Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 Chapter 9. Billions Served Neither a borrower nor a lender be; For loan oft loses both itself and friend. And borrowing dulls the edge of husbandry. This above all: to thine own self be true, And it must follow, as the night the day, Thou canst not then be false to any man. – Hamlet I.iii.79–841 In the last seven chapters, we have examined microfinance from more angles than ever before in one place. We have placed modern it in the flow of history. We have shared the points of view of the user at the metaphorical teller window and the manager behind it. We have surveyed the diversity of modern microfinance. And we have taken seriously the strongest claims for its virtues, investigating each in turn: microfinance as ender of poverty, enhancer of freedom, builder of industry. It is time to sum up, draw lessons, ponder what lies ahead, and advise how to influence it. You know the popular image of microfinance: it was invented by that guy in India who won the Nobel Prize; it gives loans so people can start businesses and lift themselves out of poverty. The job of part I of this book was to peel back that image in order to discover a more credible and complex story. Modern microfinance is not, as a cynic might have it, merely another foreign aid fad foisted upon the poor, doomed by its naiveté to fail. If it is a fad, then it is the longest in the history of overseas charity. What explains its persistence is its remarkable success on the market test: poor people are willing to pay for reliable financial services. And that says something about its value. Thus microfinance is best seen as arising organically from several sources: the real needs of poor people for tools to manage tumultuous financial lives; a long historical process of experimentation with ways to deliver such tools; the creativity, vision, and 1 “Husbandry” might be “economy” in modern English. 1 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 commitment of the pioneers such as Muhammad Yunus; and the business imperatives of mass producing small-scale financial services. The scene having been set by part I, part II delved into the evidence on microfinance’s role in development. It tried, in the words of my colleague Ethan Kapstein, to be critical but not cynical, to give the most serious defenses of microfinance a full airing. In writing it, I realized that I needed to look the question of impact from several distinct conceptions of “development,” each tending to lead to different kinds of evidence. Randomized impact studies have rightly received much attention, but have not told the full story any more than a randomized trial of mortgages would have told us what we need to know about the impact of the mortgage industry. That lesson about methodology goes well beyond microfinance. As for microfinance, the lessons distill to these: Credible evidence on microfinance’s success in development as escape from poverty is scarce. At this writing, essentially two credible studies of microcredit and one of microsavings are in the public domain. The two of credit found no impact on indicators of household welfare such as income, spending, and school attendance after 15–18 months. But the celebrated sequence from credit to enterprise is more than a myth. The study of group credit in Hyderabad, India, spotted an increase in profits among the minority (31 percent) of households that already had a business, as well as more business starts among households of relative education and wealth.2 Meanwhile the randomized study of a commitment savings account in Kenya found that this service too helped existing business owners invest in their enterprises. And here, unlike with microcredit, the boost to entrepreneurship showed up as improvements in poverty indicators such as income and spending. 2 The evidence on whether microcredit in particular spurs development as freedom, that is, Banerjee et al. (2009), 17. 2 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 strengthens the tenuous control of the poor over their life circumstances, is ambiguous. Financial services inherently enhance agency but not automatically. Poor people whose incomes are volatile, whose health is frailer, and who can’t work when injured or sick need financial services more than the global rich, in order to put aside money in good days and seasons and pull it out in bad. Loans, savings accounts, insurance, even money transfers can help them do this. But credit inevitably entraps some people through ill luck or judgment. Researchers who have spent weeks or years with borrowers have collected many happy stories of women of finding liberation by doing financial business in public spaces. Others have returned with disturbing stories—some mild, as of the women made to sit in meeting till all dues are paid, some more serious, as of the women whose roofs are taken by peers in order to pay off their debts. These contradictions are not hard to understand, for credit is both a source of possibilities and a bond. Overall, it is hard to feel sanguine that stories of empowerment are the whole story. The success on which microfinance can stake its strongest claim is in industry building. With time, the microfinance industry is growing larger, more efficient, generally more competitive, more diverse in its offerings. More institutions are becoming national intermediaries, taking deposits and lending domestically. In few realms can foreign aid and philanthropy point to such success in building industries. But this success still leaves scope for critique. The enthusiastic supply of credit for microcredit from socially motivated investors public and private is distorting the industry: undermining the drive to take savings and spurring unwise lending, even bubbles. Enthusiasm for credit appears inherently destabilizing in competitive markets, where microfinance institutions can grow fastest by poaching each other’s clients, leading people to take several loans at once, and where no 3 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 credit bureau gives MFIs the full picture. Overall the great strength and hope of microfinance lies in building self-sufficient institutions that can give billions of poor people an increment of control over their lives, control they will use to put food on the table more regularly, invest in education, and, yes, start tiny businesses. Because poor people are willing to pay for the services, microfinance institutions can serve many from a modest base of charitable funds. The benefits may be modest compared to the expectations of escape from poverty, but the costs can be modest too. Rich Rosenberg once recalled his oversight while at the U.S. Agency for International Development of “a few million dollars of donor subsidies in the mid-1990s” for Bolivia’s Prodem, which became the microfinance bank BancoSol and now serves 130,000 borrowers and 323,000 savers.3 He diagrammed the “value proposition” of microfinance this way: Small one-time subsidies leverage large multiples of unsubsidized funds producing sustainable delivery year after year of highly valued services that help hundreds of millions of people keep their consumption stable, finance major expenses, and cope with shocks despite incomes that are low, irregular, and unreliable.4 The Effects of Causes A big idea in the closing chapter of part I (chapter 5) is that microfinance as we observe it is the outcome of an evolutionary process. “Natural” selection explains the emphases on credit, groups, and women. The evolutionary perspective also explains a trait little noted in chapter 5: the mythology that promoters have woven around the workaday business of disbursing and collecting loans, what Pankaj Jain and Mick Moore called the “orthodox fallacy.” Almost no development project has held such strong and multidimensional appeal as microcredit. It appeals 3 4 [MIX market] Rosenberg (2010), 5. 4 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 to the left with talk of empowering women and to the right by insisting on individual responsibility. As the cliché goes, it offers a hand, not a hand-out. And because the currency of microcredit is currency itself, not textbooks or trainers, supporters feel that what they contribute—money—goes directly to the poor. To this extent, the intermediary disappears in the mind of the giver, creating a stronger sense of connection to the ultimate recipient. Peer-to-peer lending sites such as Kiva use the Internet to strengthen this psychological bond by posting borrowers’ stories and pictures. Just as it hardly matters from the evolutionary point of view whether joint liability was invented or copied in the 1970s, it hardly matters whether microfinance promoters believe the mythology. What matters is that investors—again, understood broadly to include all who provide finance for microfinance—rewarded those who told certain stories, creating a selective environment that favored the promoters best at telling them. This should not surprise. All of us who believe in our work tell the best stories we can to show how we believe we help. Jain and Moore put it well: We are not suggesting here that the leaders of the big [microfinance institutions (MFIs)] perpetrated some kind of fraud….The picture is far more complex than that and notions of blame or of individual responsibility are irrelevant to our objective of obtaining practical understanding of why and how [MFIs] have been so successful. Our limited evidence suggests that the orthodox fallacy blossomed and spread in large part because that is what people in aid agencies wanted to hear, thought they had heard, or asked [MFI] leaders to talk about and publicise. To the extent that [MFI] leaders did foster a particular image, this could be seen simply as targeted product promotion in a “market” of aid abundance… …to justify the continuing flow of that money to their own particular organisations and to the microfinance sector as a whole, [MFI] leaders and spokespersons have gradually found themselves, through a combination of circumstances and pressures, purveying a misleading interpretation of the reasons for their success. They emphasise a few elements in a complex organisational system, and are silent on many key components.5 Perhaps the mythologizing of microfinance was historically necessary to build support for the good cause of delivering useful financial services to billions. But in addition to being 5 Jain and Moore (2003), 28–29. 5 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 largely wrong, the mythology has also damaged the microfinance movement, making it harder for microfinance to live up to its actual potential for good. It has amplified the emphasis in favor of one service, microcredit, delivered in ways conceived at one time, about three decades ago. The mythology has spread the dangerous idea that investing in microcredit, putting the poor in debt on a large scale, is automatically good for the poor. In 2004, for example, the U.S. Congress acceded to lobbying from U.S. microfinance groups to require that half of all U.S. microfinance aid go to “very poor” people, despite the lack of evidence that the poorest wanted and could safely handle such credit.6 The acceleration of funding for microcredit, effectively predicated on the idea that more is always better, is also a core cause of the debacles in India and elsewhere, which now haunt the movement. Especially since high-quality studies have emerged that contradict the high-flying myth, the public standing of microfinance may dive, like Icarus after he flew too close to the sun. This book is an attempt to develop a more honest story of microfinance, so that Icarus will neither fly too close to the sun nor brush the waves, and so that the movement will realize its fullest potential to serve the poor. How well it and other efforts to bring realism to this business will succeed depends on how much the supporters of microfinance change their behavior. If people continue to channel billions to the best storytellers, they will continue to create contortions and distortions in the very things they mean to support. You can’t have it all Economics is sometimes defined as the study of the optimal allocation of scarce resources. Really there is more to it than that—resources are rarely allocated optimally anyway—but the definition is apt in that dismal scientists often think in trade-offs. Rejiggering a factory to alter The law defined “very poor” as less living on less than $1,000 per annum in Europe and Eurasia in 1995 dollars, under $400 in Latin America, and under $300 elsewhere. U.S. Congress, Microenterprise Results and Accountability Act of 2004, Public Law 108–484, §252(c). 6 6 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 the allocation of labor and capital produces more toasters and fewer microwaves. Part II reviewed microfinance in light of each of the three notions of success. But that sequential analysis is only an input to a broader synthesis, and to the judgment necessary for wise action. Having built our evidence base by scoring microfinance against various standards, we now need to think across them, and here it is helpful think in terms of trade-offs. Microfinance vs. everything else Trade-offs await on two levels: in comparing microfinance to other charitable projects, and in comparing styles of microfinance. On that first, broad level, is seated the grand question of this book: Does microfinance deserve all that praise and funding? Or should supporters channel their charity and aid elsewhere? Since there’s not much evidence that microfinance lifts people from poverty, or even reliably empowers them, it might seem sensible for funders and investors to dump it and move on to something that puts a bigger dent in poverty. But it turns out that microfinance is not unusual in the degree of our ignorance about its impacts. The impacts of building clinics or distributing bed nets or teaching women business skills are equally variegated, uncertain, and poorly studied. So limited evidence is not a strong argument against microfinance and for other activities. I think that financial services for the poor do deserve a place in the world’s aid and social investment portfolios, for two reasons. First, microfinance has compiled impressive achievements in building institutions that enhance the freedom of millions, and could do the same for billions. These achievements come with the caveats already noted, but because microcredit is generally safe in moderation, and because microfinance is more than microcredit, the caveats are not fatal. Second, a principle of diversification applies: given the uncertainties 7 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 about the impacts of microfinance or anything else, and given that poor people need many things, it is wise to invest in several strategies at once. That said, I will argue below that from the point of view of delivering appropriate financial services to the poor, microfinance’s slice of aid and charity—about $3 billion in 2009, as noted in chapter 8—has grown too large. Microfinance would do better on its own terms if there were less money for it. To this substantial extent, then, there is no trade-off between microfinance and other kinds of aid. Less money for microcredit and more for bednets would be a double win. Microfinance vs. microfinance Within microfinance, trade-offs are harder to avoid. In the late 1990s specialists hotly debated the trade-off between serving the poorest and weaning MFIs off subsidies so that they could grow to serve more people, even if that meant bypassing the poorest, least economical customers. Economist Jonathan Morduch called the split between the “poverty” and “sustainability” advocates the “microfinance schism.” Within this breach, however, a seedling of thought grew that questioned the inevitability of the trade-off: business-like sustainability, the argument went, need not cost much in depth of outreach to the poorest. Bangladesh was Exhibit A. True to his training, Morduch doubted that the choices could be dodged so easily.7 With coauthors, for example, he demonstrated that increasing a microcredit interest rate 1 percent (not 1 percentage point) in Dhaka, the capital of Bangladesh, reduced borrowing by slightly more than 1 percent on average. The implication: even in Bangladesh, cutting subsidies to an MFI might make it more self-sufficient, but it would also, by forcing up interest rates, put formal financial services beyond the reach of some poor people.8 The evidence gathered in this book also hints at trade-offs, especially between 7 8 Morduch (2000). Dehejia, Montgomery, and Morduch (2009). 8 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 development as freedom and development as institution building. Recall the end of chapter 7: “On any given day, in any given place, the immediate business interests of the lender conflict with the agency of the borrower.” MFIs can do credit more easily than savings or insurance, yet it is credit that by nature curtails freedom more. Imposing constraints on borrowers, such as through group meetings and weekly payments, protects the MFIs’ bottom line. Higher interest rates may boost the profitability of MFIs and the dynamism of the industry—and flirt with “usury.” Inversely, layering non-financial services on top of financial ones may enhance women’s agency but also takes subsidies. If it is easy to point out choices, it is harder to make them. The advantages and disadvantages of building subsidy into microfinance, such as through low-interest loans from social investors, vary over time and space in unknown ways. Even if we knew exact consequences, ethical imponderables would raise their heads. How are we to weigh the choice of making cheaper services available to a smaller group against offering more expensive services to a larger one? In the face of such unknowns and imponderables, I suggest two principles of judgment. First, that a project is mostly likely to achieve its potential when it follows its natural constructive tendencies. If your daughter were a piano prodigy, you would get her piano lessons. But note the emphasis on “constructive”: you would probably not nurture her tendency to sociopathy. By this principle, microfinance is likely to do the most good when it plays to its strength, namely turning modest amounts of aid into substantial industries that provide reliable services. Among charitable projects, microfinance is in this respect truly prodigious. To echo the previous chapter: “There is no Grameen Bank of vaccination. One does not hear of organizations sprouting like sunflowers in the world of clean water supply, hiring thousands and serving 9 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 millions, turning a profit and wooing investors.” In contrast, client-for-client, microfinance does not stand head and shoulders above other forms of aid in reaching the poorest, let alone lifting them out of poverty. The (limited) evidence suggests the contrary, that microcredit is more likely to help those who already have businesses or who, because they are better off to start with, can start a business more easily. With respect to Morduch’s “schism,” I therefore favor those who seek to do microfinance in a self-financing, businesslike way in order to maximize reach. The second principle of judgment is this: don’t give up hope on dodging trade-offs. The dictatorship of hard choices is only absolute if microfinance institutions are squeezing every possible ounce of productivity from the capital and labor they consume, and if technology is static. But perfectly efficient firms reside only in textbooks and technology is always improving. Thus the choices in microfinance today are not entirely dismal. The chief opportunity spied by some of the sharpest observers today, including the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, is in doing savings, perhaps especially through high technology (see below). Too much credit for microcredit The financial devices channeling billions into microfinance are marvels. Yet because the ample and cheap finance feeds mostly into microcredit portfolios, it has at least two downsides. It dulls the initiative to take savings as an alternative source of funds. And it encourages microfinance organizations to grow faster than it can safely manage—indeed, drives them to do so, because of the way competition favors the most aggressive players in the short run. Understand, fast microcredit growth is not always bad.9 But if there is some maximum amount of microcredit that a populace can sustainably absorb, the faster that line is crossed, the worse. Recognizing these risks while accepting that credit for microcredit has its place forces hard practical questions. 9 Gonzalez (2010b). 10 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 How should investors collectively define and enforce Aristotle’s golden mean? If they can define it in the abstract, can they legislate it in practice, divvying up the limited investment pie among themselves? Or if moderation cannot be enforced, would the next-best option be to browbeating certain classes of investors into withdrawing altogether? To see the complexities, consider first the concern about undermining deposit-taking. Most MFIs cannot emulate the purity of BRI circa 1990, which as a century-old governmentowned bank was stout enough to resist the World Bank’s repeated offers of credit. Nor should other MFIs necessarily emulate such purity. Even mature MFIs should diversify across funding source since each source has its costs and risks. Deposits might plunge in a recession. Equity is the most pliable, but by the same token most expensive. (And subsidized loans might disappear if the whims of donors shift.) Accepting that borrowing by MFIs is reasonable in principle, it is hard to pinpoint the right amount. Perhaps more should go to young MFIs, then taper as they grow? According to what formula? As for the second concern about ample finance—that it will cause dangerous credit expansion, even bubbles—drawing lines is difficult here too, notoriously so. Bubbles are certain only in retrospect. To ground my thinking about this challenge, my research assistant Paolo Abarcar and I set out to answer an impertinent question about the microcredit bubbles that popped in 2008–09 (see chapter 8): Who inflated them? We combed through the annual reports of the largest MFIs in the four relevant countries.10 In Bosnia, Nicaragua, and Pakistan, it turned out, foreigners supplied most of the air. And most of the money was from public sources. Number one in Bosnia was the European Fund for Southeast Europe, a conduit for European government donors. In Pakistan, the Asian Development Bank loomed over the scene; second Where one institution, such as the U.S. government’s Overseas Private Investment Corporation, had guaranteed another’s loan—promising to pay it if the borrowing MFI did not—we attributed the amount to the guarantor. 10 11 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 there was the Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund, which passed through a World Bank loan. Some of the big creditors were private companies that manage funds from both public and private investors. BlueOrchard, for example, was number one in Nicaragua and number two in Bosnia. (See Table 1.) One important message of Table 1 comes from its novelty. Laboring to answer the question of who inflated the bubbles, I realized: almost no one knew. The data summed here were incomplete, uncertain in some respects, and at 1–2 years of age when gathered, out of date next to the tempo of hypergrowth. But they were the best that were publicly available. In the years before the bubbles burst, hardly any investor saw the big picture because hardly any had tried. Perhaps intermediaries such as BlueOrchard understood the situation. If so, they seem not to have advertised it heavily. 12 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 Table 1. Top five creditor/guarantors to top five microfinance institutions with data, four countries with microcredit crises Outstanding loans and guarantees Creditor/guarantor Money source (million $) Bosnia, end-2008 European Fund for Southeast Europe (EC, Austria, Denmark, Germany, Switzerland) BlueOrchard European Bank for Reconstruction and Development Instituto de Crédito Oficial, Spain Hypo-Alpe-Adria Bank Total, all creditors and guarantors Public 86 Mixed Public Public Private 57 35 34 26 532 Public Private Private Public Private 143 104 48 34 32 468 Mixed Public Mixed Public Private 46 33 28 27 19 326 Public Public Private Private Public 71 32 8 7 6 131 Morocco, end-2008 Instituto de Crédito Oficial, Spain Banque Populaire du Maroc Banque Marocaine du Commerce Extérieur Agence Française de Développement Société Générale Marocaine de Banques Total, all creditors and guarantors Nicaragua, end-2008 BlueOrchard Central American Bank for Economic Integration ProCredit Holding Financiera Nicaragüense de Inversiones (Germany/KfW) responsAbility Total, all creditors and guarantors Pakistan, end-2007 Asian Development Bank Pakistan Poverty Alleviation Fund (World Bank) Domestic money market Habib Bank, MCB Bank, ABN Amro U.S. Overseas Private Investment Corporation Total, all creditors and guarantors Note: "Mixed" instutions are privately run conduits for mixes of public and private money. Source: "Who Inflated the Microcredit Bubbles?", blog post, j.mp/9bRASO, March 27, 2010. 13 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 This story should sound familiar: A set of borrowers, microcreditors in this case, are taking loans from many sources. Total borrowing is expanding rapidly. No one is tracking all this activity, much less whether the borrowers can reasonably be expected to handle all the debts they have contracted. The easy credit is hiding the very problems it creates, since unpayable loans are quickly refinanced with new ones. In other words, the cross-country microcredit financing scene resembles the within-country microcredit market in some places, with untracked multiple borrowing creating the risk of overborrowing and bubbles. Chapter 8 cited Herman Daly’s writing about the need to move from an empty world mentality that treats natural resources as inexhaustible to a full world one that recognizes limits.11 In short order, the footprint of microfinance finance swelled in places from empty to full. Not that everyone who would want microcredit had it; rather, the bottleneck was no longer wholesale finance. In the mid-1990s, Alex Silva struggled to raise a few million dollars for the first microfinance investment vehicle, Profund. (See chapter 8.) Now microfinance investment managers are struggling to place the funds they have on hand. A credit bureau on investment in MFIs One response within the microfinance world to the excesses of lending has been to attack the manifestations. The Smart Campaign, a joint project of CGAP and Accion International’s Center for Financial Inclusion, has signed up more than 500 MFIs to endorse six principles of responsible lending: avoidance of over-indebtedness; transparent and responsible pricing; noncoercive collection practices; proper staff behavior; mechanisms for redress of grievances; and privacy of client data.12 The organizers well understand that nice words do little in themselves. But they give investors a benchmark with which they can hold MFIs accountable. 11 12 Daly (2005). smartcampaign.org/about-the-campaign/campaign-mission-a-goals. 14 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 At any rate, the history of financial manias teaches us that a heavy tide of capital will overtop or sweep away all but the sturdiest embankments. In the United States, the trillion-dollar build-up to the crisis of 2008 tossed aside ratings agencies and central bankers and economic prognosticators—supposed agents of restraint—like so much flotsam. Only jurisdictions with the firmest restraints on lending, such as North Dakota and Canada, held back the tide. Efforts such as the Smart Campaign, while constructive, are not made of stuff strong enough to fundamentally address the problem of overeager lending. Something else is needed to attack the problem closer to its source: a campaign aimed directly at credit for microcredit, with the goal of restraining it. What should be the demands of such a campaign? How should moderation be defined and enforced? Within nations, one corrective for overeager lending is the credit bureau. By analogy, investors in microcredit need at a minimum to establish ways to share information at high frequency on the financial obligations of MFIs in which they invest. This could happen informally. In fact, many microfinance investors already demand high-frequency (such as quarterly) data on the dealings of their investees. This in turn can keep them reasonably abreast of industry-wide conditions in each country. But if that is the status quo, then improving on it calls for something more. A credit bureau with information on microcreditors could publish high-frequency data on investment flows into MFIs (including what they have borrowed wholesale) and their assets (what they have lent retail). The data could be aggregated to protect the confidentiality of individual deals. The body could develop indicators of lending growth of individual MFIs and in regional and national markets. Based on soft standards analogous to the rule of thumb that mortgage payments should not exceed a third of income, it could issue warnings of various severity levels. (Think of yellow and red traffic lights.) These external reference points would help microfinance investment managers resist higher-ups, politicians, 15 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 customers, and citizens who are eager for them to pour more money into microcredit. It would inform Kiva users about where it would be safest to lend. The body could also gather data relevant to when credit for microcredit undermines the initiative to enter the savings business. It could analyze whether a given MFI could realistically obtain permission to take savings; study the cost of doing taking savings; and compare that cost to that of external capital in order to gauge the distortion from cheap credit.13 Like ordinary credit bureaus, such a centralized brain for the microcredit investment business would reduce but not eliminate problems. After all, America’s three credit bureaus did not stop the mortgage lending bloat. The toughest problem might be imposing the restraint implied by a serious commitment to savings: would microfinance investors support a body that advised them to slash their operations, to stop picking the plum MFIs? Perhaps only if they saw the institution as essential to the industry’s survival. Public vs. private An alternative to regulating the sizes of the flows is to regulate who can emit them, favoring those more apt to act with care. In a 2007 report called Role Reversal, Julie Abrams and Damian von Stauffenberg argued that public investors ought to exit MFIs when private ones enter. The job of public investors (which they call International Financial Institutions, or IFIs) is to “go where the private sector does not yet dare to tread; to assume risks that private capital would find unacceptable.” Yet public investors often fall down on the job: Whether top decision-makers are aware of it or not, there are powerful incentives for IFIs to maximize their microfinance exposure, and to do so by concentrating on the largest and safest borrowers. Microfinance has acquired such a positive image, that a sizeable exposure in this sector has become a sign of a IFIs commitment to development. This is reinforced by an IFI’s need to disburse its microfinance budget each year. Since IFIs are not primarily profit-driven their success is often defined by the amounts that have been lent. If a budget has been allocated to microfinance, that budget must be spent—and spending it on a few large loans to top MFIs is far 13 Liliana Rojas-Suarez, Senior Fellow, Center for Global Development, conversation with author, April 30, 2010. 16 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 quicker, cheaper, and less risky than lending to, and nurturing immature institutions.14 On its face, “public should exit when private enters” is a blunt rule with a fuzzy rationale. It is not obvious why private social investors pursuing that “positive image” should behave more constructively than public social investors doing so. Private investment funds too feel pressure to get money out the door and associate with success; many of them are also not primarily profitdriven. But conversations with industry insiders have persuaded me that the public-private distinction has teeth. The key is that most private investors are small specialists. Bad calls can permanently damage their reputations. Such mortal risk focuses the corporate mind. As private companies with staffs numbering in the dozens rather than thousands, they are much less rulebound, more agile. In contrast, major public investors such as the International Finance Corporation (the IFC) are muscle-bound generalists. In recent crises, the private investors seemed quicker to recognize troubles, slow disbursements, and even gently discourage prospective investors in their funds. For example, in the last, dark days of 2008, when global financial Armageddon seemed nigh, the IFC and Germany’s KfW joined forces to announce the Microfinance Liquidity Facility. It was a sort of miniature TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) for the global microfinance industry, meant to prevent a sudden scarcity of capital from choking sound microlenders. Through leading fund managers such as BlueOrchard and responsAbility, it would inject up to $500 million into MFIs. It was a smart, swift, and bold proposal. But by the time the first monies were disbursed, five months later, the fund managers were struggling with a surplus rather than a deficit. It turned out that they already had more money than MFIs could absorb. There was no negative capital shock. Yet despite the excess of 14 Abrams and von Stauffenberg (2007), 1. 17 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 liquidity, the Facility created more of it, disbursing $76 million over the rest of 2010.15 Given the dangers of surfeit, and the continuing dominance of public investors, curtailing the flow of public money into microcredit portfolios would probably make the world a better place. And it is a practical proposal, in that a relatively small group of actors, including heads of development banks and parliamentarians holding the purse strings, could make it happen. Not that the private microfinance investment industry is foible-free. Managers of microfinance investment funds do not build careers by stashing customers’ cash in money market accounts. Their eagerness to raise and invest more money can also distort microfinance. One symbol of that is the Lift Above Poverty Organization (LAPO), an MFI in Nigeria. Von Stauffenberg, who founded the first microfinance ratings firm, MicroRate, described his impression of LAPO from visiting it in 2002: “I could see that they were perfectly positioned to cozy up to donors, but not be financially viable. They had an efficient branch network, making lots of tiny loans, but a bloated headquarters, with a big office studying women’s issues, social impacts, and so on. Those were donor concerns. It was well equipped to sing the songs the donors wanted to hear.” In 2006 MicroRate gave LAPO a grade of β—not spectacular, but passable on a continent where the pickings for microfinance investors were slim. Among the weaknesses MicroRate identified were a poor computer system for tracking loans and finances, a high client drop-out rate (suggesting dissatisfaction), and the taking of savings without a banking license.16 Over the years, LAPO received grants and loans from many private investors: Deutcshe Bank, Citigroup, Triple Jump, the Calvert Foundation, Oxfam Novib, Kiva, and the Grameen 15 16 Microfinance Enhancement Facility (2011). MicroRate (2006). 18 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 Foundation, which gave it an award.17 But then the LAPO story began to unravel. In mid-2009, MicroRate withdrew its rating of LAPO after learning that the MFI was cooking its books.18 LAPO’s external auditor should have caught that—but perhaps overlooked it because he was, improperly, a close relative of a board member.19 LAPO’s presumably uncomfortable funders commissioned a fresh analysis in December 2009 from MicroRate’s European competitor, Planet Rating. Instead if dispelling the cloud of doubt, Planet gave LAPO a harsh C+. To the list of problems it added LAPO’s deceptively high interest rate of 125.9 percent per year and some large and suspicious loans to sister organizations.20 That same month, the bloggers at GiveWell, who ask tough questions of charities, researched LAPO as the leading recipient of Kiva funds. From online sources, they learned that LAPO profits were a high 25 percent of revenue (the average profit rate for Kiva-linked MFIs was zero or less); that 49 percent of LAPO’s customers quit each year; and that some faced hurdles to getting their savings back from LAPO.21 Yet private investors seemed reluctant to let go of LAPO. The Swiss investment fund responsAbility lent it $1 million in September 2009, followed by BlueOrchard with $2 million in November.22 Kiva retained LAPO as a partner until an unfavorable story appeared in the New York Times the following April.23 Calvert appears to have dropped it around then too.24 The next month, the foundation of Klaus and Hilde Schwab, creators of the “Davos” World Economic 17 MicroRate (2007) MicroRate (2009). 19 LAPO (2008), 2, 4; Planet Rating (2009), 7. 20 Planet Rating (2009), 6. As noted in the section on forced savings in chapter 5, LAPO cut its headline interest rate in 2009—but then doubled its forced savings requirement from 10 to 20 percent of the loan, resulting in a net increase in the cost of its credit. 21 Elie Hassenfeld, “LAPO (Kiva Partner) and Financial vs.Social Success,” GiveWell, December 9, 2009; Kiva, “Lift Above Poverty Organization (LAPO) Nigeria,” j.mp/koQtFK, viewed April 27, 2011. 22 CGAP, Microfinance Dealbook, on MicroCapital.org, reports for third and fourth quarters, 2009. 23 MacFarquhar (2010); Kiva, op. cit. note 21. 24 Ashwini Narayanan, “The Truth about Microplace,” PayPal blog, viewed April 28, 2011. 18 19 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 Forum, gave LAPO an award for Social Entrepreneurship.25 To be fair to microfinance investors, doing business with young organizations in developing countries means getting one’s hands dirty. No MFI is perfect, so if one is looking to invest, one must make tough calls, and sometimes they will look bad in hindsight. LAPO’s may even operate cleanly relative to the norm in Nigeria, where the so-called microfinance industry is currently engulfed in a crisis of weak oversight and embezzlement of deposits (see below). But even if LAPO’s combination of rickety books, unlicensed deposit-taking, and high interest, profits, and turnover make it an outlier globally, extreme cases make for illuminating tests. Why was LAPO worthy of support before the New York Times article and less so after, even though most of what the article revealed had been common knowledge among investors for years—or should have been? As GiveWell, wrote: LAPO has been funded and celebrated by many of the big names in microfinance, yet for years there have been many causes for concern about its social (as opposed to financial) performance. From what we’ve seen, it is not clear that these concerns have been on the radar screen of LAPO’s funders and partners.26 The willingness to invest in an MFI despite signs of poor service suggests that pressure to invest is distorting decisions, overriding social mission. If there were less money looking for a home, perhaps there would be fewer tough calls to make. And perhaps there would be fewer LAPO’s, organizations skillfully crafted to attract foreign funds. If the microcredit investment industry cannot be run in a way that minimizes harm to the goals of responsible lending, safe deposit-taking, and healthy institutional growth then probably it should be shut down altogether, save for a catalytic role in developing new MFIs through seed capital and training grants. Because of the dangers of aggressive lending, too little direct 25 Schwab Foundation (2011), 50. Holden Karnofsky, “LAPO: Case Study on Due Diligence by Microfinance Funders,” GiveWell, October 13, 2010. 26 20 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 financing of microcredit portfolios is better than too much. A fundamental problem here is that the evidence on the overall impact of microcredit on poverty and freedom is ambiguous. If it is this hard to assure that such investment does more good than harm, that suggests the movement is spending too much time barking up this tree. Helping microfinance play to its strength, building lasting institutions, calls for less investment, not more. Deliberately seeking savings The lives of the poor are full of risk. Their incomes fluctuate sporadically by day and season. They are more prone to injury and illness, yet more dependent on physical health for their livelihoods. If the chief financial problem of the poor is managing unpredictability, then microinsurance seems tailored to help. Exploratory efforts to insure the poor should be supported and successes should be applauded. Going by the history of today’s rich countries, life insurance is the most promising avenue for take-off. The prospects are perhaps best in South Asia where, just as with microcredit, skilled staff are cheapest relative to the incomes of those to be served. However, as we saw in chapters 4 and 5, insurance is inherently more complex than credit and savings, which cuts against the microfinance business’s imperative to streamline. On balance, microinsurance for the billions appears a less practical ideal than microsavings for the billions. Savings is a conceptually simpler service, with much going for it. Shifting toward savings and away from credit should help microfinance perform better on all three of the senses of success considered in this book. A randomized trial found savings reducing poverty. Savings, if it is safe, does not impinge like debt on freedom. And MFIs enrich the local financial fabric most when they interface with the poor bidirectionally, taking savings and giving credit. Experience and common sense say that the poorest are more willing to save than to shoulder the risk of credit. Recall that BRI in Indonesia has twelve times as many savers below the poverty line as 21 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 borrowers.27 Meanwhile, as we saw in chapter 2, savings can do almost anything credit can. People can save to start a business, pay tuition, finance a funeral. To achieve its full potential, savings needs to be offered in a variety of forms—perhaps including ones that haven’t been invented yet. In principle, accounts can be completely liquid, for maximum flexibility, though in practice these are costly to administer. Commitment savings better approximate the discipline and rhythmic efficiency of loans. Exploration beyond those standard product types, deserves the same energy historically poured into elaborating and refining microcredit. An interesting credit-savings hybrid is Stuart Rutherford’s “P9,” which he is piloting through SafeSave’s rural sister in Bangladesh, Shohoz Shonchoy. It is designed to eliminate two barriers to saving: lack of discipline and lack of periodic lump sums of income, such as a paycheck, from which to set aside money. P9 morphs see-saw–like from credit to savings. A customer starts with a zero-interest loan of 2,000 taka ($28), of which the bank disburses just two-thirds, putting the rest in a zero-interest savings account. Despite having received less than 2,000, the customer pays back that much so that she ends up with a net savings balance. She repays on a schedule of her choosing. She then repeats with optionally larger amounts, so that after a typical seven cycles, savings exceed her loan balance. Once she reaches 20,000 taka in savings, she can withdraw it all, continue to “borrow to save,” or just save conventionally, now with interest.28 Those who would promote microsavings face two major challenges: assuring safety of savings and controlling costs. In informal, small-group savings arrangements, the first problem, building trust, is solved through witness. In a Village Savings and Loan Association of 30 women, everyone can watch as the three key holders secure the group’s lock box. 27 28 Johnston and Morduch (2007), 29. Stuart Rutherford, “Product rules,” j.mp/epwJlh, viewed April 24, 2010. 22 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 But when clients are too numerous for direct witness, government supervisors are usually needed. It sounds like a simple step, but when an external body assumes responsibility for the safety of savings at an MFI, it leads to a massive departure from credit-only microfinance. Regulators (who write rules) and supervisors (who monitor compliance) take an interest not only in the savings side of the operation but the previously ignorable credit side too, since the lending puts the deposits at risk. Overseers must devise and enforce formulas to govern MFI behavior, such as that for every ten dollars in outstanding microloans, the MFI have one dollar on hand in cash or some other ultrasafe form, ready to absorb losses on the loan portfolio and protect deposits (meaning a “capital adequacy ratio” of 10 percent). They may regulate the lending to help assure that it is above-board and prudent, for example, by requiring that the banks keep files with specified documentation on each borrower. They may impose constraints on the ownership and board composition of the MFI to prevent crony capitalism (overly “friendly” lending to parties with undue influence), and to assure that if the MFI needs to call in more capital, owners will have deep enough pockets to comply.29 This is the stuff of conventional banking regulation. Bringing it to microfinance requires surmounting several challenges. One is that enforcing and complying with all these rules costs the MFIs and the government money. For MFIs, collecting the required documentation and filing the required reports drives up the cost of taking savings. In an authoritative review of regulatory issues in microfinance, Robert Christen, Tim Lyman, and Rich Rosenberg write that it is not unusual for compliance to cost 5 percent of assets in the first year and 1 percent or more per year thereafter. Likewise, especially in poor countries where government agencies are chronically underfunded, supervisory agencies may lack to the staff to monitor all of a country’s MFIs and other deposit-taking institutions. And because most MFIs are too small to pose a systemic risk— 29 Christen, Lyman, and Rosenberg (2003). 23 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 too small to undermine confidence in the banking system generally—MFIs are a low priority. Recognizing such limits, Christen, Lyman, and Rosenberg point to a trade-off: only allow a few MFIs to take savings; or allow more to do so, bringing financial services to more people, but under little or no supervision. To the extent that supervisors opt for the latter, they should at least have MFIs make sure customers understand that no supervisory guardian angel is watching.30 The other challenge in keeping savings safe is adapting conventional regulation in order to suit microfinance. While some principles ought to carry over—poor savers deserve the same protections as rich ones when it comes to capital adequacy—the job is still easily botched. Some traditional rules can vitiate the microcredit approach, by, say, requiring all loans to be backed by collateral, or by viewing a non-profit MFI that would own the majority of its for-profit offspring as a crony capitalist.31 And if strict rules can undo microsavings, so can loose ones. In 2007–08, the central bank of Nigeria created defined a new type of financial institution, the Microfinance Bank, and issued an absurd 800 licenses to start them. The banks could do both savings and loans. The result was unsurprising: 800 little institutions, hardly supervised, taking depositors’ and investors’ money, growing fast, making sloppy loans, paying rich salaries to top officials…and running up records of fraud, default, bank runs, and failure. At this writing, the central bank has revoked more than 100 licenses.32 Nigeria’s experience shows why proper regulation makes it rather hard to enter the microsavings business. This, at least in effect, is why many MFIs have entered lending first to build scale, competence, and reputation, then branched into savings. On the other hand, among the exemplars of microsavings, the largest and smallest, BRI’s unit desa system and Rutherford’s SafeSave, both took savings from the start and so far have rewarded their clients’ trust. Many of 30 Ibid., 19, 28. Ibid. 32 [Rozas et al.]; Central Bank of Nigeria (2011). 31 24 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 ProCredit’s banks took savings from birth or moved into it quickly, exploiting the financial muscle of their parent organization. At any rate, accepting the credit-then-savings path as reasonable, it follows that at any given time not every MFI should do microsavings. In fact the reverse follows too by a sort of doctrine of comparative advantage: if MFIs are not all suited for savings, then not every organization that does microsavings needs to be an MFI. Institutions of different form, with a comparative advantage in reliability, can also do the job: VLSAs; credit cooperatives and their more formal and regulated cousins, credit unions; and of course established savings banks, public and private. If the end is the expansion of microsavings, promoters and regulators should be ecumenical about the means. The technological frontier Along with keeping savings safe, a primary task in making microsavings work is controlling cost. A careful study by the Inter-American Development Bank of MFIs in Latin America found that for microsavings accounts, defined as those under $100, holding $1 in deposits cost an astonishing $2 per year, mainly in bank tellers’ time handling tiny deposits and withdrawals. Clearly the economics of banking impose limits on how small the accounts and how poor the people that can be served. Happily, the situation is not as bleak as this statistic suggests. Just as microcredit is most expensive in Latin America, so should we expect microsavings to be. The economics are probably better elsewhere. Meanwhile, despite the high costs, the Latin MFIs accepted the small accounts, and for a set of interesting reasons: a sense of mission to serve the poor, backed by cross-subsidies from larger, profitable accounts; an expectation that many balances would rise over time; and use of the savings relationship as a platform to sell insurance, money transfers, and credit.33 33 Maisch, Soria, and Westley (2006). 25 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 Nevertheless, cost remains an impediment. The great hope for reducing that cost lies in modern technology. Actually, the flavors of microcredit that started the microfinance revolution—solidarity and village banking, individual microcredit—are what economists call technological breakthroughs They were fresh ways to extract more value from a given amount of labor and capital, even if they were low-tech in the everyday sense of the word, involving meeting in person, paying in cash, keeping records on paper. Since then, microfinance has not changed so much as a retail product. SKS in India does group microcredit much as Muhammad Yunus and his students invented it (albeit with a computerized back office). Compartamos in Mexico does village banking more or less as John Hatch and FINCA refined it. The hope now is that the new possibilities for connecting people and transmitting information opened up by modern technology will carry over into microfinance. The future of microfinance appears to be not merely the past with a high-tech add-on— group meetings with smart phones—but something or some things radically different. Look at what has already happened. In the mid-2000’s, Brazil used satellite links and barcode readers to extend its banking system into all of the country’s 5,561 municipalities, including 2,300 that had never been banked before. Post offices and corner stores now operate as “banking correspondents,” agents who can handle transactions on behalf of regular banks far away. They handle the conversion between paper and electronic money, so that customers can, for instance, arrive with cash and pay a water bill, with the payment then being transmitted electronically. The system has handled trillions of dollars in payments.34 In South Africa and Namibia, a company called Net1 delivers government welfare payments to nearly 4 million people by charging their smart cards. Cardholders can convert balances to cash at any store with the appropriate point of Terence Gallagher, Consultant, presentation at “Expanding Financial Services to the Poor: The Role of ITC,” International Finance Corporation, June 9, 2006. 34 26 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 sale (POS) card reader. The cards look like ordinary credit cards and the machines that read them look like ordinary card readers. But inside, the technology is more advanced. For the cards and readers are designed to operate in decentralized fashion to accommodate unreliable power and communications infrastructure. They contain chips that store encrypted transaction histories of their owners and the owners of other cards or readers that they have recently touched, allowing them to pass around and back up transaction histories like ants passing chemical signals. When the readers do connect by phone to central computers, they synchronize everything they have. And because the cards are computers, they can, when passed through readers, provide extra services. They can extend a loan on the fly, based on on-card data about the card holder’s history of welfare payments and servicing of past loans.35 The greatest potential for technological revolution in microfinance comes from one stupendous fact: some 5.3 billion people now tote mobile phones. And the community of the connected is growing fast even in the poorest countries.36 Put otherwise, there are now 5.3 billion people with globally networked computers in their pockets. What can they do with those besides talk and text? Access financial services, for one. In fact, the most successful phone-based financial service for the poor so far was created by a phone company. Called M-PESA, it was launched in 2007 by Kenya’s Safaricom with the help of a £1 million challenge grant from the U.K. Department for International Development. Interestingly, it was born out of the microfinance movement, for it did begin with the idea of doing microcredit transactions by phone. But users in pilot tests began doing something else with it: sending money to each other. As Safaricom developed the system, it realized that the “killer application” for M-PESA was not doing microcredit slightly differently—not patching a 1990s 35 David Schwarzbach, Vice President, Business Development, Net1 UEPS Technologies, Palo Alto, California, presentation at Center for Global Development, June 14, 2006, cgdev.org/content/calendar/detail/8069. 36 ITU (2011). 27 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 communications technology onto a 1970s financial technology—but sending money home. In Kenya, many rural families send a husband or son to Nairobi to work and support the family from afar. Before M-PESA, physical transport of cash was costly and dangerous. One could spend a day or so taking it home oneself. One could get robbed on the way. One could pay informal money carriers, again exposing oneself to robbery as well as fraud.37 M-PESA offered a radically safer, more reliable way to send money over long distances. In just three years MPESA reached more than 9 million, or 40 percent, of Kenyan adults. It now handles more transactions than Western Union.38 All this high technology might dazzle you into thinking that poor countries are leapfrogging the rich into the age of electronic money, leaving cash behind. Quite the contrary. The first thing that Kenyans usually want to do when they receive electronic money is encash it. This they do by visiting any of the 17,000 M-PESA shops which, like Western Union stores, convert between the old and new forms of money for a fee.39 The shops are businesses in themselves, run by individual entrepreneurs in agreement with Safaricom. Almost all the shops I visited during a trip in 2010 were run by women. For these business people, providing the ondemand conversion between paper and electronic money takes work and involves risk. They must staff their shops, project cash demand, keep enough cash on hand, and transport it between the shops and the bank at the risk of robbery. In return, these entrepreneurs keep 70–80 percent of the commissions, the rest going to Safaricom.40 As that split suggests, the M-PESA shopkeepers, and not the phones, are the heart of M-PESA. The phones are the skin. But the phones do hold the system together; and understanding how gets to the core departure 37 Hughes and Lonie (2007) Mas and Radcliffe (2010). 39 Ibid., 1. 40 Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas (2010), 3. 38 28 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 from traditional microcredit. For one, the phones allow the managers behind M-PESA to monitor transactions in real time anticipate cash demand efficiently.41 As well, the phones make MPESA’s e-money seem real and trustworthy. The instant a customer deposits cash into his phone account, Safaricom verifies his new balance with a text message, which stays in his phone’s memory. More generally, the phones let customers hold Safaricom and its agents accountable for promises of service to a degree impossible in informal ways of sending money. When someone sends money home, both he and the recipient get text messages, which prove incontrovertibly that Safaricom is obliged to surrender the funds to the recipient upon request. That accountability in turn allows the delegation and professionalization of cash transport. Before M-PESA, village women might have gone individually, by foot or by bus, to the nearest market town to pick up cash sent home by husbands. Now an M-PESA agent can do it for all of them, all at once, saving time.42 When I visited Kenya to see M-PESA, my fellow travelers and I were taken to the market at the crossroads in the Holo, not far from Lake Victoria. Before M-PESA, we were told, people trekked to the Kisumu, on the shores of the Lake, to get their cash—and spent much of the cash in the market there. Now the cash comes to them through M-PESA, and they spend it locally. And so the Holo market is bustling as it once was not.43 Ironically, a major impact of the new mobile money technology has been increased access to the old mobile money technology, cash. M-PESA shows how information technology can create new efficiencies and empower clients. In M-PESA, we see an alternative to the power relationships of traditional microcredit, in which bank employees lean on clients to lean on each other (in group credit), and in which the ultimate sanction is the loss of future access to loans (in individual and group credit). With For more on the management structure behind M-PESA, see blog post “Make New Media of Exchange, But Keep the Old,” j.mp/c3tbXx, and 42 Eijkman, Kendall, and Mas (2010). 43 Frederik Eijkman, Co-founder, PEP Intermedius, Kisumu, Kenya, conversation with author, May 18, 2010. 41 29 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 mobile-phone based payments, the relationship is less hierarchical. Just as important, technology makes it economical to atomize the client-company relationship. In contrast with a microloan, which can be viewed as a large package of transactions, mostly repayments, spread over time, in mobile money, each transaction of a dollar so, with fees measured in pennies, can stand on its own. Such tariffs encourage clients to economize on transactions while guaranteeing the provider a profit at every step. Ignacio Mas, who jumped from the world’s largest mobile phone company, Vodafone, to the world’s largest philanthropy, the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation, explains that charging by the transaction “is analogous to prepaid airtime for mobile operators: a card bought is profit booked.”44 This is one reason that the Gates Foundation is investing heavily in the high-tech route to savings. I suspect that we are on the cusp of a technological revolution in microfinance. Mobile payments look to me like a kind of infrastructure, like electricity supply and the Internet. It connects people in a radically new way and creates possibilities that will take years for human ingenuity to discover. It will disrupt every field that it touches. In May 2010, while I was in Kenya, Safaricom launched a partnership with Kenya’s dominant MFI, Equity Bank. With a few key presses, M-PESA users can now move electronic money into an Equity savings account that pays interest. They can apply to get automatic loans too, just as with Net1’s system. And they can buy personal accident insurance. Overall, as seen in Brazil and Kenya, technology is rearranging of the economics of banking the poor, centralizing core banking functions while decentralizing the interface to the customer. The new approach splits retail from wholesale while keeping them linked via wires and radio signals. The retailers are local shopkeepers who provide the interface between paper and electronic money. They substitute for the loan officers of traditional MFIs. But they are not 44 Mas (2009), 57. 30 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 banks. They do not hold clients’ money. That job is performed by regulated institutions behind the scenes. Recall how one major impediment to safe savings is the limited capacity of governments to supervise banks. Communications technology is accommodating this limitation in a new way, making it more economical to link the poor directly to traditional, supervised banks. The digital interface of a card or a phone doesn’t make the human interface obsolete; rather, as with M-PESA, it provides a new way to delegate customer service to people who can do it more cheaply than brick-and-mortar banks can do. Coming full circle I began this book with two opposing stories. One was about Murshida, who climbed out of poverty on a ladder of microcredit The other was about Razia, who slipped down a rung after taking loans. I did so to expose how storytelling forms the public image of microfinance, and to make the case for serious research. We need good research not to move beyond thinking in stories, but to test stories, to inform us about which are representative. That is as close as we can come to the truth about something as diverse as the microfinance experiences of 150 million people. Though I have examined services other than credit and notions of success other than escape from poverty, there is no denying that the grain of sand that seeded the imperfect pearl of this book is the common belief that microcredit cuts poverty. As a child of bitterly divorced parents, it goes against my nature to choose sides. I see the world in grays and it is those who see it in black and white, whatever side they choose, who most stir my ire. So I could never dismiss traditional microcredit as nothing more than hype. But it is hard for me to defend it as a great way for aid agencies, philanthropists, and social investors to help poor people. Consider: While microcredit gives people a new option to manage their complex and unpredictable 31 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 financial lives and helps some build businesses, it also leaves some worse off and has a potentially addictive character. On the creditor side, it often pays to keep lending to clients in a continual cycle. On the borrower side, the need to pay off one loan often leads people to take out another. Overlending and overborrowing becomes more likely as creditors multiply and compete, often by lending to the same clients. Although good studies show microsavings and microcredit stimulating microenterprise, those on microcredit have so far found no impact on poverty. Qualitative studies by people who immersed themselves in a village for a month or year corroborate this ambivalence. Some women find liberation in doing financial business in public. Others find entrapment in the peer pressure. Enthusiastic flows of money into lending are inherently dangerous. They can reward overlyrapid lending and, in competitive markets, nearly force it through a vicious cycle in which each lender strives to keep up with its peers. The microfinance movement has compiled a rather long list of disasters in recent years: Bosnia, India, Morocco, Nicaragua, Nigeria, Pakistan. Probably none will be fatal, but together they point to a deep problem of instability. Credit is undoubtedly useful in moderation, as a way for people to discipline themselves into setting aside money for big purchases. It becomes dangerous when it is pushed too hard. And it is here that the mythology that has grown up around microfinance is not just deceptive but destructive. How much support for microcredit is too much? Incomplete evidence cannot support a certain answer. But choices today must be made on the evidence available today. To the practical question of whether social investors ought to keep pouring billions of dollars per year into microcredit, I say no. Seed money for start-up MFIs is one thing; large-scale, submarket financing of microcredit portfolios is another. Indeed, the history of microfinance reviewed in 32 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 chapter 4 shows that small amounts of aid, intelligently placed were invaluable to the microfinance movement. The Ford Foundation, and the U.N. International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) gave crucial early support to the Grameen project. The U.S. Agency for International Development worked behind the scenes in Indonesia and Bolivia, as did Germany’s Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit in the India on the self-help group program. Since such flows currently account for the majority of money going into microfinance, it follows that finance for microfinance should go down. The priority should not be building giant machines for indebting the poor. The priority should be to create balanced, self-sufficient institutions that offer credit in moderation, that help people save and move money safely, and that push the envelope of practicality on insurance. While such a path may superficially contradict the credit-centered mythology advanced by some of the founders of microfinance, it is in fact the truest realization of their vision: businesses serving the bottom of the pyramid, giving millions of poor people more leverage over their difficult financial circumstances. Nimble social investors have helped build such institutions with money and advice, and can do more. But the scale of funding needed is an order of magnitude less than what is seen today in microcredit. The U.K. government helped bring M-PESA into being with a grant of just £1 million. At the end of day, I cannot dismiss Razia’s story. Nor can I dismiss the story of Eva Yanet Hernández Caballero, who Compartamos featured on its web site until her knitting business unraveled and she began missing payments on her loans with triple-digit interest rates.45 I cannot dismiss the story of Jahanara, the microcredit borrower and moneylender who boasted “that she had broken many houses when members could not pay.”46 I cannot dismiss the story of 45 46 Epstein and Smith (2007). Karim (2008), 23. See chapter 7. 33 Roodman microfinance book. Chapter 9. DRAFT. Not for citation or quotation. 5/29/2016 families in Andhra Pradesh who lost wives or fathers to suicide after falling into debt—debt that included microcredit.47 I cannot dismiss these stories, that is, as immaterial to the morality of favoring credit. But neither can I dismiss the manifest hunger of poor people for reliable tools to manage their money; nor the extraordinary success of some microfinance institutions in creating and serving this market over the last third of a century. The best way forward is to celebrate what is good in this achievement and build on it. The success of the microfinance movement to date has proven the viability of businesslike provision of financial services to the poor. The need now is to diversify more aggressively beyond microcredit, especially into microsavings. If savings, money transfers, and insurance can also be done through institutional forms less associated with traditional microcredit, let them be done so. Over the next third of a century, a global industry could arise to deliver to a billion or more poor people the tools they need to master the vicissitudes of their financial lives. Better banking will no more end the poverty than more clinics a more schools or more roads ever have. Most poverty reduction has arisen from profound processes of economic transformation nearly impossible to push from the outside. And building businesses and industries to meet their demand is in fact a contribution to transformational development, however incremental. As it did so often over the last third of a century, judicious outside support can catalyze the innovations needed, innovations that can help all the world’s poor manage their wealth. 47 E.g., see Biswas (2010) and Lee and David (2010). 34