Discussion of ”Debt constraints and Employment" by Kehoe, Midrigan, and Pastorino Pedro S. Amaral Banco de Portugal Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland 8th Banco de Portugal Conference on Monetary Economics 11-13 June, 2015 Main Contributions KMP put some theoretical meat and bones under Mian and Sufi’s empirical findings The key drivers are: Backloaded earnings (through HK growth) Higher discount rates from tightening debt constraints Intuition: when earnings come late in one’s career an increase in discounting lowers expected discounted surplus disproportionately Backloading wages Backloading compensation may be an appealing feature even outside of HK accumulation: Burdett and Coles (ECTA 2003): backloading insures against on the job-search Deferring compensation to induce effort If firms have higher discount rates A perpetual youth economy Data-like earnings-profile is crucial for argument Life-cycle issues can be complicated to model Perpetual youth assumption makes things tractable No need to keep track of age But age distributions are off – Mathusalem economy Labor force experience distribution 0.25 US data 0.2 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 20−24 25−29 30−3435−39 40−44 45−49 50−5455−59 60−64 65−6970−75 75+ Labor force experience distribution 0.25 US data 0.2 Model 0.15 0.1 0.05 0 20−24 25−29 30−3435−39 40−44 45−49 50−5455−59 60−64 65−6970−75 75+ A perpetual youth economy Does it matter, though? Model has more experienced people than data Buchinsky et al. (2010) obtain returns to experience that are the highest in the literature As a consequence, the earnings-age profile is still steep well into one’s grave years Earnings-age profile 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 50 100 Years of Experience 150 A perpetual youth economy: consequences Does it matter, though? Model has more experienced people than data Buchinsky et al. (2010) obtain returns to experience that are the highest in the literature As a consequence, the earnings-age profile is still steep well into one’s grave years This raises two potential problems: calibration and magnitude of discounting effects Discounting earnings Consider discounting the earnings-age profile at different factors: a constant one: 0.985, and a variable one built to replicate the one resulting from the shock Discount factor following shock 0.995 0.99 0.985 0.98 0.975 0.97 0.965 0.96 0 2 4 6 Years from shock 8 10 Discounting earnings Consider discounting that earnings profile at different factors: a constant one: 0.985, and a variable one resulting from the shock Under perfect foresight, discount profiles differ for roughly 10 years Discount factor profiles 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 10 20 30 Years from shock 40 50 Discounting earnings: a surprise The percentage loss in discounted earnings increases with how old workers were when shock hit Totally counterintuitive! Losses in discounted earnings −0.022 −0.024 −0.026 −0.028 −0.03 −0.032 −0.034 −0.036 −0.038 −0.04 0 50 100 Age when shock hit 150 Discounting earnings: questions The percentage loss in discounted earnings increases with how old workers were when shock hit Totally counterintuitive! This may be problematic as the old are over-represented The mean loss in the model is -3.2% and the mean loss under a replica of the U.S. labor force distribution is -3%. Discounting earnings: questions But that still leaves us with two questions: 1 How come the intuition that losses from an increase in the discount rate are higher under increasing wage profiles is incorrect? It is correct for constant discount rates Discount factor profiles 1 β=0.985 Discount factor 0.8 β=0.96 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 Constant earnings −0.2 % loss Linear earnings −0.4 −0.6 −0.8 0 20 40 60 Quarters after shock 80 100 Discounting earnings: questions But that still leaves us with two questions: 1 How come the intuition that losses from an increase in the discount rate are higher under increasing wage profiles is incorrect? It is correct for constant discount rates But not for time varying ones Discount factor profiles Discount factor 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 20 40 60 80 100 80 100 0.05 Constant earnings 0 % loss Linear earnings −0.05 −0.1 0 20 40 60 Quarters after shock Discounting earnings: questions But that still leaves us with two questions: 1 How come the intuition that losses from an increase in the discount rate are higher under increasing wage profiles is incorrect? It is correct for constant discount rates But not for time varying ones 2 Where are the results coming from then? I conjecture that from changes to the wage policy (and the consequent changes to surpluses) Calibration Why calibrate to employment to working-age population? You have a counterfactually low steady-state job-finding rate Given model demography and your average wage growth target, your early wage growth is too high Buchinsky et al (2010) have estimates by education level. The coefficients for experience vary substantially. Not clear what is used. Floden and Linde’s (2001) estimates for the standard deviation of temporary shocks are yearly Concern that estimates of standard deviation of initial log wages not purged from sources of variation not present in the model. Consumption (HP) 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 −0.005 −0.01 −0.015 −0.02 −0.025 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Employment to WAP (HP) 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 −0.005 −0.01 −0.015 −0.02 −0.025 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Employment rate (HP) 0.02 0.015 0.01 0.005 0 −0.005 −0.01 −0.015 −0.02 −0.025 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Wage policy 3.5 3 Wages 2.5 2 1.5 1 0.5 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 z 3 3.5 4 Distributions Employed 200 150 100 50 0 −1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Unemployed 200 150 100 50 0 −3 −2 −1 0 1 z 2 3 4