Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Lukas Kornher and Matthias Kalkuhl Center for Development Research, Bonn ZEF-IFPRI Volatility Workshop, Bonn 8th July 2014 Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Background and motivation After global food crisis in 2007/2008 - discussion on how to prevent renewed crisis through food reserves (von Braun and Torero, 2009; Sarris et al., 2011) Number of countries (plan to) introduce/ expand public stockholding and market intervention (Ghana, Ethiopia, Guatemala) after 2008 Proposal for West African food reserve among ECOWAS countries with support from G20 Why stocks? Import dependency creates reliance on free markets (vs. ad-hoc trade policies; e.g. during global food crisis) Additional imports need time for shipping (appr. 30 days to West Africa) Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Food reserves - overview In classical storage model: optimal stocks increase with production variability (Gustafson, 1958; Williams and Wright, 1991) Risk pooling - regional stocks as an insurance against production shocks General observations: Importance of clear release rule International commodity agreements became popular after WWII - UNCTAD focus on tropical commodity - existing regional reserves: ASEAN+3 and SAARC (seldom intervention) Concentration on one or two major commodities Physical plus financial reserve Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Institutional environment in West Africa UEMAO and ECOWAS are among most advanced political and economical organizations (free trade, common external tariff) High import dependency in the region for rice Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Contribution of this study Quantification costs and benefits of regional cooperation Provide a simple framework that is easily applicable to different regions No complex modeling of behavioral responses of the private sector (e.g. crowding out) Focus on consumption stabilization Simulate stock levels for West African countries under different storage rules Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Fixed reserve e.g. emergency or virtual reserve Allow deviation from expected production by certain % Required stocks are the difference between largest historic shortfall and %-threshold Qt S ∗ = (1 − %/100)E[Qt ] − Qt if min [ E[Q ] t] Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Fixed reserve Source: Own elaboration based on FAOSTAT. Source: Own elaboration based on FAOSTAT. 7 production shortfall of more than 5% since 1980 8 production shortfall of more than 5% since 1980 Allowing for 5% production shortfall required stocks are 73,686mt Allowing for 5% production shortfall required stocks are 258,757mt 73,686mt = 5.96% of 2012 production 258,757mt = 9.4% of 2012 production Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Fixed reserve Source: Own elaboration based on FAOSTAT. 7 production shortfall of more than 5% since 1980 if countries had cooperated Allowing for 5% production shortfall required stocks are 294,735mt compared to a combined total of 332,443mt 294,735mt = 7.8% of 2012 production In order to be pareto-improving both countries must not stock more than in isolation Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Figure: CV of cereal production instability in the region Source: Authors’ computation based on FAOSTAT. √ CV = CV2 ( P 1/n Qi ) = P P (Qt −E[Qt ])2 µ with E[Qt ]: HP trend value s2i CV2 (Qi ) + 2 Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination PP si sj rij CV(Qi )CV(Qj ) References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Fixed reserve - results Table: Results for allowed production shortfall of 5% country Benin Burkina Faso Cameroon Cape Verde Chad Cote d’Ivoire Gambia, the Ghana Guinea Guinea-Bissau Liberia Mali Mauritania Niger Nigeria Senegal Sierra Leone Togo Σ Region Public stocks as of 2013 planned in 2020 Regional reserve per capita cereal production in 2012 % share in regional production 2010-2012 production variability no. of shortfalls required stocks stock-to-use ratio 127.7 214.9 94.8 24.2 138.6 71.7 111.3 83.2 166.7 117.2 53.2 227.3 53.6 262.4 158.6 116.3 97.8 141.5 147.0 3.8 11.8 8.1 0.0 6.4 3.4 0.6 7.3 6.7 0.5 0.5 15.6 0.5 13.1 63.1 3.7 2.4 2.8 100 - 7.6 11.8 6.2 52.9 21.3 3.9 19.9 10.2 2.8 9.1 11.7 10.2 19.6 15.0 6.9 21.4 13.5 6.3 5.6 7 10 5 15 13 2 10 8 0 9 10 11 11 9 4 14 9 7 5 73,686 447,650 132,269 5,693 756,897 58,845 56,712 258,757 0 16,148 18,130 247,780 24,555 431,413 2,836,943 435,668 63,088 38,316 5,902,550 3,091,356 0.07 0.13 0.06 0.09 0.40 0.03 0.17 0.11 0.00 0.08 0.04 0.08 0.04 0.13 0.12 0.20 0.08 0.07 0.12 0.06 Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination 227,000 841,000 411,000 Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Fixed reserve Figure: Correlation of production shocks in the region Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Fixed reserve Figure: % of reduction of production variability from country’s joining the reserve union Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Linear stocking rule Ct = Qt + ∆St with ∆St = St−1 − St St−1 = α(St + Qt ) 1 Define desired level of consumption variability (CV) - e.g. 5% 2 Calculate optimal α using production variability (CV) - e.g. 7% r 1−α CV(Qt ) 1+α α = 0.32 CV(Ct ) = 3 Compute required stocks level: S ∗ = αE[Qt ] (1−α) E.g. E[Qt ] = 3,000,000 mt → S ∗ = 1,410,000 mt Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Summary: Benefits Regional stockholding reduces the level of required stocks massively Joint variability of production is lower than individual variability (even if production is positively correlated) (Koester, 1986) BUT: required stocks automatically reduce by adding more and more countries (→ world-wide reserve) BUT: stock levels should be interpreted cautiously NO trade NO private storage NO transportation costs Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Costs of economic integration It is not possible to implement “country-specific policies contingent on countries’ preferences” (Ruta, 2005) Heterogenous preferences with respect to the level of consumption stabilization reduce welfare Cost of joining regional stockholding regime is the difference in preferences αi − αmedian (Alesina et al., 2005) e.g. Guinea and Cote d’Ivoire have no interest to join at 5 % Preferences are not observable but approximable Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Existing reserve and buffer scheme in the region Ghana (both buffer and reserve) since 2009 - 70,000 mt Mali (both buffer and reserve) Burkina Faso (both buffer and reserve) Nigeria (strategic reserve only) - 150,000 mt Mauritania (strategic reserve only) Niger (strategic reserve only) Chad (strategic reserve only) Source: Own research. Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Stock to use ratio and propensity to store Source: FAO Giews. Source: FAO Giews. Note: Importing countries have low levels of production. Production variability seems to play a role for level of stocks Suprisingly!? countries with food reserves have lower stocks Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Summary: Costs Production variability largely differs among West African countries (Sahel vs. coastal) Stock data suggests heterogeneity of preferences with respect to consumption stability BUT: It is key to include countries with low instability Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Conclusion and next steps Large benefits from risk sharing in form of storage cooperation Costs of economic integration are difficult to quantify Importance to clearly discuss individual contributions and releases to/from the reserve Discuss distribution channels in case of emergency Next steps: Rule for contribution to regional reserve - introduce costs of joining a union Price analysis: where do domestic price shocks come frome? SVAR - international vs. regional vs. national component Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Thank you very much for your attention! Comments? Questions? Suggestions? For more information: lukas.kornher@uni-bonn.de http://www.zef.de/volatility.html Financial support of the Federal Ministry of Development and Economic Cooperation (BMZ) is gratefully acknowledged. Special thanks to GIEWS in FAO for helpful comments and provision of data. Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Qt = E[Q] + (1) Ct = Qt + ∆St with ∆St = St−1 − St (2) St−1 = α(St + Qt ) (3) ∆St = α(St + Qt ) − St (4) = (α − 1)St + αQt (5) Ct = Qt − αQt + (1 − α)St (6) = (1 − α)Qt + (1 − α)St (7) (8) In steady state E[St−1 ] = α(E[St ] + E[Qt ]) E[St−1 ] = E[St ] = S ∗ S∗ = Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination αE[Qt ] (1 − α) (9) (10) (11) Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion Var(Ct ) = (E[Ct ] − Ct )2 References (12) 2 (13) 2 (14) = (1 − α) [Var(St + Qt )] = (1 − α) [Var(St ) + Var(Qt ) + 2Cov](St + Qt ) Qt i.i.d. and St depends on Qt−1 only → Cov(St + Qt ) = 0 = (1 − α)2 [α2 Var(St−1 ) + (1 + α2 )Var(Qt )] (15) 2 (16) α Var(Qt ) (1 − α2 ) (17) ! = (1 − α) [Var(St ) + Var(Qt )] 2 Var(St ) = (18) Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion α2 Var(Qt ) (1 − α2 ) α2 Var(Ct ) = (1 − α)2 [ Var(Qt ) + Var(Qt )] (1 − α2 ) 1−α = Var(Qt ) (1 + α) Var(St ) = Var(Qt ) = 1/n X (E[Qt ] − Qt )2 E[Qt ] : Trendvalue from HP-filter Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination References (19) (20) (21) (22) (23) Background Motivation Results - fixed reserve Costs of cooperation Conclusion References Alesina, A., Angeloni, I., and Etro, F. (2005). International unions. American Economic Review, 95(3):602–615. Gustafson, R. L. (1958). Carryover levels for grains: A method for determining amounts that are optimal under specified conditions. Technical bulletin, United States Department of Agriculture. Koester, U. (1986). Regional cooperation to improve food security in southern and eastern african countries. Research Report 53, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington, D.C. Ruta, M. (2005). Economic theories of political (dis)integration. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19(1):1–21. Sarris, A., Conforti, P., and Prakash, A. (2011). The use of organized commodity markets to manage food import price instability and risk. Agricultural Economics, 42(1):47–64. von Braun, J. and Torero, M. (2009). Implementing physical and virtual food reserves to protect the poor and prevent market failure. IFPRI Policy Brief 10, International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), Washington D.C. Williams, J. C. and Wright, B. D. (1991). Storage and Commodity Markets. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1st edition. Assessing the costs and benefits of storage coordination