On Systemic Risk Contribution and Macro-financial linkages By Marco A. Espinosa-Vega IMF Prepared for the Conference on Financial Stability and Macroprudencial Policy Central Bank of Portugal Lisbon, Portugal February 2015 The views expressed in this presentation are those of the author and do not necessarily represent those of the IMF or IMF policy. 1 Identifying SIFIs has become a priority Calibration of financial institutions’ systemic contribution and (macroprudential) policies to mitigate systemic risk … a policy reality •The Turner Report •The Dodd-Frank bill •The work of the BIS … An implosion of technical analysis An Implosion of Technical Work • IMF work includes – Systemic risk monitoring toolkit: a user guide (SysMo, 2013) – Addressing interconnectedness (2013) – Options to deal with credit booms (2011) – Options to deal with real estate booms (2011) 3 An Implosion of Technical Work • A Survey of Systemic Risk Analytics (Bisias, Flood, Lo, Valavanis (2012) 4 A Taxonomy – Time dimension – Structural dimension • • • • • Estimates of co-dependence of financial institutions in the tails of equity returns or CDs: Tobias and Brunnermeier (2008) Marginal expected shortfall and systemic risk: Acharya et al. (2010) Contingent claims analysis: Gray and Jobst (2011) Distress dependence: Segoviano (2011) Network Analysis 5 Network Analysis: from Espinosa-Vega & Solé We start from the following stylized balance sheet identity: ki ∑ x ji j di ai bi ∑ xij j Where x stands for interbank lending, a : bank i’s other assets, k : bank i’s capital, b : other borrowing, and d : deposits Interbank Exposures 7 Network Analysis: Tracking Shocks from Espinosa-Vega & Solé We consider two shocks: (i) a credit shock Pre-Shock Balance Sheet ki ∑ x ji j di ai bi ∑ xij j Post-Shock Balance Sheet Network Analysis: Tracking Shocks from Espinosa-Vega & Solé (ii) and a funding shock δρxih ki ∑ x ji ∑ x ji j ki j di ai di ai ai bi bi ∑ xij ∑ j =h xij ρxih j (1 + δ ) ρxih Network Analysis: Algorithms Parameters: λ is loss-given default, δ is asset price haircut, ρ fraction of s/t funding not rolled-over 10 Network Analysis: Tracking shocks from Espinosa-Vega & Solé Institution i fails Assess the impact of parameter assumption including on LGD & haircut for each institution: is capital ≤0 ? Institution j fails Institution k Institution m Institution n fails Compile list of all failed institutions up to this point and re-start algorithm for remaining (nonfailed) institutions Network Analysis: Main Findings 1. Provides clean metric on the domino effect of capital losses and failures induced by alternative credit events 2. Compounding shocks reveals additional systemic countries/institutions Number of Induced Failures 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 France Germany Credit Channel Netherlands United Kingdom Credit and Funding Channel United States Network Analysis: Main Findings 3. It is possible to quantify amount of potential capital losses at institutional level (stress-tests’ second round effects). Post Simulation Capital Impairment Australia Austria Belgium Canada France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Nether. Portugal Spain Sweden Switzer. U.K. Trigger Country: Australia Austria Belgium Canada France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Nether. Portugal Spain Sweden Switzer. U.K. U.S. U.S. (capital impairment in percent of pre-shock capital) -1.9 -1.8 -36.2 0.0 -61.7 -95.9 -2.6 -0.5 -18.7 -36.2 -0.2 -1.3 -1.4 -10.0 ------------- -18.1 -1.6 -32.3 -------5.3 -49.3 -2.0 -18.1 -1.9 -6.6 -1.7 -10.9 ------------- -7.3 -8.1 -6.7 -------------90.3 -48.7 -12.1 -------8.7 -46.3 -4.2 -19.3 ------------- 0.0 -0.2 -3.3 -4.4 -8.5 -0.5 -0.1 -2.5 -3.3 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -1.1 -20.4 -79.1 -7.0 -3.8 -46.8 -3.8 -------13.1 -70.1 -36.9 -46.8 -4.6 -29.6 -2.7 -10.8 ------------- -7.2 -17.5 -41.7 -5.9 -82.6 -30.9 -46.1 -16.5 -41.7 -6.6 -38.2 -8.9 -13.0 ------------- -4.6 -4.8 -46.0 -7.1 -79.0 -------43.5 -21.9 -46.0 -5.8 -23.0 -4.7 -13.1 ------------- -0.2 -25.7 -13.4 -0.4 -49.3 -------12.6 -2.9 -13.4 -1.2 -8.0 -0.5 -2.8 ------------- -2.9 -0.4 -4.8 -2.5 -14.5 -33.0 -2.2 -2.6 -4.8 -0.2 -1.4 -0.7 -3.5 -49.5 -97.5 -39.9 -7.9 -------22.8 -------------24.1 -42.0 -24.7 -8.2 -73.5 -6.0 -18.9 ------------- -0.7 -1.9 -22.7 -0.3 -44.0 -99.3 -15.5 -6.6 -1.3 -22.7 -68.8 -1.3 -3.8 ------------- -0.7 -1.1 -18.0 -0.5 -38.6 -83.7 -5.0 -11.0 -1.8 -18.0 -16.6 -0.9 -1.9 ------------- -4.4 -3.5 -26.0 -3.5 -47.7 -------11.7 -6.7 -7.6 -26.0 -1.3 -11.6 -12.6 ------------- -9.8 -6.9 -33.3 -11.6 -76.3 -------11.7 -9.2 -59.5 -33.3 -1.5 -7.7 -5.1 ------------- -8.3 -1.2 -16.1 -5.6 -37.5 -86.0 -15.3 -5.4 -9.9 -16.1 -1.3 -14.1 -1.6 -7.0 ------- -1.7 -0.4 -7.3 -6.4 -17.2 -40.0 -2.4 -1.2 -12.2 -7.3 -0.1 -2.4 -0.7 -9.0 -64.8 Network Analysis: Main Findings 6. Allows to track potential contagion paths. Japan: Contagion Paths December 2008 Trigger Country Affected Countries Contribution to Final Capital Impairment Japan's Total Capital Impairment (percent of initial capital) (percent of initial capital) Time Series Contagion/Vulnerability Index Contagion/Vulnerability Index from Espinosa-Vega & Solé Post Simulation Capital Impairment Australia Austria Belgium Canada France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Nether. Portugal Spain Sweden Switzer. U.K. Trigger Country: Australia Austria Belgium Canada France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Nether. Portugal Spain Sweden Switzer. U.K. U.S. U.S. (capital impairment in percent of pre-shock capital) -1.9 -1.8 -36.2 0.0 -61.7 -95.9 -2.6 -0.5 -18.7 -36.2 -0.2 -1.3 -1.4 -10.0 ------------- -18.1 -1.6 -32.3 -------5.3 -49.3 -2.0 -18.1 -1.9 -6.6 -1.7 -10.9 ------------- -7.3 -8.1 -6.7 -------------90.3 -48.7 -12.1 -------8.7 -46.3 -4.2 -19.3 ------------- 0.0 -0.2 -3.3 -4.4 -8.5 -0.5 -0.1 -2.5 -3.3 0.0 -0.1 -0.2 -1.1 -20.4 -79.1 -7.0 -3.8 -46.8 -3.8 -------13.1 -70.1 -36.9 -46.8 -4.6 -29.6 -2.7 -10.8 ------------- -7.2 -17.5 -41.7 -5.9 -82.6 -30.9 -46.1 -16.5 -41.7 -6.6 -38.2 -8.9 -13.0 ------------- -4.6 -4.8 -46.0 -7.1 -79.0 -------43.5 -21.9 -46.0 -5.8 -23.0 -4.7 -13.1 ------------- -0.2 -25.7 -13.4 -0.4 -49.3 -------12.6 -2.9 -13.4 -1.2 -8.0 -0.5 -2.8 ------------- -2.9 -0.4 -4.8 -2.5 -14.5 -33.0 -2.2 -2.6 -4.8 -0.2 -1.4 -0.7 -3.5 -49.5 -97.5 -39.9 -7.9 -------22.8 -------------24.1 -42.0 -24.7 -8.2 -73.5 -6.0 -18.9 ------------- -0.7 -1.9 -22.7 -0.3 -44.0 -99.3 -15.5 -6.6 -1.3 -22.7 -68.8 -1.3 -3.8 ------------- -0.7 -1.1 -18.0 -0.5 -38.6 -83.7 -5.0 -11.0 -1.8 -18.0 -16.6 -0.9 -1.9 ------------- -4.4 -3.5 -26.0 -3.5 -47.7 -------11.7 -6.7 -7.6 -26.0 -1.3 -11.6 -12.6 ------------- -9.8 -6.9 -33.3 -11.6 -76.3 -------11.7 -9.2 -59.5 -33.3 -1.5 -7.7 -5.1 ------------- -8.3 -1.2 -16.1 -5.6 -37.5 -86.0 -15.3 -5.4 -9.9 -16.1 -1.3 -14.1 -1.6 -7.0 ------- -1.7 -0.4 -7.3 -6.4 -17.2 -40.0 -2.4 -1.2 -12.2 -7.3 -0.1 -2.4 -0.7 -9.0 -64.8 Contagion/Vulnerability Index • Bank i’s contagion index: the sum of all the capital losses in the system (except for the trigger bank) divided by the sum of the capital of all banks. • Bank i’s vulnerability index: the simple average of percentage of capital losses suffered by a country in all the simulations. 19 1-Abr-14 1-Jan-14 1-Out-13 1-Jul-13 1-Abr-13 1-Jan-13 1-Out-12 1-Jul-12 1-Abr-12 1-Jan-12 1-Out-11 1-Jul-11 1-Abr-11 1-Jan-11 1-Out-10 1-Jul-10 1-Abr-10 1-Jan-10 1-Out-09 1-Jul-09 1-Abr-09 1-Jan-09 1-Out-08 1-Jul-08 1-Abr-08 1-Jan-08 Contagion and Vulnerability Indexes Bank 16 120 100 80 60 Index of Contagion Index of Vulnerability 40 20 0 20 Recent Approaches • A simulated network approach, Hałaj and Kok (2013) Next step: Design Pigouvian Capital Surcharges Based on the systemic contribution of an institution From the Work of Espinosa-Solé (2010) Capital surcharges should be commensurate with the large negative effects that a financial firm’s distress may have on other financial firms—their systemic interconnectedness. A Methodology to Compute Systemic-Risk Based Surcharges comprises: 1. Tracking financial institutions’ portfolios through the credit cycle. 2. Estimating each institution’s spillover effects following a stress event, at each point in the cycle— based on network analysis. 3 Computing Systemic-Risk Based Surcharges 4 Computing Systemic-Risk Based Surcharges 5 Computing Systemic-Risk Based Surcharges from Espinosa-Vega & Solé Two Approaches: • Standardized Approach (SA): regulators assign systemic risk ratings based on the amount of system-wide capital impairment that the default of each institution would induce under a tail-risk scenario. • Risk-Budgeting Approach (RBA): capital surcharges are a function of an institution’s marginal contribution to systemic risk and its own probability of distress. In addition, A smoothing technique is applied to the RBA to lessen its procyclical profile. 6 The Standardized Approach • Consider three ratings based on the system-wide capital impairment caused by an institution’s default: Tier 1 (T1) if capital of distressed institutions is above 35% of system’s capital, Tier 2 (T2) if capital of distressed institutions is 20-35% of system’s capital, NS for the rest of institutions • Each institution is rated at the peak, trend and through of the business cycle. • Regulator assigns a “systemic-risk rating” based on each institution ‘s worst rating through the cycle, to reflect tail-risk. • The regulator then assigns a capital surcharge based on this systemicrisk rating 7 The Standardized Approach 8 The Standardized Approach from Espinosa-Vega & Solé Capital Surcharges Based on SA 11 12 The Risk-Budgeting Approach • Under this approach, an institution’s capital surcharge is determined as a function of its probability of default and its incremental credit Value at Risk (VaR) • Incremental VaR is defined as the increase in the joint VaR of the rest of institutions, caused by the institution’s default on its interbank exposures. 14 The Risk-Budgeting Approach (RBA) 15 Figure 5. Simulation of Systemic Risk Capital Surcharges (Capital shortfall in percent of risk weighted assets) Cyclical capital shortfall Smoothed capital shortfall 0.6 4.5 Bank 1 4.0 Detrended credit growth 0.6 4.5 Bank 2 4.0 0.4 3.5 0.4 3.5 3.0 3.0 0.2 2.5 - 1E - 15 2.0 0.2 2.5 0 2.0 1.5 1.5 - 0.2 1.0 - 0.2 1.0 0.5 0.5 - 0.4 0.0 - 0.5 - 0.6 Trend Trough 4.5 Trend - 0.5 - 0.6 Trend Peak 0.6 Bank 3 - 0.4 0.0 4.0 Trough 4.5 Trend Peak 0.6 Bank 4 4.0 0.4 3.5 3.0 0.2 2.5 0.4 3.5 3.0 0.2 2.5 0 2.0 1.5 0 2.0 1.5 - 0.2 1.0 0.5 - 0.4 0.0 - 0.2 1.0 0.5 - 0.4 0.0 - 0.5 - 0.6 Trend Trough 4.5 Trend - 0.5 Peak 0.6 Bank 5 - 0.6 Trend 4.0 Trough 4.5 Trend Peak 0.6 Bank 6 4.0 0.4 3.5 3.0 0.2 2.5 0.4 3.5 3.0 0.2 2.5 0 2.0 1.5 0 2.0 1.5 - 0.2 1.0 0.5 - 0.4 0.0 - 0.2 1.0 0.5 - 0.4 0.0 - 0.5 - 0.6 Trend Trough Trend Peak - 0.5 - 0.6 Trend Trough Trend Peak Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: The capital shortfall is defined as the difference between the minimal Basel capital requirement the systemic assets. - risk surcharge minus the actual total capital of each institution, in percent of risk plus - weighted 19 The Risk-Budgeting Approach (RBA) • An alternative is to focus on marginal expected short fall as in Acharya et.al. (2010) 17 The BIS approach Country Experience Macroprudential Toolkit for Cross Sectional Dimension (number of countries) 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 Yes No SIFI surcharge Yes No Interbank exposure limit Yes No Concentration Limit Source: IMF survey on Macrorudential Policy Instruments, 2013. • Concrete plans to introduce SIFI surcharges within 2 years? 37 countries • Early adopters: Australia, Canada, Singapore, Austria, Denmark, Sweden and Switzerland. Macro-Financial Linkages Interconnectedness, Systemic Crises, and Recessions. Espinosa-Vega and Russell (2015) 37 In the Aftermath of the Crisis Claims • financial institutions’ linkages may increase an economy’s vulnerability to systemic financial crises • recessions that follow financial crises tend to be exceptionally severe (e.g., Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), Kannan et.al. (2009)) • the recent financial crisis was caused, at least in part, by a lack of complete and accurate information about the state of the portfolios of financial institutions. Corollary • proposals for government regulation to limit interconnectedness A paper consistent with these claims In Espinosa-Vega-Russell (2015) we lay out a simple theoretical model that helps explain the relationship between interconnectedness of financial institutions, systemic financial crises, and long, severe recessions. In our model: diversification retains its traditional advantage from portfolio theory: depositors are risk averse and diversification tends to increase their expected utility (by reducing the variance of their returns, across portfolios and states of the world) interconnectedness means banks connect with each other by loan portfolio diversification: their portfolios include loans originated by other banks. This interconnectedness is attractive to bank depositors but potentially hazardous for the banking system. • Related literature. Bimpikis and Tabaz-Salehi (2012), Ibragimov, et al. (2011), and Wagner (2010, 2011). • In our paper, interconnectedness obscures information about the sources of banks’ portfolio returns. A paper consistent with these claims • Loan portfolio diversification makes it difficult for a bank’s depositors to determine the returns on particular components (by originator) of the bank loan portfolio. As a result, depositors may make inefficient decisions, of two types: – They may liquidate loans (and projects) whose prospects are good, along with loans whose prospects are bad. (They may also fail to liquidate loans whose prospects are bad.) This can create a recession. – because it may be difficult for banks to determine which group of managers originated bad loans, many banks may fire their managers, even though a few banks’ managers were incompetent. This will impair the effectiveness of bank risk assessment, going forward, increasing the probability of prolonged, severe recessions. Interconnectedness and Externalities • The link between the decisions of current depositors and the returns received by future depositors produces an intertemporal externality, – bank managers act to maximize the expected utility of the current depositors. Macroprudential Policy The government cares about current and future depositors…creating a rationale for restricting interconnectedness: Macropru regulation. – Complete restriction – Partial restriction Macroprudential Policy Macropru regulation: curtailing interconnectedness – reduces inefficient liquidations and boosts future depositors’ expected returns – make it easier to differentiate the returns on loans with different originators, which produces both more efficient liquidation decisions and more efficient ‘firing’ decisions and shorter recessions. … but regulation has costs: curtailing interconnectedness increases variability in depositors returns, thus reducing depositors expected utility. Optimal regulation will be a function of the depositors’ degree of risk aversion Optimal regulation may not eliminate crisis Summing Up • Keen interest in furthering our understanding of financial interconnectedness …with an eye at identifying SIFIs and their potential contribution to systemic risk. …to help in the design of macroprudential policies (e.g. Pigouvian capital surcharges) • Ongoing analysis on when to trigger, tighten or relax macropru policies…and their interaction with the macroeconomy. 44 Summing Up • More needs to be done to improve our understanding of macro-financial linkages. • When financial interconnectedness goes ‘wrong’ what is the mechanism through which the macroeconomy gets affected? • What should the policy response be? 45 THANK YOU 46