58) (–8.26) (–6.72) (–5.09) (–3.79) area % 371 354 371 315 371 365 Aid × –0.15 –0.13 –0.07 –0.09 –0.45 –0.31 –0.15 –0.13 Guillaumont environ(–1.79) (–1.73) (–1.40) (–1.54) (–1.96) (–1.77) (–2.13) (–2.01) & Chauvet ment 68 71 73 73 66 66 68 69 All t statistics (in parentheses) are heteroskedasticity-robust; those for GMM regressions also autocorrelation Except for original Hansen and Tarp regression, all GMM standard errors incorporate the Windmeijer (2005) sample correction. Entries significant at 0.05 in bold. Source: Authors’ analysis based on sources described in the text. 23 Table 6. Coefficients on Key Terms under Data Set–Modifying Tests Specification Burnside & Dollar key term Aid × policy Observations Aid × policy Collier & Dehn Collier & Dollar Collier & Hoeffler ΔAid × negative shock Observations Aid × policy Observations Post-conflict × aid × policy Observations Aid 2 Aid Hansen & Tarp Aid, lagged 2 Aid , lagged Observations Aid Dalgaard, Hansen, & Tarp Original Full No sample outliers New data Full No sample outliers 0.19 –0.05 –0.03 –0.25 (2.61) (–0.45) (–0.17) (–1.27) 270 263 446 436 0.10 0.11 0.06 0.10 (1.70) (1.11) (1.07) (0.73) 0.04 –0.06 0.03 –0.17 (3.17) (–1.33) (2.93) (–1.92) 234 224 402 379 0.14 0.07 –0.01 –0.04 (2.15) (1.06) (–0.19) (–0.81) 344 341 520 508 0.18 1.18 0.08 –0.06 (3.92) (2.12) (1.91) (–0.19) 344 333 520 494 0.90 0.96 0.08 0.03 (4.22) (2.19) (0.41) (0.16) –0.02 –0.02 –0.001 –0.001 (–3.83) (–1.95) (–0.57) (–0.42) –0.70 –0.70 –0.13 –0.07 (–4.91) (–2.73) (–0.92) (–0.53) 0.01 0.01 0.002 0.001 (3.64) (1.86) (1.03) (0.71) 213 212 517 514 0.69 0.34 0.89 –0.69 (5.09) (0.20) (5.23) (–0.79) Aid × tropical –0.41 0.63 –0.98 –0.96 area % (–0.25) (0.73) (–3.16) (–3.65) Observations 371 362 474 463 Aid × –0.15 –0.11 environment Guillaumont & Chauvet (–1.79) (–1.96) Observations 68 67 All t statistics (in parentheses) are heteroskedasticity-robust; those for GMM regressions also autocorrelation-robust. Except for original Hansen and Tarp regression, all GMM standard errors incorporate the Windmeijer (2005) finitesample correction. Entries significant at 0.05 in bold. 24 References Acemoglu, D., S. Johnson, and J. A. Robinson. 2001. “The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation.” American Economic Review 91: 1369–1401. Anderson, T.W. and C. Hsiao. 1982. “Formulation and Estimation of Dynamic Models Using Panel Data.” Journal of Econometrics 18(1): 47–82. Arellano, M. and S. Bond. 1991. “Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations.” The Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277–97. Banks, A. 2002. “Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive.” Databanks International, Bronx, NY. Barro, R. J. 1991. “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries.” American Economic Review 106(2): 407–43. Barro, R. J. and J. Lee. 2000. “International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications.” Working Paper 7911. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Bloom, D. and J. D. Sachs. 1998. “Geography, Demography and Economic Growth in Africa.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 207–73. Boone, P. 1994. “Aid and Growth.” Mimeo, London School of Economics, London. Burnside, C. and D. Dollar. 2000. “Aid, Policies, and Growth.” American Economic Review 90(4): 847–68. Burnside, C. and D. Dollar. 2004. “Aid, Policies, and Growth: Revisiting the Evidence.” Policy Research Working Paper O-2834. World Bank, Washington, DC. Chang, C. C., E. Fernandez-Arias, and L. Serven. 1998. “Measuring Aid Flows: A New Approach.” Working Paper 387. Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC. Chauvet, L. and P. Guillaumont. 2002. “Aid and Growth Revisited: Policy, Economic Vulnerability and Political Instability.” Paper presented at the Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics: Towards Pro-poor Policies, Oslo. Collier, P. and J. Dehn. 2001. “Aid, Shocks, and Growth.” Policy Research Working Paper 2688. World Bank, Washington, DC. Collier, P. and D. Dollar. 2002. “Aid Allocation and Poverty Reduction.” European Economic Review 45(1): 1–26. Collier, P. and D. Dollar. 2004. “Development Effectiveness: What Have We Learnt?” The Economic Journal 114(496): F244–71. Collier, P. and A. Hoeffler. 2004. “Aid, Policy and Growth in Post-Conflict Societies.” Euro25 pean Economic Review 48(5): 1125–45. Dalgaard, C. and H., Hansen. 2001. “On Aid, Growth and Good Policies.” Journal of Development Studies 37(6): 17–41. Dalgaard, C., H. Hansen, and F. Tarp. 2004. “On the Empirics of Foreign Aid and Growth.” The Economic Journal 114(496): F191–F216. Dehn, J. 2000. “Commodity Price Uncertainty in Developing Countries.” Working Paper 12. Centre for the Study of African Economies, Oxford. Development Assistance Committee (DAC). 2002. Development Assistance Committee Online. Paris. Doornik, J.A., M. Arellano, and S. Bond. 2002. “Panel Data Estimation Using DPD for Ox.” Available online at http://www.doornik.com/download/dpd.pdf. Durbarry, R., N. Gemmell, and D. Greenaway. 1998. “New Evidence on the Impact of Foreign Aid on Economic Growth.” CREDIT Research Paper 98r8. University of Nottingham, Nottingham. Easterly, W. and R. Levine. 1997. “Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(4): 1203–50. Easterly, W. and R. Levine. 2003. “Tropics, Germs, and Crops: How Endowments Influence Economic Development.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50(1): 3–39. Easterly, W., R. Levine, and D. Roodman. 2004. “New Data, New Doubts: A Comment on Burnside and Dollar’s ‘Aid, Policies, and Growth (2000)’.” American Economic Review 94(2). Easterly, W. and S. Rebelo. 1993. “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 32(3): 417–58. Gallup, J. L., and J. D. Sachs. 1999. “Geography and Economic Development.” In Pleskovic, B. and Stiglitz, J. E. eds., Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, 1998 Proceedings. World Bank, Washington, DC, pp. 127–78. Griffin, K. B. and J. L. Enos. 1970. “Foreign Assistance: Objectives and Consequences.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 18(3): 313–27. Guillaumont, P. and L. Chauvet. 2001. “Aid and Performance: A Reassessment.” Journal of Development Studies 37(6): 66–92. Hadi, A. S. 1992. “Identifying Multiple Outliers in Multivariate Data.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B 54: 761-777. Hadjimichael, M. T., D. Ghura, M., Muhleisen, R. Nord, and E. M. Ucer. 1995. “Sub-Saharan 26 Africa: Growth, Savings, and Investment, 1986–93.” Occasional Paper 118. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Hansen, H. and F. Tarp. 2000. “Aid Effectiveness Disputed.” Journal of International Development 12(3): 375–98. Hansen, H. and F. Tarp. 2001. “Aid and Growth Regressions.” Journal of Development Economics 64(2): 547–70. Holtz-Eakin, D., W. Newey, and H. S. Rosen. 1988. “Estimating Vector Autoregressions with Panel Data.” Econometrica 56(6): 1371–95. International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2003. International Financial Statistics Database. Washington, DC. Jepma, C. J. 1991. “The Tying of Aid.” OECD Development Centre, Paris. Kaufmann, D., A. Kraay, and M. Mastruzzi. 2003. “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002.” Policy Research Working Paper 3106. World Bank, Washington, DC. Killick, T. 1998. “Aid and the Political Economy of Policy Change.” Routledge, London. King, R. G. and R. Levine. 1993. “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might be Right.” American Economic Review 108(3): 717–37. Knack, S. and P. Keefer. 1995. “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures.” Economics and Politics 7(3): 207–27. Leamer, E. E. 1983. “Let’s Take the Con out of Econometrics.” American Economic Review 73(1): 31–43. Levine, R. and D. Renelt. 1992. “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions.” American Economic Review 82(4): 942–63. Lensink, R. and H. White. 2001. “Are There Negative Returns to Aid?” Journal of Development Studies 37(6): 42–65. Lu, S. and R. Ram. 2001. “Foreign Aid, Government Policies, and Economic Growth: Further Evidence from Cross-country Panel Data for 1970–93.” Economia Internazionale 54(1): 15– 29. Mankiw, N. G., D. Romer, and D. N. Weil. 1992. “A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth.” American Economic Review 107(2): 407–37. Mosley, P., J. Hudson, and S. Horrell. 1987. “Aid, the Public Sector and the Market in Less Developed Countries.” Economic Journal 97(387): 616–41. Rajan, R. and A. Subramanian. 2005. “Aid and Growth: What Does the Cross-Country Evidence Really Show?” Working Paper 05/127. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. 27 Ram, R. 2004. “Recipient Country’s ‘Policies’ and the Effect of Foreign Aid on Economic Growth in Developing Countries: Additional Evidence.” Journal of International Development 16(2): 201–11. Rodríguez, F. and D. Rodrik. 2001. “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.” In Bernanke, B. and Rogoff, K. S., eds., National Bureau of Economic Research Macroeconomics Annual. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. Roeder, P.G. 2001. “Ethnolinguistic Fractionalization (ELF) Indices, 1961 and 1985.” Avaliable on http//:weber.ucsd.edu/~proeder/elf.htm, accessed May 2004. Roodman, D. 2006. “How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to “Difference” and “System” GMM in Stata.” Working Paper 103. Center for Global Development, Washington, DC. Sachs, J. D. 2001. “Tropical Underdevelopment.” Working Paper W8119. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Sachs, J. D. 2003. “Institutions Don’t Rule: Direct Effects of Geography on per Capita Income.” Working Paper W9490. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Sachs, J. D. and A. Warner. 1995. “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995(1): 1–118. Sala-I-Martin, X. X. 1997. “I Just Ran Two Million Regressions.” American Economic Review 87(2): 178–83. Summers, R. and A. Heston. 1991. “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comparisons, 1950–88.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2): 327–68. Svensson, J. 1999. “Aid, Growth and Democracy.” Economics and Politics 11(3): 275–97. Van de Walle, N. and T. A. Johnston. 1996. “Improving Aid to Africa.” Policy Essay 11. Overseas Development Council, Washington, DC. United Kingdom Department for International Development (DFID). 2000. “Eliminating World Poverty: Making Globalisation Work for the Poor.” White Paper on International Development Presented to Parliament by the Secretary of State for International Development by Command of Her Majesty, London. United States Department of State (various years). World Military Expenditures and Arms Transfers. Washington, DC. Wacziarg, R. and K. H. Welch. 2002. “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence.” Mimeo, Stanford University, Stanford, CA. Windmeijer, F. 2005. “A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Two-step GMM Estimators.” Journal of Econometrics 126: 25–51. 28 World Bank. 2003. World Development Indicators 2003 Database. Washington, DC. 29 Appendix 1. Data set construction The data set used in this study is based on that of Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004). Some variables in that set have been slightly revised. Others have been added to match the data sets of the tested regressions. The period of coverage has been pushed back to 1958 and forward to 2001 where possible. All data were collected from standard sources, expect for countries’ export price indexes, which were provided by Jan Dehn (see Dehn 2000). (See Table A1.) Following are notes on the data set construction: Revisions since Easterly, Levine, and Roodman (2004) • Some observations for inflation are completed by using wholesale inflation where consumer price inflation was unavailable. • The update of the Sachs-Warner variable is slightly revised under the influence of the independent update by Wacziarg and Welch (2002). • Some missing values for Effective Development Assistance during 1975–95, the period of the EDA data set, are filled in in the same manner as missing values outside this period already were, via a regression of EDA on Net ODA. • ICRGE now varies over time, rather than taking 1982 values throughout. Observations before 1982 are assigned 1982 values. In addition, the variable is revised in order to extend it after 1997. In 1998, the PRS Group stopped reporting two of ICRGE’s original components, Expropriation Risk and Repudiation of Government Contracts. So these were dropped entirely from the variable, leaving Corruption, Bureaucratic Quality, and Rule of Law. On annual data, the revised ICRGE has a 0.97 correlation with the original. • Some missing values for ethno-linguistic fractionalization are filled in from Roeder 30 (2001). Expansion of period • Data was collected where available for 1958–2001. • The Collier and Dehn shocks variables are only updated to 1997 because the underlying data on export prices in Dehn (2000) cease in 1997. • The Guillaumont and Chauvet environment variable is not updated, for lack of underlying data on its four components. • The 1998–2001 values for the updated Sachs-Warner variable are based on 1998 data only. Currency Data International, the long-time source of black market premium data, which is one component of Sachs-Warner, shut down in 1999. Table A2 documents the changes in sample that the new data set brings to the tested regressions. Table A1. Construction of Data Set Variable Per-capita GDP growth Initial GDP per capita Code GDPG Data source World Bank 2003 Notes LGDP Summers and Heston 1991, updated using GDPG Ethno-linguistic fractionalization, 1960 Assassinations/ capita Political instability, lagged Institutional quality ETHNF Roeder 2001 ASSAS Banks 2002 Natural logarithm of GDP/capita for first year of period; constant 1985 dollars Probability that two randomly chosen individuals differ ethnically Assassinations/capita PINSTAB Banks 2002 ICRGE PRS Group’s IRIS III data set (see Knack and Keefer 1995) M2/GDP, lagged one period Sub-Saharan Africa East Asia M2–1 World Bank 2003 SSA World Bank 2003 EASIA Simple average of ASSAS and revolutions/year Revised. Computed as the average of the three components still reported after 1997, dropping two. Codes nations in the southern Sahara as sub-Saharan Dummy for China, Indone- 31 sia, South Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, and Thailand Central America Franc zone CENTAM FRZ Egypt Budget surplus EGYPT BB Inflation INFL World Bank 2003; IMF 2003 Sachs-Warner, updated SACW Positive and negative shock POSSHOCK NEGSHOCK Sachs and Warner 1995; Easterly, Levine, and Roodman 2004; Wacziarg and Welch 2002 Dehn 2000 Effective Development Assistance/real GDP AID Chang, FernandezArias, and Serven 1998; OECD-DAC 2002; IMF 2003; World Bank 2003; Summer and Heston 1991 Net Overseas Development Assistance/real GDP Net Overseas Development Assistance/nominal GDP Dummy for end of civil conflict in previous period Tropical area fraction Population Population growth Mean years of secondary schooling among ODAPPPGDP OECD-DAC 2002; IMF 2003; World Bank 2003; Summer and Heston, 1991 OECD-DAC 2002; World Bank 2003 ODAXRGDP World Bank 2003 Burnside and Dollar 2000 World Bank 2003; IMF 2003 POSTCONFLICT1 Collier and Hoeffler 2004 TROPICAR LPOP POPG Gallup and Sachs 1999 World Bank 2003 World Bank 2003 SYR Barro and Lee 2000 Codes African nations in the CFA franc zone World Bank primary source. Additional values extrapolated from IMF, using series 80 and 99b (local-currency budget surplus and GDP) log (1 + inflation). World Bank primary source. Wholesale price inflation from IMF used to fill gaps Extended to 1998. Slightly revised pre-1993. Shocks are % price index changes. “Shock” threshold country-specific. Reconstructed based on underlying index data for 1957–97 Available values for 1975– 95 from Chang, FernandezArias, and Serven. Missing values extrapolated based on regression of EDA on Net ODA. Converted to 1985 dollars with World Import Unit Value index from IMF, series 75. GDP computed like LGDP above Like AID exception using net ODA from OECD-DAC log (population) 32 those over 25 Arms imports/total imports, lagged ARMS-1 U.S. Department of State, various years All variables aggregated over time using arithmetic averages. 33 Table A2. Overview of Differences in Regression Samples, Original and Expanded Data Sets Regression Lost in expanded data set Burnside & Dollar Somalia, Tanzania Collier & Dehn ““ Collier & Dollar, Collier & Hoeffler None Hansen & Tarp Somalia Dalgaard, Hansen, and Tarp None Gained in expanded data set Burkina Faso, Bulgaria, China, Cyprus, Hungary, Iran, Jordan, Myanmar, Papua New Guinea, Poland, Republic of Congo, Romania, Singapore, South Africa, Uganda ““ Angola, Burkina Faso, Bulgaria, China, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Guinea, GuineaBissau, Iran, Jordan, Liberia, Mongolia, Mozambique, Myanmar, Namibia, Oman, Papua New Guinea, Poland, Republic of Congo, Romania, Somalia, Suriname, Uganda Angola, Burundi, Benin, Burkina Faso, Barbados, Bulgaria, Central African Republic, Chad, China, Cyprus, Hungary, Iran, Jordan, Mauritania, Mauritius, Mozambique, Myanmar, Nepal, Papua New Guinea, Poland, Republic of Congo, Romania, Rwanda, Singapore, South Africa, Uganda Bangladesh, Czech Republic, GuineaBissau, Singapore, South Africa, Tanzania Guillaumont & None None Chauvet Source: Author’s analysis based on sources described in the text. Study period Original Expanded 1970–93 1970– 2001 1974–93 1974–97 1974–97 1974– 2001 1978–93 ““ 1974–97 ““ 1970–93 1970–93 34 Appendix 2. Partial scatters of growth against variables of interest Each figure below is a partial scatter of GDP/capita growth versus a variable of interest in the context of a tested regression. The figures correspond to OLS and 2SLS results of table 6 in the main text. Data points are labeled by ISO three-letter codes and the last two digits of the starting year of the period. Outliers are marked separately, and two partial regression lines are shown, one for the full sample, one for the sample excluding outliers. Note that the second line in each graph is not the best fit to the non-outlier data points as plotted. Deleting observations causes the estimated coefficients to shift and all remaining data points in the partial scatter to move. The second line is the best fit to the data points in their post-exclusion positions, which are not shown. 35 Figure A1. B&D regression 5/OLS: Partial scatter of GDP/capita growth versus aid×policy Original data GAB74 GDP/capita Growth -5 0 5 10 CMR78 ZMB86 ZMB90 SYR74 DOM70 EGY82 NGA70 PRY78 EGY74 GAB70BRA70 ECU70 MEX78 SYR90 SYR78 LKA82 NGA90 PAK82 ARG90 MLI86 KEN70 EGY78 KOR86TTO78 BOL82 PAK78 URY86 BRA86 IDN90 SEN82 URY78 KOR82 CMR82 SLV90 THA86 NGA74 DOM86 NGA86 PAK86 LKA90 ARG74 TUR90 IND86 KEN86 ETH86 MAR82 SOM74 MAR74 NIC74 TUN82 CMR74 CHL90KOR90 GAB82 THA90 IDN78 SLE78 IND82 ZWE82 GUY74 PAK90 PRY74 PER78 HTI78 NER78 NGA82 BRA82ARG82 ZAR82 GMB74 GTM70 COL78 IDN86 TZA82 ZWE86 GTM74 GAB90 IDN82 KEN78 CHL86 TGO78 SLV82 MWI82 CRI70 ZAR70 CHL78 LKA78 GMB82 MYS90 URY74PHL78 KOR74 BRA74 ARG86 BOL90 COL70 LKA86 MEX70 COL82 TTO74 SLV74 GHA78 COL90 GHA70 VEN90 TZA86 ARG70 PHL86 COL86 SLE86 PHL74 GHA86 KOR70 PER90 DOM78 URY90 LKA74 MAR78 TUN90 THA82 SEN74 HND78 HND86 PRY70 SLE90 EGY86 SLE70 KEN82 BOL74 SYR70 IND90 DOM74 PER70 DZA74 GUY78 MYS78 PHL70GHA90 GTM78 HND70 ZAR86 PER74 TGO74 HND74 IDN74 MEX82 ZMB70 HND90 DZA70 ARG78 HND82 BRA78 PER86 SLV70 PRY86 MDG86 TGO86 HTI74 PAK70 GHA82 GUY70 NIC82 CRI90 DOM82 MAR86 CRI74 MEX74 GTM86 ZWE90 SLE82 ECU82 GTM90 KOR78 SLV86 BRA90 DOM90 IDN70 COL74 MWI78 MYS82 ZMB78 IND78 PAK74 GAB86 HTI82 ECU90 TTO70 HTI70 TGO82 JAM82 THA78 PER82 ECU78 IND74 LKA70 MWI90 EGY90 MAR70 ECU74 ECU86 MYS70 KEN74 VEN74 MEX90 GMB78 ZMB82 BOL78 GUY86 NIC70 CRI86 MYS86 KEN90 MWI86 CRI82 BOL70 TUN86 BOL86 SEN70 SLE74 CRI78 VEN70 SOM78 URY70 ZAR78 GUY82 ZMB74 VEN86 HTI86 PRY82 MYS74 GTM82 THA70 CHL70 PRY90 GMB70 MDG90 JAM78 CIV78 MDG70 NER74 THA74 NGA78 MEX86 PHL90 VEN82 TTO82 MAR90 SYR86 SEN78 IND70 CHL82 MDG74 CMR86 CHL74 PHL82 GHA74 ZAR74 URY82 SLV78 VEN78 TTO86 JAM74 BWA78 BWA82 BWA86 -10 CMR90 GAB78 NIC78 ETH82 -10 -5 Non-outliers Outliers 0 Aid*Policy 5 10 Fit to all data, coef = 0.19, t = 2.61, N = 270 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.05, t = -0.45, N = 263 10 Expanded sample GDP/capita Growth -5 0 5 SYR74 NGA70MMR98 GAB70 CMR78 PRY78 BWA86 EGY74 DOM70 TGO94 BWA78 PNG90 SYR78 IRN90 CMR82 EGY82 CHN94 MEX78 BRA70 CHN90 BOL82 BWA82 KEN70 IRN82 URY86 KOR86 TTO78 SYR90 CHN98 CHL90 BWA74 CYP82 LKA90 BWA98 UGA94 UGA86 TUR90 CYP78 SEN98 CYP86 MAR74 ZWE78 PAK82 UGA90 THA86 PAK78 URY78 CHN86 URY90 ZWE94 BGR98 EGY78 LKA82 MLI86 MMR94 IND98 NGA90 KOR82 MLI98 ARG74 PER94 CHL86 MYS90 IND94 NGA86 CHL94 TTO74 SEN82 THA90 IDN90 CMR74 GHA98 MWI90 IND86 DOM98 MAR82 TUR82 POL94 TUN70 SGP70 BRA94 PER90 GTM78 IND82 PRY74 NGA74 IRN98 HUN98 KOR90 CMR98 ETH94 CYP98 IDN78 UGA98 GMB74 PAK86 TGO78 TUR86 URY94 PAK90 ETH86 MMR90 BRA82 KEN86 LKA78 NGA98 GTM70 URY74 NIC98 MEX98 VEN90 KEN78 SEN94 TUN98 HTI78 COG98 LKA94 DOM86 IND90 MYS94 ARG94 IDN86 NIC74 CHL78 POL98 DZA98 DZA70 BFA94 TUR74 SLE78 TZA98 TUN78 BRA74 TGO74 LKA86 GTM74 MWI82 TTO82 MMR78 ZMB98 MMR82 BFA82 COL90 GHA86 UGA82 GTM90 TUR94 TTO94 TUN90 PER78 ZAR82 CRI70 COL78 GMB82 KOR94 COL94 KOR74 TUN74 COL86 COL70 ZAR94 DOM94 PRY86 MDG98 GAB82 ETH98 TUN82 IDN70 CRI98 SGP86 IDN94 LKA98 EGY98 PHL86 GHA90 CIV94 CYP90 ZAF98 GHA70 ECU70 PRY70 IDN82 ZWE86 EGY90 GAB90 JAM90 ARG78 HND90 MLI94 SLE82 PAK98 DZA74 ARG70 BOL90 GMB78 ZAR86 SGP90 MEX90 MEX70 ROM94 SGP78 SYR70 CRI90 SEN74 BFA98 BWA94 EGY86 BFA90 SYR98 GHA78 MEX94 ZWE82 PHL78 KOR98 BFA74 PHL74 TZA90 SLE70 THA94 SYR94 IDN74 KOR70 HUN86 ZMB70 COL82 PHL70 NER78 PAK94 TGO86 NGA94 GHA94 BRA78 MAR86 ZAR70 BFA86 THA82 IRN94 CYP94 HND78 SLE86 GTM86 GTM94 KEN82 HND86 PAK70 TTO70 TUN94 BRA98 BOL74 DOM74 LKA74 DZA94 HTI74 MEX82 EGY94 SGP94 MAR98 MMR74 ETH90 GTM98 HND70 BOL94 ZAF94 COG90 ZWE90 HND74 MYS78 BWA90 CRI74 MAR78 MEX74 ECU86 HTI98 ZMB78 DOM78 HUN94 THA78 MAR70 PAK74 BOL70 GHA82 BFA78 KEN74 VEN94 NGA82 ECU90 PER70 VEN74 PER74 CHL98 KEN90KEN94 TUR70 MEX86 ECU74 NIC82 ROM98 COL74 CRI86 ECU98 KOR78 SLV98 HND82 SLV70 IND74 TZA94 PER82 MDG86 BOL86 VEN86 ZMB82 VEN70 GAB86 ECU94 HTI70 MYS86 DOM82 CIV98 COL98 JAM82 MLI90 SGP82 IND78 PRY90 BOL98 URY70 TUR98 CRI94 TTO90 MYS70 MWI78 ECU78 JOR98 TUR78 CMR94 MWI86 KEN98 HND98ZAR98 HND94 SLE98 THA70 ZMB74 DOM90 MYS82 NIC70 MAR94 THA74 NER74 PHL94 TGO82 JAM98 PNG82 MDG94 CIV78 ZAR78 SEN70 MYS74 SLE74 TUN86 BGR94 CHL74 GMB70 LKA70 HTI82 BOL78 JOR90 URY98 ZAF90 PER98 JAM78 CHL70 PRY94 VEN98 ARG98 MDG90 COG94 CRI82 CIV86 PNG86 PRY82 JAM94 PNG98 CRI78 ECU82 HTI86 SYR86 MAR90 PHL98 PNG78 MMR70 TGO98 SGP98 PRY98 PNG94 SGP74 GHA74 JOR94 GTM82 MYS98 SLE90 THA98 ETH82 CHL82 IND70 CIV82 VEN82 SEN78 CIV90 HTI94 MDG70 BFA70 PHL90 ZAR90 ZAR74 TTO86 CMR86 VEN78 NGA78 MDG74 HTI90 IDN98PHL82 URY82 IRN86 JAM74 ROM90 GAB78 MMR86 HUN90 CMR90 TGO90 JOR86 SLE94 -10 NIC78 IRN78 -4 -2 Non-outliers Outliers 0 Aid*Policy 2 4 Fit to all data, coef = -0.04, t = -0.23, N = 436 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.27, t = -1.33, N = 426 36 Figure A2. Collier & Dehn regression: Partial scatter of GDP/capita growth vs. Δaid×neg. shock GDP/capita Growth -5 0 5 10 Original data CMR78 SYR86 GMB90 GAB74 EGY82 PRY78 SYR74 BWA78 EGY74 MEX78 SYR90 NGA86 NGA90 BWA82 ARG90 PAK82 TTO78 SEN82 SLE78 SLV90BOL82 PAK78 LKA82 KOR86 URY78 CMR82 KOR82 ARG74 PAK86 IDN90 GAB82 BWA86 GMB82 URY86 BRA86 NIC74 LKA90 GUY74 KEN86 IDN86 TZA82 ETH86 TUR90 ZWE82 NGA74 TGO78 MAR82 TUN82 PRY74 CHL90 KEN78 GAB90 THA86 IND82 MWI82 CMR74 GHA78 HTI78 IND86 GTM74 ZAR82 PER78 THA90 BRA74 PER74 URY74 KOR90 NGA82 BRA82 KOR74 BOL74 CHL78 GMB74 COL78 PAK90 LKA78 ZWE86 DOM86 NER78 IDN78 SLV82 SYR78 TTO74 GUY90 MAR74 IDN82 GAB86 ARG86 CHL86 TZA86 PHL78 EGY78 EGY86 ARG82 MYS90 LKA74 SLV74 COL82 ZMB74 HND86 COL86 VEN90 GHA90 DOM74 BOL90 PHL74 LKA86 GTM78 DOM78 ZMB86 GHA86 SLE90 COL90 MAR78 GUY78 HND78 URY90 TUN90 HND90 PER90 CRI90 ZMB90GMB78 THA82 GTM90 PHL86 MWI78 TGO86 HND82 ZMB78 HND74 MEX74 NIC82 BRA78 MYS78 ZWE90 SLE82 MEX82 TGO82 CRI74 IND90 GTM86 MWI90 MDG86 PRY86 GHA82 ARG78 ZAR86 DOM82 HTI74 PAK74 COL74 VEN86 ECU82 KOR78 KEN82 TUN86 MYS86 ECU86 SLE86 MYS82 ZMB82 VEN74 IND74 PER86 SOM78 IDN74 DOM90 HTI82 CRI86 MAR86 SLE74 IND78 ECU90 ECU74 THA78 BRA90 ECU78 KEN90 PER82 EGY90 MSEN74 EX90 CIV78 BOL78 CRI82 CHL74 CRI78 NIC86MEX86 JAM82 DZA74 MDG90 MYS74 ZAR74 KEN74 PRY82 THA74 JAM78 GTM82 MWI86 PRY90 HTI86 GUY82 SEN78 ZAR78 NGA78 TTO82 VEN82 CMR86 GHA74 CHL82 GUY86 TTO86 MAR90 TGO74 PHL90 NER74 GMB86 MDG74 PHL82 URY82 SLV78 VEN78 JAM74 MLI86 SOM74 NIC90 SLV86 BOL86 -10 CMR90 NIC78 GAB78 ETH82 -50 0 50 Change in Aid*Negative Shock Non-outliers Outliers 100 Fit to all data, coef = 0.04, t = 3.17, N = 234 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.06, t = -1.33, N = 224 GAB74 SYR86 -10 -5 GDP/capita Growth 0 5 10 15 Expanded sample NGA70 JOR78 DOM70 PRY78 ARG90 TGO94 CMR78 GAB70 SYR74 BWA78 BWA86 PNG90 CMR82 EGY82 BRA70 BWA82 CHN94 BWA74 NGA86 CHN90 EGY74 KEN70 MEX78 IRN90 CHL90 IRN82 PAK82 SYR90 CYP82 LKA90 MMR94 GUY94 ZWE78 PAK78 TTO78 ZWE94 UGA90 TUR90 ETH94 CYP78 KOR86 GMB74 MMR82 IND82 MLI86 PER94 IND94 GTM78 KOR82 BRA86 SLE78 UGA86 URY86 CHL94 SEN82 URY78 LKA82 POL94 NGA90 PAK86 TUN70 CHN86 IDN86 BOL82 MWI90 MAR74 MAR82 CYP86 TUR82 THA86 URY90 CHL86 SYR78 SGP70 IDN90 IND86 MMR78 MMR90 CMR74 PRY74 THA90 LKA78 TTO74 GTM90 TGO78 BFA82 MWI82 HTI78 ETH86 BRA94 BFA94 CHL78 IDN78 LKA94 ARG74 BRA90 GTM70 KEN78 EGY78 PAK90 MYS90 SEN94 NGA74 IND90 URY94 DOM94 COL86 ZAR82 KEN86 ZMB90 KOR90 BRA82 NIC90 DZA70 EGY86 DOM86 BFA90 PER90 VEN90 ARG94 GMB82 BRA74 TUR74 COL94 COL90 CRI70 TUN90 COL78 NIC74 UGA82 COL70 HND90 CRI90 BOL74 PRY86 URY74 UGA94 ECU70 MLI94 TUR94 TUN82 TUR86 GHA90 CIV94 GHA86 MYS94 GHA78 BFA86 GTM74 IDN70 PRY70 TUN78 KOR74 ROM94 SGP86 TTO94 ARG86 PER78 IDN94 IDN82 KOR94 ZAR94 LKA86 BWA94 ZMB86 SLE82 GHA70 JAM90 EGY90 MMR74 ZWE82 EGY94 GTM94 TTO82 MEX86 TGO74 JOR82 BOL90 GMB78 GAB82 GTM86 KOR70 PER74 SLE70 NGA94 COL82 PAK94 PER86 TZA90 HND86 TUN94 SGP78 ECU86 MEX70 VEN86 MEX94 GHA94 ZWE86 SYR70 CYP90 NER78 ZAR70 HND78 BFA78 MEX90 PHL86 HTI74 ZAR86 HND70 THA82 DZA94 SYR94 ZMB74 ETH90 LKA74 DOM74 ARG70 ARG82 ZMB70 PAK70 DOM78 BRA78 BFA74 KEN94 BOL94 GAB86 IRN94 HUN94 GAB90 KEN82 ARG78 THA94 HND74 PHL78 BWA90 CYP94 MYS86 ZAF94 MAR86 PHL70 DZA74 TGO86 SGP90 CRI86 GHA82 MLI90 MAR70 ZWE90 BOL70 TUN86 IND74 PAK74 HTI70 PHL74 THA78 SEN74 CRI74 MAR78 IDN74 TUR70 IND78 MYS78 ZMB78 HND82 HUN86 DOM82 NGA82 NIC86CHL74 ECU74 KEN90 SLV70 CMR94 MEX82 BOL86 MWI78 MDG86 ECU94 TTO70 COG90 SGP94 JOR74 MDG94 ECU90 PER70 MEX74 COL74 TUN74 ECU78 CRI94 KOR78 GMB70 NIC82 PRY90 VEN94 ZMB82 KEN74 MAR94 SLE86 CIV78 TGO82 MYS70 HTI82 GMB90 VEN74 PER82 DOM90 SGP82 TUR78 GMB86 PNG82 PHL94 ZMB94 THA70 HND94 PRY94 LKA70 VEN70 JAM82 URY70 MDG90 SEN70 THA74 NIC70 MMR70 SGP74MWI86 SLE74 JAM94 MYS82 ZAR78 ETH82 TTO90 CRI82 PRY82 JOR90 BOL78 MYS74 ECU82 JAM78 TZA94 COG94 CRI78 MAR90 BGR94 PNG94 CHL70 JOR94 ZAR74 CHL82 HTI86 NER74 PNG78 IND70 PNG86 GTM82 NIC94 CIV86 TTO86 BFA70 MDG70 CIV82 HTI94 IRN86 SLE90 SEN78 GHA74 CIV90 VEN82 CMR86 HTI90 MDG74 PHL90 NGA78 VEN78 URY82 PHL82 ZAR90 ROM90 JAM74 MMR86 TGO90 HUN90 CMR90 GAB78 SLE94 JOR86 NIC78 IRN78 -50 Non-outliers Outliers 0 50 Change in Aid*Negative Shock 100 Fit to all data, coef = 0.03, t = 3.01, N = 391 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.10, t = -1.15, N = 372 37 Figure A3. Collier & Dollar regression: Partial scatter of GDP/capita growth vs. aid×policy 20 Original data GDP/capita Growth 0 10 GAB74 SDN94 SDN74TGO94 BWA82BWA78 PAN90 PRY78 CMR78 NIC94 SYR90 BHS82 BWA86 SYR74 CMR82 EGY82 BHS78 SDN90 TTO78 ARG90 ETH86 EGY74 GUY94 MEX78 GUY90 MLI74 CHL78 SLV90 THA86 ZWE78 JAM86 DOM86 HTI78 MLI86 BWA74 IDN78 KOR82 KOR86 THA90 PER94 IDN90 PAN78 SEN82 SYR78 CHL90 NGA90 CHL86 ETH94 DOM94 NIC74 DOM74 VEN90 DOM78 KEN86 SLE86 SLE78 ECU74 PAK78 LKA82 PAK82 DOM82 PRY86 MAR82 ECU78 GTM90 TGO78 HND86 CRI90 NGA86 ZAR82 PRY74 DZA82 BGD78 GMB82 HTI74 MWI90 EGY78 URY78 SLV82 LKA90 URY86 SDN86 URY90 COL90 IND94 ETH90 IDN94 HUN86 CMR74 MWI82 HUN82 ECU90 IDN74 NER78 MWI94 GAB94 COL86 BOL74 GTM74 ZWE94 MLI82 SLV86 BOL90 IDN82 MYS90 BGD82 BRA86 JAM90 CHL94 CIV94 BRA94 TZA90 IND82 GTM78 HND90 ZMB86 CIV74 THA94 GMB74 NGA74 KOR90 THA82 BGD90 BWA90 PER78 EGY86 TTO82 TZA86 SEN94 TUN90 HUN94 GHA90 CRI86 DOM90 NER86 IDN86 SLV94 NGA94 IND86 MEX90 ZWE86 ZWE82 SLV74 MAR94 KOR94 PHL86 GAB90 MLI94 COL78 BRA82 MAR74 MYS94 GAB82 PRY90 NIC82 BOL86 BRA74 ZAR86 MAR86 PER90 KEN78 GUY74 HTI82 SEN86 ECU82 SDN82 GTM86 URY94 PAK86 GHA86 COL94 URY74 GTM94 TUR94 PAK90 SGP78 ZAR78 PAN82 MWI74 KEN94 HND74 GUY86 EGY90 KEN82 EGY94 BWA94 GHA94 ECU94 HND78 LKA78 COL82 SLE82 MDG82 KOR74 SLE74 NER94 MYS78 THA78 PER86 HND82BOL94 MYS86 SEN74 BGD74 IND90 TZA94 TUN78 SEN90 GMB86 GHA78 DZA74 LKA94 LKA74 ZAF94 BRA78 TTO94 MDG86 NGA82 THA74 PRY94 BGD94 GMB90 GMB78 ARG74 MLI90 TGO86 TUN82 TGO74 CHL82 SGP82 MYS82 TGO82 ARG82 LKA86 ZMB90 KEN90 HTI86 TUN74 GHA82 BRA90 ARG86 BOL82 DZA78 CMR94 ARG94 PHL94 BOL78 ZWE90 NER74 BGD86 TTO90 ETH82 PHL78 MAR78 CRI82 MEX82 GUY78 PAN94 BHS86 ZMB78 TUN94 JAM82 GTM82 SYR82 MEX74 ECU86 MLI78 NER90 IND78 IND74 CRI94 ARG78 PER74 ZMB82 ZAR94 MDG94 PAK74 PAK94 JAM94 PHL74 MDG90 CIV86 CRI74 VEN86 GAB86 MWI86 CIV90 SYR86 MWI78 HTI94 NIC90 MDG78 MAR90 PER82 COL74ZAR74 DZA94 MYS74 MDG74 PRY82 MEX94 JAM78 MEX86 KOR78 ZMB74 HND94 KEN74 HTI90 VEN94 PHL90 PAN74 CRI78 SDN78 HUN90 GUY82 GMB94 BHS90 SGP74 TUN86 CHL74 CIV78 SEN78 CMR86 PAN86 DZA90 DZA86 SLE90 CIV82 NIC86 SLE94 NGA78 NER82 GHA74 TTO86 PHL82 CMR90 URY82 GAB78 JAM74 SLV78 TGO90 NIC78 ZAR90 -10 ZMB94 -15 -10 Non-outliers Outliers -5 Aid*Policy 0 5 10 Fit to all data, coef = 0.14, t = 2.15, N = 344 Fit excl. outliers, coef = 0.07, t = 1.06, N = 341 20 Expanded sample LBR98 GAB74 LBR94 GDP/capita Growth -20 0 CYP74 COG78 OMN82 COG82 SDN74 CHN82 SYR90BWA86 SDN86 PAN90 ARG90 MOZ98 PRY78 MOZ86 AGO94 BHS82 BWA82 CHN90 CMR78 SYR74 PNG90 BWA78GUY90 SDN98 TTO78 BHS78 TGO94 IRN90 MEX78 SDN90 SLV90 CMR82 EGY82 CHN94 EGY74 CHL90 SDN94 THA86 THA90 MMR90 CYP86 SOM82 AGO98 ETH86 CHL78 IDN90 MMR94 GUY94 TUR90 MOZ94 BGR98 DOM86 DOM98 CHN98 MLI74 CHN78 IDN78 JAM86 ZWE78 KOR86 HTI78 VEN90 BFA82 UGA94 NGA90 SYR78 MLI98 SUR86 ROM82 MYS90 DOM94 LKA90 CHL86 CHN86 GTM90 POL94 NIC98 AGO86 KOR82 CYP82 TTO98 PER94 PAN78 UGA90 MLI86 BWA74 CRI90 PAK78 CYP78 SOM86 SLE78 UGA86 CMR98 BWA98 DOM74 LKA82 JAM90 MWI90 NIC74 SEN82 SUR90 URY90 PAK82 PRY86 CHL94 URY86 COL90 KOR90 DOM78 SEN98 GAB94 URY78 GMB98 ETH94 MMR82 TGO78 ECU74 ZWE94 ECU78 COG98 EGY78 HTI74 NGA86 GHA98 KEN86 PRY74 MDG98 BGD90 BFA86 HND86 ZAR82 MAR82 TZA98 MMR78 IDN74 MEX90 UGA98 DOM90 ETH98 GTM74 GIN98 CYP90 GAB90 DOM82 GNB82 CMR74 MEX98 BOL90 GIN90 TUN90 GTM78 GIN94 PAK90 GIN86 BRA86 TTO82 NGA74 COL86 TUR82 URY94 TUR74 GHA90 HND90 SLV82 SLV86 GNB90 DZA82 IDN82 ECU90 IDN94 GUY74 PHL86 CIV74 IDN86 SLE82 NER98 BRA94 HUN98 NGA98 CRI98 TTO94 BFA98 NER78 GAB82 GNB94 MAR74 SGP78 ETH90 ARG94 COG90 BOL74 IND98 BGD98 MOZ90 PRY90 THA82 PAN98 BWA90 BFA90 GMB82 IND94 PER78 EGY86 MYS94 GUY86 PAK86 GMB74 ZMB86 SEN94 URY74 BGD82 BGD78 CIV94 MWI94 IND82 SLE86 GTM86 BFA74 IND90 OMN90 HUN86 EGY90 CRI86 UGA82 EGY98 SLV74 MWI82 ECU94 POL98 SLV94 LKA78 TZA90 IND86 ZAR86 TUN98 ROM94 GTM98 BGD74 BFA94 DZA98 GTM94 KOR94 HUN94 BFA78 ECU98 BRA74 TUR86 SLE74 BRA90 NGA94 COL78 MAR86 ZAR78 ZWE86 BRA82 TTO90 MYS86 LKA94 KOR98 THA78 MYS78 TUR94 GHA86 TGO74 NAM94 PER86 LKA86 TZA86 MLI94 KEN78 HND74 THA94 HND78 ROM86 OMN78 SEN90 SEN86 KOR74 EGY94 CRI94 ZWE82 PAN82 COG74 ARG74 NER86 JOR90 COL94 HUN82 MMR74 PER90 HTI98 GNB78 BWA94 CMR94 SEN74 ROM98 ZMB98 DZA74 KEN82 THA74 HTI82 LKA74 NIC82 BHS86 HND82 MLI90 BRA78 PRY94 MEX94 TZA94 SUR78 ZAF94 MAR98 SLV98 BGD94 BOL94 GMB90 NGA82 GHA78 TUN78 GHA94 MWI74 KEN90 JAM98 NAM98 VEN94 COL82 KEN94 KEN98 SLE98 PAN94 SGP82 ZWE90 BRA98 PRY98 MDG82 ARG78 MYS82 POL90 GNB86 CZE94 MDG86 ARG86 LKA98 GUY98 ZAF98 ECU86 ECU82 SDN82 NER94 CZE98 ZMB90 DZA78 PHL94 BOL98 GUY78 GMB78 TUN94 CHL82 PHL78 MEX82 BGD86 TUN74 GAB86 BOL82 MNG98 TUN82 JAM94 BOL86 HND98 HTI86 ZMB78 PAK74 MNG94 MEX74 GTM82 CIV90 ARG82 PAK98 MWI98 SYR82 TGO86 GMB86 VEN86 GAB98 BOL78 NER90 SYR86 PER74 CIV98 VEN98 NIC94 MAR90 PHL74 GHA82 MAR94 IND78 IND74 MDG90 PHL90 NER74 IRN94 CIV86 CHL98 CRI82 JAM82 LBR74 BHS90 MDG94 JOR82 MEX86 JOR98 HND94 SUR82 NIC90 KOR78 CRI74 PER82 MLI78 TGO82 ETH82 DZA94 PER98 COG86 ZMB82 PNG82 MYS74 ZAR74 PAK94 MDG78 JAM78 COL74 PRY82 ZMB74 MDG74 HTI90 PHL98 ZAR98 SLE90 SOM74 GUY82 LBR82 MAR78 LBR78 JOR94 COG94 MLI82 ROM78 SGP74 MWI86 DZA90 OMN86 TGO98 COL98 PAN74 GMB94 PNG86 KEN74 SDN78 URY98 MWI78 TUR78 CRI78 PNG78 THA98 CIV78 ZAR94 PNG98 BGR94 PAN86 NIC86 CHL74 TUR98 MYS98 TUN86 SOM90 ARG98 SEN78 DZA86 IDN98 ZWE98 TTO86 HTI94 CMR86 PNG94 NGA78 CIV82 CMR90 MMR86 GAB78 BGR90 GHA74 ROM90 GNB98 PHL82 HUN90 ZMB94 CZE90 NER82 URY82 JAM74 SOM78 TGO90 MOZ82 LBR86 SLV78 PNG74 AGO90 NIC78 ZAR90 SLE94 MNG90 JOR86 BHS74 JOR74 JOR78 -40 LBR90 -60 -40 Non-outliers Outliers -20 Aid*Policy 0 20 40 Fit to all data, coef = -0.01, t = -0.19, N = 520 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.04, t = -0.81, N = 508 38 Figure A4. Collier & Hoeffler regression: Partial scatter of GDP/capita growth vs. Postconflict 1×aid ×policy 20 Original data GDP/capita Growth 0 10 GAB74 SDN94 SDN74TGO94 BWA82BWA78 PAN90 PRY78 CMR78 NIC94 SYR90 BHS82 SYR74 BWA86 CMR82 EGY82 BHS78 SDN90 TTO78 ARG90 ETH86 EGY74 GUY94 MEX78 GUY90 MLI74 CHL78 SLV90 THA86 ZWE78 JAM86 DOM86 HTI78 MLI86 BWA74 IDN78 KOR82 KOR86 THA90 PER94 IDN90 PAN78 SEN82 SYR78 CHL90 NGA90 CHL86 ETH94 DOM94 NIC74 DOM74 VEN90 DOM78 KEN86 SLE86 SLE78 ECU74 PAK78 LKA82 PAK82 DOM82 PRY86 MAR82 ECU78 GTM90 TGO78 HND86 CRI90 NGA86 ZAR82 PRY74 DZA82 BGD78 GMB82 HTI74 MWI90 EGY78 URY78 SLV82 LKA90BOL90 URY86 SDN86 URY90 COL90 IND94 ETH90 IDN94 HUN86 CMR74 MWI82 HUN82 ECU90 IDN74 NER78 MWI94 GAB94 COL86 BOL74 GTM74 ZWE94 MLI82 SLV86 IDN82 MYS90 BGD82 BRA86 JAM90 CHL94 CIV94 BRA94 TZA90 IND82 GTM78 HND90 ZMB86 CIV74 THA94 GMB74 NGA74 KOR90 THA82 BGD90 BWA90 PER78 EGY86 TTO82 TZA86 SEN94 TUN90 HUN94 GHA90 CRI86 DOM90 NER86 IDN86 SLV94 NGA94 IND86 MEX90 ZWE86 ZWE82 SLV74 MAR94 KOR94 PHL86 GAB90 MLI94 COL78 BRA82 MAR74 MYS94 GAB82 PRY90 NIC82 BOL86 BRA74 ZAR86 MAR86 PER90 KEN78 GUY74 HTI82 SEN86 ECU82 SDN82 GTM86 URY94 PAK86 GHA86 COL94 URY74 GTM94 TUR94 PAK90 SGP78 ZAR78 PAN82 MWI74 KEN94 HND74 GUY86 EGY90 KEN82 EGY94 BWA94 GHA94 ECU94 HND78 LKA78 COL82 SLE82 MDG82 KOR74 SLE74 NER94 MYS78 THA78 PER86 HND82BOL94 MYS86 SEN74 BGD74 IND90 TZA94 TUN78 SEN90 GMB86 GHA78 DZA74 LKA94 LKA74 ZAF94 BRA78 TTO94 MDG86 NGA82 THA74 PRY94 BGD94 GMB90 GMB78 ARG74 MLI90 TGO86 TUN82 TGO74 CHL82 SGP82 MYS82 TGO82 ARG82 LKA86 ZMB90 KEN90 HTI86 TUN74 GHA82 BRA90 ARG86 BOL82 DZA78 CMR94 ARG94 PHL94 BOL78 ZWE90 NER74 BGD86 TTO90 ETH82 PHL78 MAR78 CRI82 MEX82 GUY78 PAN94 BHS86 ZMB78 TUN94 JAM82 GTM82 SYR82 MEX74 ECU86 MLI78 NER90 IND78 IND74 CRI94 ARG78 PER74 ZMB82 ZAR94 MDG94 PAK74 PAK94 JAM94 PHL74 MDG90 CIV86 CRI74 VEN86 GAB86 MWI86 CIV90 SYR86 MWI78 HTI94 NIC90 MDG78 MAR90 PER82 COL74ZAR74 DZA94 MYS74 MDG74 PRY82 MEX94 JAM78 MEX86 KOR78 ZMB74 HND94 KEN74 HTI90 VEN94 PHL90 PAN74 CRI78 SDN78 HUN90 GUY82 GMB94 BHS90 SGP74 TUN86 CHL74 CIV78 SEN78 CMR86 PAN86 DZA90 DZA86 SLE90 CIV82 NIC86 SLE94 NGA78 NER82 GHA74 TTO86 PHL82 CMR90 URY82 GAB78 JAM74 SLV78 TGO90 NIC78 ZAR90 -10 ZMB94 -15 -10 Non-outliers Outliers -5 Aid*Policy 0 5 10 Fit to all data, coef = 0.14, t = 2.15, N = 344 Fit excl. outliers, coef = 0.07, t = 1.06, N = 341 20 Expanded sample GDP/capita Growth -20 0 LBR98 GAB74 LBR94 CYP74 COG78 OMN82 COG82 SDN74 BWA86 SYR90 CHN82 SDN86 PAN90 ARG90 MOZ98 MOZ86 BWA82 PRY78 BHS82 AGO94 PNG90 CMR78 CHN90 SYR74 BWA78 TGO94 TTO78 SDN98 BHS78 GUY90 MEX78 JOR78 GUY94 SLV90 IRN90 SDN90 EGY82 EGY74 CHN94 CMR82 SDN94 CHL90 THA90 THA86 SOM82 CYP86 MMR90 AGO98 MMR94 BGR98 IDN90 CHL78 ETH86 MLI74 TUR90 MOZ94UGA90 DOM98 CHN98 DOM86 JAM86 IDN78 CHN78 HTI78 SYR78 UGA94 BFA82 ZWE78 KOR86 VEN90 NIC98 MLI98 SUR86 LKA90 DOM94 NGA90 BWA74 POL94 GTM90 ROM82 MYS90 MLI86 TTO98 CHN86 PAN78 CYP82 KOR82 CHL86 AGO86 CYP78 SOM86 PER94 CRI90 PAK78 MWI90 UGA86 DOM74 JAM90 LKA82 CMR98 BWA98 SLE78 NIC74 SEN82 SUR90 PAK82 URY90 GAB94 SEN98 DOM78 PRY86 COL90 TGO78 CHL94 URY86 KOR90 MMR82 URY78 GMB98 ECU74 ETH94 ECU78 COG98 EGY78 HTI74 HND86 ZWE94 BFA86 MDG98 GNB82 PRY74 IDN74 MAR82 MMR78 TZA98 BGD90 GHA98 KEN86 NGA86 CYP90 ZAR82 GIN90 BOL90 GIN98 UGA98 DOM82 GAB90 DOM90 MEX90 GTM74 GIN94 MEX98 GNB90 CMR74 GTM78 ETH98 GIN86 TUN90 SLV86 TTO82 PAK90 GNB94 HND90 SLV82 TUR74 TUR82 BRA86 GUY74 GHA90 URY94 PHL86 IDN82 ECU90 NGA74 COL86 IDN94 HUN98 DZA82 GAB82 IDN86 GMB82 MOZ90 NER78 TTO94 BFA98 BRA94 CIV74 NER98 CRI98 SLE82 BFA90 BOL74 ARG94 ETH90 BGD98 IND98 COG90 NGA98 MAR74 BWA90 PRY90 THA82 SGP78 SEN94 GMB74 ZMB86 EGY86 GUY86 MYS94 PER78 PAN98 MWI94 CIV94 IND94 PAK86 BGD78 BGD82 BFA74 URY74 SLE86 GTM86 EGY90 TZA90 LKA78 CRI86 POL98 OMN90 HUN86 IND82 BFA94 SLV74 MWI82 ECU94 UGA82 IND90 SLV94 BGD74 EGY98 ROM94 GTM98 BFA78 GTM94 TUN98 HUN94 ECU98 KOR94 ZAR86 IND86 DZA98 KOR98 TUR86 MLI94 SEN86 TZA86 LKA94 BRA74 LKA86 PER86 SLE74 TTO90 MYS86 ZWE86 BRA82 BRA90 TGO74 GHA86 SEN90 NAM94 TUR94 MAR86 THA78 COL78 ROM86 ZAR78 NGA94 NER86 HND74 OMN78 THA94 MYS78 JOR90 EGY94 HTI98 HND78 ARG74 COG74 KEN78 ZWE82 ZMB98 KOR74 MMR74 ROM98 CRI94 PAN82 HUN82 SEN74 CMR94 BWA94 HTI82 COL94 PER90 LKA74 SUR78 MLI90 THA74 NIC82 GMB90 HND82 DZA74 KEN82 BHS86 BOL94 TZA94 MEX94 GNB86 PRY94 BGD94 VEN94 BRA78 MWI74 GHA94 MAR98 PRY98 SLV98 KEN90 NAM98 TUN78 BRA98 JAM98 GHA78 SGP82 ZAF94 NGA82 ZMB90 GUY98 PAN94 ZWE90 ARG78 KEN94 POL90 SLE98 MYS82 COL82 KEN98 GMB78 CZE94 CZE98 LKA98 MDG86 ARG86 MDG82 NER94 GUY78 BOL98 SDN82 ECU82 ECU86 PHL94 ZAF98 MNG98 DZA78 BOL82 TUN74 HND98 BGD86 GAB86 MEX82 GMB86 MNG94 BOL86 JAM94 TUN94 PHL78 CHL82 TGO86 ZMB78 HTI86 TUN82 PAK74 MWI98 SYR82 PAK98 CIV90 GTM82 ARG82 BOL78 NER90 MEX74 SYR86 VEN98 GAB98 JOR82 PER74 CIV98 VEN86 NER74 PHL74 PHL90 JAM82 CRI82 MDG90 IND74 MAR90 NIC90 MAR94 CHL98 IND78 GHA82 CIV86 HND94 MDG94 LBR74 IRN94 SUR82 PNG82 JOR98 BHS90 MLI78 TGO82 PER82 MEX86 ZMB82 DZA94 CRI74 KOR78 PER98 JAM78 MYS74 ETH82 COG86 PAK94 ZAR74 ZMB74 PRY82 MDG78 LBR82 COL74 HTI90 PHL98 MLI82 SOM74 COG94 GUY82 MDG74 SLE90 JOR94 MAR78 LBR78 ZAR98 MWI86 PNG86 GMB94 SGP74 PAN74 COL98 ROM78 SDN78 URY98 OMN86 DZA90 TGO98 MWI78 KEN74 TUR78 PNG78 CRI78 THA98 PNG98 CIV78 BGR94 NIC86 ZAR94 TUR98 MYS98 PAN86 SEN78 CHL74 TUN86 IDN98 ARG98 SOM90 HTI94 PNG94 DZA86 TTO86 ZWE98 CMR86 NGA78 CIV82 BGR90 CMR90 GNB98 GAB78 MMR86 ZMB94 ROM90 GHA74 PHL82 HUN90 NER82 CZE90 URY82 JAM74 TGO90 SOM78 MOZ82 LBR86 SLV78 PNG74 AGO90 NIC78 SLE94 MNG90 ZAR90 JOR86 BHS74 JOR74 NIC94 GNB78 -40 LBR90 -10 0 Non-outliers Outliers 10 20 Post-conflict 1*Aid*Policy 30 40 Fit to all data, coef = 0.08, t = 1.91, N = 520 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.06, t = -0.19, N = 494 39 Figure A5. Guillaumont and Chauvet Regression 1.2: Partial Scatter of GDP/Capita Growth versus Aid×Environment 4 Original data GDP/capita Growth -2 0 2 GMB82 GMB70 IND82 THA82 TTO70 DOM70 KOR82 PRY70 PAK82 ECU70 GTM82 GHA82 IDN70 MWI82 BOL82 SLV82 SYR82 EGY82 MYS82 DOM82 IDN82 HND82KOR70COG82 BRA70RWA70 KEN82 VEN82 COL82 JAM82 PAK70 PRY82 CYP82 HND70 URY82 MYS70 CRI82 MUS70 SLE70 CHL82 GUY82 MUS82 SLE82 MEX82 ARG82 PHL82 GUY70 PHL70 TGO82 VEN70 RWA82 BRA82 URY70 COL70BOL70 ECU82 TTO82 THA70 CHL70 LKA82 MMR82SLV70 GHA70 NIC82 -4 SEN82 CMR82 JOR82 ZAR82 -15 -10 Non-outliers Outliers -5 0 5 Aid*Environment, instrumented values 10 Fit to all data, coef = -0.15, t = -1.79, N = 68 Fit excl. outliers, coef = -0.11, t = -1.96, N = 67 40