Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy Volume 5, Issue 1 2006 Article 17 Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition: Evidence from Mergers Following Radio Broadcast Ownership Deregulation Joel Waldfogel∗ ∗ † Julie Wulf† Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania and NBER, waldfogj@wharton.upenn.edu Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, wulf@wharton.upenn.edu c Copyright 2006 The Berkeley Electronic Press. All rights reserved. Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition: Evidence from Mergers Following Radio Broadcast Ownership Deregulation∗ Joel Waldfogel and Julie Wulf Abstract This paper examines the effects of multimarket contact on advertising prices in the U.S. radio broadcasting industry. While it is in general difficult to measure the effect of multimarket contact on competition, the 1996 Telecommunications Act substantially relaxed local radio ownership restrictions, giving rise to a major and exogenous consolidation wave. Between the years of 1995 to 1998, the average extent of multimarket contact in major U.S. media markets increased by 2.5 times. Importantly, the extent of change in multimarket contact varies across markets, and the change in multimarket contact varies separately from the change in concentration. Using a panel data set on 248 geographic U.S. radio broadcast markets, 1995-1998, we find that multimarket contact has little effect on advertising prices. This paper contributes to the empirical literature on multimarket contact by analyzing a different industrial context and using longitudinal data surrounding an ownership deregulation. ∗ Corresponding author: Julie Wulf, Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, 2023 SteinbergDietrich Hall, Philadelphia, PA 19104 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 1 Industrial economists and strategy researchers have long thought that multimarket contact (MMC) might soften competitive behavior. Consequently, considerable effort has been devoted to documenting the effects of multimarket contact on competition, especially since Bernheim and Whinston’s formal characterization (1990). A large group of cross sectional studies finds competition to be weaker in markets whose participants also interact in other markets. A consensus has emerged, based on this evidence, that multimarket contact reduces competition.1 Yet, measurement of the effect of multimarket contact requires exogenous variation in multimarket contact that the cross-sectional context cannot plausibly provide. Recognizing this, researchers in industrial organization and strategy have looked to longitudinal data surrounding deregulatory episodes to measure effects of multimarket contact on competition. Notably, Evans and Kessides (1994) and Gimeno and Woo (1996, 1999) examine the relationship between the changes in prices and changes in multimarket contact surrounding airline deregulation, finding that markets with increased multimarket contact also experience increased prices. In this study, we make use of longitudinal data surrounding a major ownership deregulation in radio broadcasting to revisit the question of whether multimarket contact affects competition. The effect found in the airline studies might be unique to the structure of that industry or specific to the deregulation of airlines. Multiple studies in other industrial contexts using longitudinal data are needed to determine the generality of this effect. We examine the effects of changes in multimarket contact and ownership concentration on radio advertising prices in the period surrounding the 1996 Telecommunications Act. While firms had previously been limited to owning two stations per market and 40 stations nationally, under the Act, they could own up to 8 stations in each of the largest markets and an unlimited number nationally. The Act set off a major consolidation wave, increasing local ownership concentration by more than 30% over the four-year period. Beyond that, the average number of markets in which the ten largest firms operated doubled from less than 15 to more than 30, increasing multimarket contact significantly. In 1995, the two largest owners in each of 248 markets interacted in 1.27 markets on average. By 1998, this measure had increased to over 3—2.5 times the level in 1995. While this sharp increase in multimarket contact was accompanied by an increase in local ownership concentration—itself an important potential determinant of 1 Jayachandran, Gimeno and Varadarajan (1999) and Korn and Baum (1999) summarize the results of the research on multimarket contact and competition. While the results are somewhat mixed, the majority of the studies suggest that firms compete less aggressively (using various measures such as pricing, entry/exit rates, profitability) in markets in which they jointly compete. Combining the list of papers from both summaries, 22 of the 27 studies find that multimarket contact reduces competition. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 2 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 competitive conditions—the increases in multimarket contact and concentration are not so collinear to preclude measurement of distinct effects. Over this period, radio advertising prices rose substantially, by about 25%, although this price increase seems to have originated outside of the radio advertising market. Similar ad price increases occurred in other media markets. (See note 8 below.) Not only were there exogenous changes in concentration and multimarket contact, but because the Act relaxed local ownership limits by different amounts in different-sized markets, it gave rise to exogenously different amounts of variation in multimarket contact and concentration across markets. The structure of ownership deregulation suggests an instrumental variables strategy for empirically documenting the effect of multimarket contact on competition. The relationship between market size and ownership limits is nonlinear by regulatory fiat; it can be modeled with multiple terms in market size—for example, population and its square—which provide two instruments for the two endogenous variables. Using a variety of empirical approaches, we find that neither multimarket contact nor concentration had a robust effect on advertising prices in radio broadcast markets in the U.S. during the years surrounding the Telecommunications Act. These findings contribute to the empirical literature on multimarket contact by analyzing a different industrial context and using longitudinal data surrounding an ownership deregulation. The paper proceeds in 3 parts. Section 1 presents background from existing empirical and theoretical literature. Section 2 describes the data used in the study, as well as the Telecommunications Act and the empirical strategy it allows. Section 3 presents results. A brief conclusion follows. BACKGROUND: THEORY AND EXISTING EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE Most research on tacit collusion among firms has been in the context of singleproduct firms. The possibility that multiproduct firms recognize their rivals and interactions across markets was first raised in 1955 by Corwin Edwards: the “multiplicity of their contacts may blunt the edge of competition.” Mutual forbearance—that is, competitors adopting “a live-and-let-live policy designed to stabilize the whole structure of the competitive relationship”—was a concept that was discussed and explored in several empirical studies.2 In 1990, Bernheim and Whinston developed a theoretical model of multimarket contact and collusive behavior that accelerated interest in the topic, spurring research that evaluated the relationship between multimarket contact and the degree of competition. In what 2 Quotes from Scherer, 1980, p.340. For a list of empirical papers examining the effects of multimarket contact on competition, see Korn and Baum (1999) and Jayachandran, Gimeno and Varadarajan (1999). http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 3 follows, we first describe the intuition behind Bernheim and Whinston’s model and then highlight the results of select empirical studies on multimarket contact. In a game-theoretic analysis of multimarket contact, Bernheim and Whinston establish that interdependencies between firms across markets can facilitate tacit cooperation in otherwise competitive markets. The intuition is that collusive outcomes are easier to sustain with multimarket contact because there is more scope for punishing deviations in any one market. For example, when firms compete in two markets, they recognize that any deviation from collusive behavior in either market will be met with punishment in both markets. In the formal modeling, multimarket contact serves to pool the firm’s incentive constraints across markets. The incentive constraints are expressions that compare the firm’s payoffs from deviating today to the payoffs from cooperating over future periods. For example, in a duopoly market where each firm receives half of monopoly payoffs, the payoffs from cooperating over future periods may far exceed the payoffs from deviating (i.e. there is slack in the constraint) and firms will cooperate. However, in a competitive market in which firms share payoffs among many players, the opposite holds (i.e. payoffs from cooperation are less than that from deviation) and firms do not cooperate. As this two-market example illustrates, in pooling the constraints in both markets, the slack in the constraint of the duopoly market relaxes the competitive market’s binding constraint. Multimarket contact facilitates collusive behavior in the more competitive market since the firms can shift the ‘slack enforcement power’ or the ability to collude in the duopoly market to the more competitive market. Hence, we would expect to see higher prices in otherwise competitive markets whose participants have contact in other less competitive markets. This formal characterization of multimarket contact has led to accelerated interest in the topic by both strategy researchers and industrial economists alike and, while the empirical evidence is somewhat mixed, the majority of studies find that multimarket contact weakens competition. Price levels, profitability, and the stability of incumbents are higher in markets with greater multimarket contact, typically measured by the number of markets in which participants compete. For example, based on a sample of 187 local banking areas in 1972, Heggestad and Rhoades (1978) find greater market share stability of large bank holding companies in local markets with higher multimarket contact. Baum and Korn (1996) using event history analysis find lower entry and exit rates over the period 1979 to 1984 in California airline routes with higher multimarket contact. In industries with higher multimarket contact, Scott (1982) finds higher profits among U.S. manufacturers based on a sample of 437 firms in 1974. Fewer studies find either no effect or the opposite effect of multimarket contact on competitive behavior. For example, Rhoades and Heggestad (1985) find no relationship between operating profits, service charges, or loan rates and fees and Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 4 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 multimarket contact using a larger sample of banks than the earlier study. Mester (1987) finds lower operating profits among 171 California savings and loans in markets with higher multimarket contact. Identification of the effect of multimarket contact on competition is inherently difficult because pricing, market concentration, and multimarket contact all emerge as endogenous outcomes of market processes. While the cross sectional approach in earlier studies may identify correlations between multimarket contact and competition, the causal relationship is unknown.3 A few, more recent empirical studies use longitudinal techniques to analyze the causal relationship and find that increases in multimarket contact weaken competition. Evans and Kessides (1994) find that major airlines during the period from 1984 to 1988 raise fares more on routes where average multimarket contact among all competitors increases faster. During a similar period, Gimeno and Woo (1996, 1999) find that major airlines earn increasing yields on routes where their average multimarket contact with competitors is growing more quickly. These studies rely on the deregulation of the airline industry as a source of exogenous variation to identify the effects of multimarket contact on airline fares and yields.4 Similar to these studies, we exploit an exogenous change in regulation—the relaxation of radio station ownership limits across varying-sized geographic markets—to evaluate the effect of changes in concentration and multimarket contact on advertising prices.5 DATA, MEASURES, AND EMPIRICAL STRATEGY DATA The data for the study are drawn from a radio station-level dataset that includes revenue estimates, owner identity, programming format, and audience size for 3 An important endogeneity problem in this setting is due to unobserved heterogeneity across markets. For example, a positive market shock may increase market price and induce large firms to enter a market. Entry by large firms (that operate in many markets) increases multimarket contact. Hence, we observe a positive correlation between market price and multimarket contact. In this example, omission of market demand in the price regression leads to overstating the effect of multimarket contact on market prices. Panel regressions using market fixed effects address unobserved heterogeneity across markets. 4 Baum and Korn (1996) use longitudinal data on airlines over the period 1979 to 1984 and find that multimarket contact lessens interfirm rivalry as measured by exit and entry (not prices). 5 While the common intuition—codified into the Merger Guidelines—is that increased concentration raises prices, competition in the industry could operate differently. Stations compete for listeners in part through their choice of the quantity of ads to air. Competition would tend to reduce ad quantities and, via the market demand curve, to raise prices with ambiguous effects on revenue overall. The actual effect of concentration on revenue per listener (our measure of prices) remains an empirical question. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 5 every station in 268 U.S. markets in 1995-1998. Our measure of listening is average quarter hour (AQH) listening, the number of persons listening for at least five minutes during an average quarter hour period. Most of the data come from BIA Research (Media Access Pro). We obtain market level AQH listening for Spring of each year from Duncan American Radio. The underlying dataset covers 5888 commercial stations and 2268 owners in 1998. Table 1a shows the number of stations increasing slightly from 1995 to 1998 and the number of owners nationwide declining by more than 25%. We compute measures of price, multimarket contact, and ownership concentration at the market level for much of the analysis. MEASURES Our study requires measures of prices and their determinants including ownership concentration within markets and multimarket contact by firms across markets.6 Here we describe the calculation of these measures. We calculate each market’s advertising price as the aggregate revenue across stations divided by the sum of listeners across the same stations.7 We measure ownership concentration based on the listening share of the largest firms in a market. Because the top 4 firms generally account for 65-85 percent of radio listening in a market, we calculate the collective share of the largest 2, 4 and 6 firms in the market as measures of ownership concentration. In addition, we calculate the Herfindahl index (hhi) of station listening by market. Table 1b shows the market averages of revenue per listener and several measures of ownership concentration by year. Revenue per listener has increased by 25% and concentration (measured by hhi) has increased by 32% over the four-year period. Spot market prices increased by 18% over the three-year period from 1995 to 1997. 8 6 In this study, we use market level data which are based on actual information about market level revenue rather than estimates of firm revenue. 7 This measure has the shortcoming that, in principle, annual station revenue= (price per ad/listener) * (# of listeners) * (# of ads). Since we don’t observe the number of ads, our “price” actually equals the product of two expressions we cannot disentangle. That is, our “price”=(price per ad/listener) * (# of ads). Balancing this disadvantage are two advantages. First, the revenue data, while estimates for individual stations, are calculated to audited totals for many markets. (See Duncan (1993)). The second advantage of these data is that they are available for all major stations. Clearly, there is a problem if the revenue data reflect a formula rather than actual prices. To address this, we also estimate regressions using cities in which revenue data are audited by an accounting firm (either Hungerford or Miller Kaplan). Approximately 100 of the 268 markets were audited by an accounting firm. (Refer to discussion in Section 3a.) 8 The magnitude of the increase in revenue per listener is consistent with price increases in both radio and television advertising as documented in a Morgan Stanley Dean Witter (1999) research report. Over the same time period, the report documents increases in radio ad prices (measured by CPM or cost-per-thousand-listeners) of 32.1% in network radio and 23.4% in spot radio ads. The Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 6 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 The calculation of multimarket contact in a market is more complicated. Table 2 shows the amount of multimarket contact between pairs of firms in geographic markets in 1998. The table includes the largest ten firms measured by the number of stations owned in 1998. (The diagonal elements show the instances of multimarket contact with the own-firm or, more directly, the number of markets of operation for the firm—Clear Channel Communications owned radio stations in 80 geographic markets, while Capstar Broadcasting Partners operated in 62 markets.) Zeroes in this table indicate that a firm pair has no geographic overlap. Clear Channel overlaps with each of the other largest firms (i.e. multimarket contact measure greater than zero for all values in column 1), yet Cumulus Media shares markets with only two of the largest firms (with mainly zeroes in column 3). A value of one indicates that the firms have stations coexisting in a single market. Values of 2 or more literally reflect multimarket contact. Clear Channel overlaps in more than fifteen markets with four of the largest firms. Slightly more than one-half of the forty-five firm pairs represented in Table 2 have some market overlap (i.e. multimarket contact greater than or equal to 2), while about one-third have no geographic overlap. How does one quantify the amount of multimarket contact in a market? A market consists of N participants that may encounter each other in different markets, in addition to this one. It seems natural to consider the pairs of participants in a market, then to average the multimarket contact across these pairs. Thus, if there are N firms in the market, one measure of multimarket contact is the average of the number of contacts across all markets between N(N1)/2 pairs of firms. A practical problem with this “simple average” approach is that because ownership within markets is fairly concentrated, firms are not symmetric. Computing the average multimarket contact over all firms, including the “fringe” of firms that may own only one station nation-wide, might give undue weight to firms that are unimportant in price-setting. To address this concern we calculate the amount of multimarket contact between the top 2, 4 and 6 participants in each market (based on listening share for each firm’s local collective stations). (Note that the numbers of firm-pairs among the top 4 and 6 firms in each market are 6 and 15, respectively.) The following example illustrates this measure of multimarket contact. In Philadelphia, the top four firms based on listening share in 1998 are Greater report documents even higher increases in television ad prices: 37.7% in network television and 46.9% in spot television ads. Source: Morgan Stanley Dean Witter (March 3, 1999), “Ad Hoc: Media Pricing Trends—A Look Under the Hood.” Table 1, pg. 3. We take averages of men/women categories for both radio and television and broadcast / spot categories for television. The average spot prices in Table 1b come from SQAD Spot Radio and represent CPM (cost per thousand) estimates for Arbitron Metro Survey Areas (MSAs). http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 7 Media, Chancellor Media Corporation, Evergreen Media Corporation, and Beasley Broadcast Group. There are 6 possible firm-pairs among these firms and each pair meet in a number of markets nationwide including the Philadelphia market. Hence, our multimarket contact measure between the top 4 firms in Philadelphia equals the average of the total number of markets in which each firm-pair meets. Based on this method of calculation, Table 1b shows that average multimarket contact for all markets almost tripled over the period (2firm) from 1.27 to 3.17. EMPIRICAL STRATEGY The Telecommunications Act of 1996 substantially relaxed both local and national ownership restrictions. Prior to the Act, a firm could own up to 40 stations nationally and no more than 3 in each market.9 Under the Act a firm could own up to 8 stations in each of the largest markets and faced no national ownership limits. As has been documented elsewhere (Berry and Waldfogel, 2001), this policy shift unleashed a wave of consolidation that substantially increased ownership concentration in local markets. The question here is whether the policy change also gave rise to exogenous variation in the extent of multimarket contact and, moreover, whether the change in multimarket contact is separate from the change in concentration. In 1995 the largest chain (the firm owning the most radio stations within the sample markets) was Jacor Communications, with 52 stations in 23 city markets (Table 3).10 A few other firms operated networks of similar reach. American Radio Systems operated 45 stations in 18 city markets, and SFX Broadcasting operated 37 stations in 17 city markets. By 1998 (only two years after the Act), the largest firm operated over 400 stations in as many as 80 city markets. While no firm operated in over 23 city markets in 1995, in 1998 six firms operated in over 23 city markets. It is clear from Table 3 that firms operated more stations per city market in 1998 relative to 1995 hence explaining the increase in local ownership concentration. The fact that firms increased the number of markets of operation 9 Prior to September 1992, a firm could own up to 12 AM plus 12 FM stations nationally. On September 16, 1992, the national ownership limits were increased to 18 AM plus 18 FM stations. On September 16, 1994, the limits increased to 20 AM plus 20 FM stations. (Source: FCC) 10 While Jacor’s ownership of 52 stations appears to contradict the ownership rules then in effect, it appears not to be an error. Other authoritative accounts, such as Noam (2004) write that Jacor owned 54 stations during 1995 (see http://www.vii.org/papers/medconc.htm, accessed October 24, 2005). And FCC documents indicate that some stations “owned” by Jacor were actually separately owned but operated jointly with Jacor properties during 1995 (see http://www.fcc.gov/Bureaus/Mass_Media/Orders/1996/fcc96380.txt, accessed October 24, 2005). Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 8 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 also suggests that incidence of multimarket contact between firms—as when two firms both operate in a number of markets—would increase. Tables 4 and 5 illustrate the dimensions of exogenous variation that we will exploit to measure the impact of multimarket contact and ownership concentration on market prices. The ownership restrictions were relaxed to different extents in markets of different sizes, thus giving rise to different extents of increase in both multimarket contact and ownership concentration across markets of different sizes. Thus, we can address the possible endogeneity of multimarket contact and concentration measures by using two terms in market size, measured by either population or by the number of stations in a market prior to the changes in ownership restrictions. Table 4 presents averages of both multimarket contact and concentration ratios of the two largest firms by 1998 population quartiles in 1995 and 1998. A number of things are apparent from this table. First, consider the statistics in the lower part of the table. While larger markets are less concentrated, the increase in concentration over the period is the greatest in the largest markets. In 1995, concentration is higher in smaller markets than in larger markets [0.60 in the smallest market (Q1) vs. 0.38 in the largest market (Q4)]. Second, concentration in all markets increased between 1995 and 1998 by 24%, and the increase is proportionately larger in larger markets (45% for Q4 vs. 12% for Q1). In contrast with the concentration measures in Table 4, multimarket contact is higher in larger markets [1.9 in the largest market (Q4) vs. 1.0 in the smallest market (Q1)]. Multimarket contact increases dramatically between 1995 and 1998 (139% overall), with sharp increases of more than 3.5 times in the larger population markets (265% for Q4). Table 5 shows the local limits before and after the Act, by market size measured by the number of stations in the market. The patterns are qualitatively similar to those presented in Table 4. That is, while markets with more stations are less concentrated, the increase in concentration over the period is the greatest in the markets with the most stations. Moreover, multimarket contact is greater in markets with more stations and the increase in multimarket contact is proportionately larger in those markets. We propose to use the variation in multimarket contact and ownership concentration that followed the Act to measure the effects of multimarket contact and ownership concentration on competition. We have two endogenous variables, multimarket contact and concentration, and one conceptual instrument, market size (measured by either population or the number of stations). But the ownership limits were relaxed to different extents in markets of different sizes, and a review of Tables 4 and 5 shows that the changes in multimarket contact and concentration bear different nonlinear relationships with market size. Hence, more than one term in market http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 9 size, such as population and its square, can serve as plausible instruments for both multimarket contact and concentration. REGRESSION RESULTS LONGITUDINAL SPECIFICATIONS Fixed effects regressions using longitudinal data overcome the biases in OLS estimates that arise from fixed unobserved heterogeneity. In this sense, our approach goes beyond many of the earlier studies based on cross-sectional results. We begin by estimating market fixed effects regressions using pooled data for all years and the 2-firm measures of multimarket contact and concentration. In the first column of Table 6, we regress the logarithm of average revenue per listener in a market (i.e. our measure of price) on 2-firm measures of multimarket contact and concentration.11 We include year effects and report robust standard errors clustered by market. We find a positive and significant coefficient on multimarket contact and a positive, but insignificant coefficient on concentration. As mentioned earlier, one concern might be that the revenue data just reflect a formula and that we are learning about the relation between multimarket contact, concentration, and this formula and not about the relation with actual prices. To address this concern, in Table 6 column (2), we estimate the baseline regression, but use only those city markets (approximately 100) in which revenue data are audited by an accounting firm (either Hungerford or Miller Kaplan). We find similar results as reported in column (1) based on all markets. Importantly, the coefficient on 2-firm multimarket contact (0.0033) is very close in magnitude in comparison to the estimate based on all markets (0.0037), but is weakly significant at the 10% level. The coefficient on concentration is positive and larger in magnitude in comparison to column (1), but is imprecisely estimated. In Table 6 columns (3) and (4), we replicate the regressions in columns (1) and (2), but use the 4-firm measures of multimarket contact and concentration. Both coefficients on multimarket contact are positive and larger in magnitude in comparison to those based on the 2-firm measure, but neither coefficient is statistically significant. In both regressions, we find negative and insignificant coefficients on concentration. When we replicate these regressions using the 6firm measures of multimarket contact and concentration, the multimarket coefficients are qualitatively similar to those based on the 4-firm measure (unreported). 11 This semi-log specification is the same as that estimated in Evans and Kessides (1994) and we report these results to allow a direct comparison to their findings. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 10 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 The range of multimarket contact coefficients in Table 6 is between 0.0033 (for the 2-firm measure) and 0.0117 (for the 4-firm measure). How large are these coefficients? Recall from Table 1 that the 2-firm multimarket contact measure increases from 1.27 in 1995 to 3.17 in 1998, while the 4-firm measure increases from 1.24 to 2.08. Multiplying the 0.0037 (coefficient on multimarket contact in column (1) that is significant at the 1% level) by the change in 2-firm multimarket contact yields a 0.70 percent change in prices attributable to the change in multimarket contact. The analogous exercise for the 4-firm measure in column (4) yields a 0.98 percent increase in price. Only the estimates in columns (1) & (2) are significantly different from zero with one estimate being only weakly significant. Nevertheless, one could infer that there is an effect of multimarket contact on prices. However, it is quite small. ROBUSTNESS CHECKS Next we explore the robustness of the relatively small effect of multimarket contact on radio prices as documented in Table 6. While fixed effects control for time-invariant market effects and we cluster standard errors by market, we may still be understating standard errors due to serially correlated residuals. In Table 7 column (1), we address this by adjusting standard errors for serial correlation [AR(1)] and find that the coefficient on multimarket contact remains positive, but is no longer significant. Also, the size of the coefficient is less than half that in our baseline regression (Table 6 column 1). Of course, this difference might be attributable to the smaller sample, since we lose the first year in the AR(1) specification. In column (2), we repeat the baseline regression on the sub-sample that excludes 1995 observations and find that the coefficient on multimarket contact is positive, slightly larger, but remains insignificant. As expected, the standard errors in the AR(1) specification are slightly larger than the clustered standard errors in column (2) (however, only those associated with the multimarket contact coefficient). We find qualitatively similar results when we estimate regressions using only audited markets (unreported). Thus we find that the small and significant positive coefficient on multimarket contact in our baseline regression is not robust to adjusting standard errors for serial correlation. Yet, since we lose 1995 in these analyses, this may be simply due to the inability of capturing large changes in both prices and multimarket during a critical year. Of potentially greater concern than incorrect inference due to understated standard errors, our fixed effects results may be influenced by time trends in advertising prices that vary by market. To evaluate this, in Table 7 column (3), we return to the sample based on all four years and control for market-specific trends by adding an interaction term between city-market effects and a trend variable. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 11 We find a positive coefficient on multimarket contact and a negative coefficient on concentration, but neither coefficient is statistically significant. Once again, the positive and statistically significant coefficient on multimarket contact that is reported in our baseline regression (Table 6 column 1) is not robust when we control for market-specific trends. Moreover, we find qualitatively similar results when we estimate regressions using only audited markets (unreported). The small but significant effect of multimarket contact on prices documented in our baseline regression is not robust to either adjustments for serial correlated residuals or to controls for market-specific trends. Next, we turn to estimating instrumental variables regressions to acknowledge the potential endogeneity of multimarket contact and ownership concentration. INSTRUMENTAL VARIABLES SPECIFICATIONS As discussed earlier, both multimarket contact and ownership concentration are potentially endogenous variables and the extent of the change in each is also potentially endogenous across markets. But it is also possible that the change in multimarket contact over time is endogenous. If the change in multimarket contact is related to the change in prices, then our fixed effects approaches will yield biased estimates of the effect of within-market variation in multimarket contact on prices. To address this, we estimate instrumental variables regressions using nonlinear terms in two measures of market size, population and the number of stations in a market prior to the changes in ownership restrictions. The relationship between the variation in both endogenous variables and each instrument has been previously documented in the tables of summary statistics [market population in Table 4 and number of stations in a market (or policy bands) in Table 5]. In the last two columns in Table 7, we report results of our instrumental variables regressions. In column (4) we instrument multimarket contact and concentration with 1995 population of the market (and its square). In column (5), we instrument with the number of stations in a market (or policy bands). The policy bands are defined as a series of dummy variables that represent how the Act changed ownership limits in each market as illustrated in Table 5. For example, if a market in 1995 had 14 or fewer stations, then the policy band dummy equals one and zero otherwise. Analogous dummy variables are created for two other categories: markets with 15 or more, but less than 30 stations; and markets with more than 30 stations.12 In the regressions in columns (4) and (5), none of the variables of interest are significantly different than zero. 12 population of a market in 1995, and and ( population 2 ) i where populationi is it is a dummy which is 1 after the Telecommunications Act In particular, our instruments are populationi it Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy it 12 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 COMPARISON TO PREVIOUS LONGITUDINAL STUDIES Previous research has estimated the effect of multimarket contact on price competition. Studies based on longitudinal data that exploit exogenous variation surrounding a deregulation are generally limited to the airlines industry.13 These studies find the multimarket contact has a positive effect on prices that is both statistically and economically significant. For example, Evans and Kessides use the exogenous variation in multimarket contact caused by airline deregulation and find that increases in multimarket contact from the 25th to the 75th percentile results in an increase of over 5% in airline prices. By contrast, based on a similar empirical strategy in a different industrial context, we find weak evidence of an effect of multimarket contact on price competition. In this paper, we report the results of semi-log regressions that are based on similar specifications to the regression results reported in Evans and Kessides (hereafter EK). As mentioned earlier, we find a small economic effect of multimarket contact on price—the growth in multimarket contact between 1995 and 1998 explains a 0.7 percent increase in average revenue per listener. In addition to being small, this effect is not statistically robust to: (a) adjusting standard errors for serial correlation or (b) controlling for market-specific trends. Finally, instrumenting multimarket contact and concentration measures using two measures of market size (market population and policy bands) results in coefficients that are not statistically different than zero. By contrast, EK in a comparable regression of the logarithm of average route price on multimarket contact find that an increase of one standard deviation in multimarket contact leads to a 3.5% increase in prices with a t-statistic greater than 8.14 So, EK estimate a larger and statistically significant effect of multimarket contact on prices in airlines (3.5%) in comparison to our estimate in radio broadcasting (less than 1%). To sum up, we find an economically small effect that is not robust to a goes into effect. The policy band instrument is, analogously, the policy band dummies interacted with it . 13 An exception to this is Gelfand and Spiller (1987) who examine multiproduct interactions in the Uruguayan Banking Sector in the late 1970s surrounding a partial relaxation of legal entry barriers. 14 This estimate comes from the Table V regression results in EK on page 359. In Section V-A of the paper, EK address the potential for understated standard errors due to regressing airline prices that vary within the route on measures of multimarket contact that vary only across routes. To address this, they define their dependent variable as the logarithm of the average ticket price at the route level which is comparable to our dependent variable—logarithm of average radio prices in a city market. A one standard deviation increase in their measure of average route contact (0.08) results in a 3.5% increase in average route price (0.08*0.443 coefficient on average route contact from Table V, column 1). http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 13 reasonable set of analyses suggesting that the multimarket effect on radio prices is not significantly different than zero. One possible explanation for the differences between EK and our findings is that the amount of exogenous variation in multimarket contact differs between the samples. However, the changes in multimarket contact over the periods studied are roughly comparable: multimarket contact in airlines doubles from 1984 to 1988 and it increases by 2.5 times in radio from 1995 to 1998. Another possible econometric explanation might be due to differences in samples: EK analyze only the 1000 largest city-pair routes, while we investigate all radio markets. More broadly, and possibly more likely, the results raise the question of whether sector differences account for the different effect of multimarket contact on competitive behavior. For example, airlines set prices for large numbers of customers, and the prices are not only public information but they are also observable at a relatively low cost. This may make it easier for competitors to detect cheating and, in turn, strengthen incentives for tacit collusion. The number of ad buyers in radio is small (compared to air travelers). Ad prices are negotiated and not necessarily publicly known, even if rate cards are public. As a result it may be more difficult to monitor behavior and maintain tacit collusion in radio markets. Another possible explanation is that joint ownership and the existence of close substitutes may affect the ability of competitors to sustain collusion. While there is joint ownership in multiple advertising media by radio firms (i.e. radio, television and bulletin boards owned by a single firm), the same is not true in transportation: airline firms are distinct from firms operating in railroad, bus, and rental cars sectors. Finally, there may be differences in the deregulation of airlines and radio that may account for the difference. CONCLUSION The consensus of previous empirical research across many industrial sectors suggests that multimarket contact reduces rivalry among competitors. However, the results are open to question because most of the studies are based on cross sectional datasets, and measurement of the effect requires exogenous variation in multimarket contact that the cross sectional context cannot plausibly provide. More recent papers based on longitudinal studies surrounding deregulation in the airline industry find support for the theory of mutual forbearance: increases in multimarket contact between competitors serving the same airline routes lead to higher prices. We argue that additional industrial settings should be explored using longitudinal datasets. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 14 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 The 1996 Telecommunications Act significantly relaxed ownership restrictions in radio broadcasting leading to massive consolidation following the Act. The extreme exogenous changes in multimarket contact combined with well-defined geographic markets in radio broadcasting make it a desirable setting to empirically measure the effect of multimarket contact on price competition. We find a small economic effect of multimarket contact on radio advertising prices surrounding the deregulation of radio ownership and this effect is not robust to a reasonable set of analyses. Moreover, our estimates indicate that the change in multimarket contact can explain very little (almost one thirty-fifth) of the large increase in advertising prices between 1995 and 1998. Because the concentration measures are significant in none of the fixed effects regressions, there is no portion of the change in ad prices that we can attribute to increased concentration. The findings in this paper suggest that the effect of multimarket contact on competitive behavior may differ across industries. Why do we find little effect of concentration or multimarket contact on prices in radio advertising? One possibility is that radio advertising is not a distinct market. That is, television advertising may be a close substitute to radio advertising. A number of recent studies ask whether advertising on a particular broadcast medium is in the same market as ads on other media (Ekelund, Ford and Jackson, 1999; Silk, Klein and Berndt, 2001; and Bush, 2002). The findings in these studies are mixed. Using 2001 BIA data to estimate own-price elasticities and cross-price elasticities, Bush (2002) finds evidence suggesting that the local radio advertising market is not distinct from local television or newspaper advertising markets. By contrast, Ekelund et al. (1999) use 1995 BIA data and estimate own-price elasticities that suggest radio advertising is a distinct market, although their data do not allow them to distinguish between local and national advertising. Our finding of little discernable effect of multimarket contact or concentration on prices suggests that radio advertising is not a distinct market. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 15 REFERENCES Baum, Joel A. C. and Helaine J. Korn (1996), “Competitive Dynamics of Interfirm Rivalry,” The Academy of Management Journal 39(2), pp. 255291. Bernheim, Douglas and Michael D. Whinston (1990), “Multimarket Contact and Collusive Behavior,” RAND Journal of Economics 21, pp. 1-26. Berry, Steven T. and Joel Waldfogel (2001), “Do Mergers Increase Product Variety? Evidence from Radio Broadcasting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(3), pp. 1009-1025. Bush, C. Anthony (2002), “On the Substitutability of Local Newspaper, Radio, and Television Advertising in Local Business Sales,” Federal Communications Commission, Media Bureau Staff Research Paper, pp. 2002-2010. Duncan, James H. (1993), American Radio, Spring 1993, Indianapolis: Duncan’s American Radio. Ekelund, R.B. Jr., G.S. Ford and J.D. Jackson (1999), “Is Radio Advertising a Distinct Local Market? An Empirical Analysis,” Review of Industrial Organization 14, pp. 239-256. Edwards, Corwin D. (1955), “Conglomerate Bigness as a Source of Power,” in Business Concentration and Price Policy, National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 331-352. Evans, William N. and Ioannis Kessides (1994), “Living by the ‘Golden Rule’: Multimarket Contact in the U.S. Airline Industry,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109, pp. 341-366. Federal Communications Commission (1996), Memorandum Opinion and Order, Transfer of Control of Citicasters to Jacor, September 17, 1996. Gelfand, Matthew D. and Pablo T. Spiller (1987), “Entry Barriers and Multiproduct Oligopolies: Do They Forebear or Spoil?” International Journal of Industrial Organization 5, pp. 101-113. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 16 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 Gimeno, Javier and Carolyn Y. Woo (1996), “Hypercompetition in a Multimarket Environment: The Role of Strategic Similarity and Multimarket Contact on Competitive De-Escalation,” Organization Science 7, pp. 322-341. ________ and ________ (1999), “Multimarket Contact, Economies of Scope, and Firm Performance,” Academy of Management Journal 42(3), pp. 239-259. Heggestad, Arnold A. and Stephen A. Rhoades (1978), “Multimarket Interdependence and Local Market Competition in Banking,” The Review of Economics and Statistics 60, pp. 523-532. Jayachandran, Satish, Javier Gimeno and P. Rajan Varadarajan (1999), “The Theory of Multimarket Competition: A Synthesis and Implications for Marketing Strategy,” Journal of Marketing 63, pp. 49-66. Korn, Helaine J. and Joel A.C. Baum (1999), “Chance, Imitative, and Strategic Antecedents to Multimarket Contact.” Academy of Management Journal 42(2), pp. 171-194. Mester, Loretta J. (1987), “Multiple Market Contact Between Savings and Loan,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 19, pp. 538-549. Morgan Stanley Dean Witter, Micheal Russell (1999), “Ad Hoc: Media Pricing Trends—A Look Under the Hood,” March 3, 1999, Table 1, p. 3. Noam, Eli M. (2004), “Media Concentration in the United States: Industry Trends and Regulatory Responses,” Virtual Institute of Information—Industry Report, Columbia Business School. Rhoades, Stephen A. and Arnold A. Heggestad (1985), “Multimarket Interdependence and Performance in Banking: Two Tests,” The Antitrust Bulleting 30, pp. 975-995. Scherer, F. M. (1980), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Houghton Mifflin, Boston, MA. Scott, John T. (1982), “Multimarket Contact and Economic Performance,” The Review of Economics and Statistics 64, pp. 368-375. Silk, A.J., L.R. Klein and E.R. Berndt (2001), “Intermedia Substitutibility and Market Demand by National Advertisers,” NBER working paper 8624. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 17 TABLE 1 DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS Panel A: Sample Statistics 1995 1996 1997 1998 % Change No. of Stations 5794 5846 5771 5888 1.6 No. of Owners 3040 2773 2448 2268 <25.4> Avg. No. of Stations Owned 1.8 2.1 2.4 2.6 44.4 Panel B: Averages by City Market (248 Markets) Stations (Avg.) Owners (Avg.) Avg. Revenue/listener Avg. Revenue/listener (101 audited markets) Avg. Spot Prices Concentration 2 Firm 4 Firm Herfindahl (hhi) Multimarket Contact 2 Firm 4 Firm 1995 1996 1997 1998 % Change 21.7 11.3 393 371 21.8 10.3 415 400 21.5 9.1 445 425 22.0 8.5 491 472 1.4 <24.7> 24.9 27.2 6.02 6.49 7.12 -- 18.3 (95-97) 0.51 0.75 0.22 0.56 0.80 0.25 0.61 0.83 0.28 0.63 0.86 0.29 23.5 14.7 31.8 1.27 1.24 1.61 1.39 2.34 1.73 3.17 2.08 149.6 52.8 Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 18 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 TABLE 2 MULTIMARKET CONTACT (MMC) FOR TEN LARGEST OWNERS (BY NUMBER OF STATIONS IN 1998) Clear Channel Comm. Capstar Broadcast. Partners Cumulus Media LLC Salem Comm. Corp. CBS Corp. Chancellor Media Corp. Citadel Comm. Corp. Cox Radio Inc. Sinclair Comm. Inc. Entercom Clear Channel Comm. 80 16 3 18 17 17 8 9 7 2 Capstar Broadcast. Partners 16 62 3 1 3 0 6 1 3 1 Cumulus Media LLC 3 3 30 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 Salem Comm. Corp. 18 1 0 27 13 18 1 2 1 4 CBS Corp. 17 3 0 13 26 10 0 2 3 6 Chancellor Media Corp. 17 0 0 18 10 25 0 5 0 2 Citadel Comm. Corp. 8 6 0 1 0 0 22 0 1 0 Cox Radio Inc. 9 1 0 2 2 5 0 13 0 0 Sinclair Comm. Inc. 7 3 0 1 3 0 1 0 10 1 Entercom 2 1 0 4 6 2 0 0 1 8 Note: The main diagonal represents the number of city-markets in which the firm operates. The off-diagonal represents the number of citymarkets in which the firm-pair interact. A number greater than one in the off-diagonal represents multimarket contact for that firm-pair. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 19 TABLE 3 NUMBER OF STATIONS AND NUMBER OF CITY-MARKETS FOR TEN LARGEST FIRMS (BY NUMBER OF STATIONS IN 1998), 1995 - 1998 1995 Owner 1998 No. of Stations No. of Owner City-markets No. of Stations No. of City-markets 409 80 228 62 Jacor Communications Incorporated American Radio Systems License Corp SFX Broadcasting Inc 52 23 45 18 Clear Channel Communications Capstar Broadcasting Partners 37 17 Cumulus Media LLC 142 30 Evergreen Media Corp 35 14 Chancellor Media Corp. 124 25 Clear Channel Communications Salem Communications Corporation Benchmark Communications Group W Radio 33 11 104 22 29 19 Citadel Communications Corporation CBS Corporation 89 26 25 9 Cox Radio Inc 55 13 23 12 Sinclair Communications Inc. 50 10 Triathlon Broadcasting 23 7 44 27 River City Broadcasting 23 8 Salem Communications Corporation Entercom 37 8 Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy 20 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 TABLE 4 MULTIMARKET CONTACT (MMC) AND CONCENTRATION BY MARKET SIZE (1998 POPULATION QUARTILE) CITY-MARKETS, 1995-1998 City Markets (248) MMC (Top 2-firms) by 1998 Population Quartile (Avg. Pop. 1000’s) Concentration (Top 2-Firms) 1995 1998 % Change All Markets 1.27 3.17 149.6 Quartile 1 (109.9) 1.02 1.26 23.5 Quartile 2 (210.2) 1.02 1.62 58.8 Quartile 3 (404.5) 1.09 2.28 109.2 Quartile 4 (1980.2) 1.94 7.08 264.9 All Markets 0.51 0.63 23.5 Quartile 1 0.60 0.67 11.7 Quartile 2 0.54 0.65 20.4 Quartile 3 0.53 0.64 20.8 Quartile 4 0.38 0.55 44.7 http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 21 TABLE 5 FCC RESTRICTIONS ON LOCAL JOINT OWNERSHIP OF RADIO STATIONS AND MEASURES OF MULTIMARKET CONTACT AND CONCENTRATION BY POLICY BANDS USING MARKET SIZE Restrictions on Local Joint Ownership of Radio Stations Pre- & Post-1996 Telecommunications Act Max. No. of Jointly Limit on No. in Same Owned Stations Service (AM or FM) Size of Market (No. of Stations) Pre- 1996 Post- 1996 Pre- 1996 45+ 4(a) 8 2 30-44 4(a) 7 15-29 4(a) 0-14 (b) Nationwide Notes: (a) (b) Post- 1996 Measures of Multimarket Contact and Concentration by City-Market, 1995-1998 Multimarket Contact (MMC) Concentration (Top 2-Firms) (Top 2-Firms) 95 98 95 98 5 2.73 8.00 193.0 0.27 0.43 59.3 2 4 1.60 6.11 281.9 0.39 0.57 46.2 6 2 4 1.11 2.43 118.9 0.49 0.62 26.5 3 5 2 3 1.01 1.24 22.8 0.67 0.71 6.0 40 No limit 20 No limit 1.27 3.17 149.6 0.51 0.63 23.5 In any case, no one may own more than 25% of the stations. In any case, no one may own more than 50% of the stations. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy % % 22 Vol. 5 [2006], No. 1, Article 17 TABLE 6 REGRESSIONS OF (LOG) AVERAGE PRICE ON MULTIMARKET CONTACT AND OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION 2 AND 4 FIRM MEASURES CITY-MARKET FIXED EFFECTS (1) FE All Markets MMC- 2 firm Concentration- 2 firm 0.0037*** (0.0014) 0.0003 (0.0620) (2) FE Audited Markets 0.0514*** (0.0098) 0.1158*** (0.0122) 0.2066*** (0.0169) 5.9235*** (0.0321) 0.0646*** (0.0119) 0.1184*** (0.0158) 0.2104*** (0.0325) 5.8696*** (0.0335) 0.0077 (0.0051) -0.0299 (0.0718) 0.0529*** (0.0102) 0.1186*** (0.0128) 0.2104*** (0.0166) 5.9413*** (0.0516) 990 248 0.43 404 101 0.44 990 248 0.43 Concentration- 4 firm 1997 1998 Constant Observations Number of markets R-squared (4) FE Audited Markets 0.0033* (0.0019) 0.0291 (0.0747) MMC- 4 firm 1996 (3) FE All Markets 0.0117 (0.0092) -0.0330 (0.0968) 0.0672*** (0.0113) 0.1228*** (0.0152) 0.2132*** (0.0286) 5.8932*** (0.0619) 404 101 0.44 Notes: All markets sample includes all city-markets for which all data are available. Audited markets sample includes markets audited by an accounting firm. Regressions report standard errors clustered by market. ***/**/* represent significance at the 1%/5%/10% level. http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/contributions/vol5/iss1/art17 Waldfogel and Wulf: Measuring the Effect of Multimarket Contact on Competition 23 TABLE 7 REGRESSIONS OF (LOG) AVERAGE PRICE ON MULTIMARKET CONTACT AND OWNERSHIP CONCENTRATION 2 FIRM MEASURES CITY-MARKET FIXED EFFECTS AND IV REGRESSIONS MMC (1) FE-AR(1) (2) FE (3) FE 1996-1998 1996-1998 1995-1998 0.0014 (0.0022) 0.0218 (0.0666) -0.1112*** (0.0091) -0.0836*** (0.0086) 0.0021 (0.0014) 0.0308 (0.0714) -0.1559*** (0.0158) -0.0916*** (0.0122) 0.0010 (0.0016) -0.0558 (0.0823) Constant 6.1264*** (0.0322) 6.1156*** (0.0476) City-market*Trend -- Observations Number of markets 742 248 Concentration 1996 1997 (4) FE-IV Population Instrument 1995-1998 (5) FE-IV Policy Band Instrument 1995-1998 5.2388*** (0.0106) 0.0151 (0.0282) 0.0917 (1.7166) 0.0430 (0.0783) 0.0941 (0.1496) 0.1740 (0.1559) 5.8624*** (0.8369) 0.0365 (0.0436) -1.2997 (1.6902) 0.1062 (0.0726) 0.2159* (0.1311) 0.3013** (0.1248) 6.5418*** (0.8039) -- yes -- -- 742 248 990 248 990 248 990 248 1998 Notes: Sample includes all city-markets for which all data are available. Column (1) reports standard errors adjusted for serial correlation (AR(1)). Column (2) is based on the same sample as in column (1), but reports standard errors clustered by market. Regressions in columns (3) through (5) are based on the sample that includes all city-markets for which all data are available. ***/**/* represent significance at the 1%/5%/10% level. Contributions to Economic Analysis & Policy