“How to regain confidence in the euro area?” contribution by Vítor Gaspar 1to a panel discussion at the Conference “The Euro Area and the Financial Crisis”, 6-8 September, Bratislava, hosted by the National Bank of Slovakia. I thank the organizers, especially Ludovit Ódor, for inviting me for this Conference and for giving me the opportunity to participate in this panel to discuss “How to regain confidence in the euro area?” As Athanasios Orphanides said, in his opening keynote address, the Global Crisis revealed fault lines in the governance of the euro area. He focused on the new architecture for financial stability in Europe. In my brief introduction to this panel I want to focus on public finances; specifically I want to focus on budget discipline. 1. Demographic transition, the global crisis and debt levels. Before focusing on the specific case of the euro area I want to very briefly comment on a crucial evolutionary trend that shapes the context in which budgetary policy will be conducted in the next decades: demographics. Developments are the more surprising as the world is experiencing a fundamental demographic transition. According to the latest demographic projections, made available by the United Nations 2, World Population will stop growing by 2050, when it will have reached about 9 billion people (compared to almost 7 billion in 2010). This will interrupt a trend of pronounced population growth recorded for centuries. This constitutes an epochal transition with profound impacts on economic, political and social balances. The transition will happen first in advanced countries. For example for the 27 Member States of the European Union the population is projected to decline slightly in the four decades from 2010 to 2050 (notwithstanding significant migration flows). The share of EU27 in World population is projected to decline from 7.2% to 5.4% 3. The transition has far-reaching implications for social, political and economic trends. It has, in particular, strong influence on the sustainability of public finances. All other things equal, a slowdown in population growth increases the implicit public debt burden associated with the operation of health and pension systems. At the same time demographic transition raises very difficult issues of equity across generations. Public debts in OECD countries have doubled since the mid-seventies. The Global Crisis accelerated the trend. The evolution was marked by the functioning of automatic stabilizers, discretionary expansion and the costs of intervention to stabilize the financial 1 Special Adviser Banco de Portugal. I am grateful to Isabel Gameiro and Paul Hiebert for comments and corrections. The remaining errors are my responsibility. The views expressed are my own and do not necessarily reflect those of the Banco de Portugal or the Eurosystem’s. 2 An authoritative source is provided by United Nations, 2009. 3 In 1950 the relevant percentage was 14.8%. system 4. Such accumulation of public debt is unprecedented in peace time. Therefore, sustainability of Public Finances is a central challenge that the Global Crisis has made even more pressing. 2. Budgetary rules and procedures in the euro area. The economic constitution of the euro area reflects the view that stability-oriented macroeconomic policies provide the groundwork for the proper functioning of a market economy with unfettered competition leading to sustainable growth. The primary goal of monetary policy is price stability and the conduct of monetary policy was entrusted to the independent European Central Bank. The Lisbon Treaty includes provisions protecting the central bank from encroachment from the fiscal authorities. Article 123 prohibits monetary financing and Article 124 rules out privileged access to financial institutions. Moreover, Article 125 excludes the responsibility of the Union or of other Member States for financial commitments assumed by one Member State; and Article 122 limits financial assistance for cases in which a Member State “is in difficulties or is seriously threatened with severe difficulties caused by natural disasters or exceptional occurrences beyond its control …” Notoriously, article 143 of the Treaty does not foresee mutual assistance for the case of members of the euro area 5. A fundamental question is whether, given the prohibition of monetary financing, privileged access and bail out, market discipline can be expected to be sufficient to ensure fiscal discipline. The question was addressed more than twenty years ago in the Delors Report (page 24): “To some extent market forces can exert a disciplinary influence … However, experience suggests that market perceptions do not necessarily provide strong and compelling signals and that access to a large capital market may for some time facilitate the financing of economic imbalances … The constraints imposed by market forces might either be too slow and weak or too sudden and disruptive.” In a companion piece, Lamfalussy (1989) argues that there is indeed reason to be skeptical about the effectiveness of market-imposed discipline for countries participating in a monetary union 6. The conclusion in the Delors Report was that participation in the single market and in the single currency implied that Member States had to accept corresponding policy constraints. This view is reflected in relevant provisions in the Lisbon Treaty. Specifically Articles 120 and 121 prescribe that Member States conduct their economic policies as a matter of common concern and with a view to achieve the objectives of the Union. In case a Member 4 As Trichet stressed, in his address to the 2010 Jackson Hole Conference, in the euro area, public debt to GDP shot up by more than 20 percentage points in a period of just four years starting in 2007 (see Trichet, 2010). 5 The point is made by Marzinotto, Pisani-Ferry and Sapir (2010). 6 Empirical evidence and further discussion are provided in Restoy (1996) and Bernoth et al. (2006) and Schuknecht et al (2008). State does not behave in conformity with the Broad Economic Policy Guidelines or risks jeopardizing the smooth functioning of economic and monetary union, it is subject to the possibility of warnings from the European Commission and recommendations from the EU’s Council. Moreover, Article 126 imposes on Member States participating in the euro area, the legal obligation to avoid excessive deficits. The Treaty provisions were completed by the Stability and Growth Pact 7. The Pact made clear a distinction between the preventive arm, based on the surveillance of budgetary positions, and the corrective arm, based on the excessive deficit procedure. The preventive arm is covered by Regulation EC 1466/97 (amended by Regulation EC 1055/2005). The corrective arm, in turn, is covered by Regulation EC 1467/97 (amended by Regulation EC 1056/2005) 8. Paragraph 11, of article 126 of the TFEU foresees the possibility of sanctions in the case of non-compliance. 3. Sovereign Debt Market Behavior. The creation of the euro area has been associated with the emergence of an integrated market for sovereign debt. Capiello, Engle and Shephard (2006) find that correlation between bond returns issued by governments participating in the euro area approached unity shortly after the start of the euro area in 1999. In most of the first decade of the euro area sovereign spreads have been low (rarely exceeding 30 basis points and averaging much lower) 9. The situation changed dramatically with the Global Crisis. Spreads widened slowly and gradually and the process paced up after the bankruptcy of Lehman, in September 2008. In 2009 there was a period when the situation seemed on a path of gradual easing. However, from the autumn onwards spreads widened again and CDS premiums increased reflecting bond market tensions, driven, to a large extent, by idiosyncratic factors. Euro area bond markets were in turmoil in early May 2010 and stabilized only after the announcement of strong collective action at the European level. At the current time (September 2010) tensions persist in bond markets. Schuknecht, von Hagen and Wolswijk (2008, 2010) importantly show that bond yield spreads can be largely explained on the basis of economic fundamentals before and after financial market turmoil and the crisis. They are able to relate differentials to benchmark (the German bunds for the euro area) with deficit and debt differentials. However, after September 2009, the coefficient on deficit differentials has been multiplied by a factor between 3 and 4 and the coefficient on debt differentials by a factor of 7-8. At the same time spreads have also increased as a response to shifts in general risk aversion, with German ten-year bonds assuming a safe haven role. The ability of these authors to find a systematic relation between spreads and fundamentals before and after market turmoil and the crisis has important policy 7 For the genesis of the Stability and Growth Pact see Stark (2001) and Costello (2001). A very useful source for the relevant secondary legislation texts is http://europa.eu/legislation_summaries/economic_and_monetary_affairs/stability_and_growth_pact/i ndex_en.htm. 9 As documented by, for example, Gerlach, Schulz and Wolff (2010). 8 implications. In particular market discipline has been present throughout the whole period, albeit in a much stronger way in the recent past. The evidence shows a clear pattern in which market discipline was “too slow and weak” before the Global Crisis and became, more recently, “too sudden and disruptive”. The Stability and Growth Pact and the other provisions in the Treaty and secondary legislation failed to prevent the very pattern of market behavior they were designed to avoid. Such failure requires major adjustments in the governance of the euro area. The issue is central for macroeconomic stability, in general, and for financial stability, in particular. 4. The work of the van Rompuy Task Force. The problem identified above was already clear in March 2010. On 26 March the European Council gave a mandate to the van Rompuy Task Force to examine the relevant issues and proposed specific actions aiming at reinforcing economic governance in the euro area. The approach of the Task Force includes three elements: First, strong surveillance over national fiscal policies and more effective prevention and correction of excessive levels of public deficits and public debt; Second, effective monitoring countries’ competitiveness positions aiming at the correction of macroeconomic imbalances; Third, a crisis management framework. In their contribution to the work of the van Rompuy Task Force, the Governing Council of the ECB, stresses the importance of mechanism design to contain moral hazard associated with the crisis management framework. As Jean Tirole said: in crisis, policy-makers often have their options narrowed to choosing between “the bad and the ugly”. The only way around is to design ex ante institutions to shape incentives to ensure prudent behavior. To do so it is necessary to ensure that financial support will be made available only at penalty rates and under strict conditionality. The rules that apply in extreme crisis situations are crucial to shape incentives at all times. The Task Force has met for the fourth time on Monday, September 6 and Van Rompuy will report to the 16 September European Council. The Task force is due to complete its work and to make concrete proposals before the end of October. Progress is being reported. Nevertheless, it is important not to underestimate difficulties. The work of the Task Force is made harder because we already have an extensive framework of rules and procedures (described above in section 2) that failed to deliver as intended (as discussed in section 3). The Global Crisis has demonstrated an unprecedented degree of international interdependence. Nowhere are linkages stronger than in the euro area. An institutional response is required, consistent with this increased interdependence. The construction of the euro area is work in progress. If we are successful we will lay the stability-oriented economic policy framework of the euro area on stronger institutional foundations. REFERENCES Baele, Lieven, Annalisa Fernando, Peter Hördahl, Elizaveta Krylova and Cyril Monnet, 2004, Measuring Financial Integration in the Euro Area, ECB Occasional Paper 14. Bernoth, K., J. von Hagen and L. Schuknecht, 2006, Sovereign Risk Premiums in the European Government Bond Market, SFB/TR Discussion Paper 150. Capiello, Lorenzo, Robert Engle and Kevin Shephard, 2006, Asymmetric dynamics of correlation of global equity and bond markets returns, Journal of Financial Econometrics, Fall 4 (4): 537572. An earlier version of the paper was released as ECB Working Paper 204. Constâncio, Vítor, 2005, European Monetary Integration and the Portuguese Case, in Carsten Detken, Vítor Gaspar and Gilles Noblet (eds.), The New EU Member States: Convergence and Stability, Third ECB Central Banking Conference, 21-22 October 2004, Frankfurt: European Central Bank. Costello, Declan, 2001, The SGP: How Did we Get There? In Anne Brunilla, Marco Buti and Danielle Franco (eds.) The Stability and Growth Pact: the architecture of fiscal policy in EMU, New York: Palgrave. Delors Report, 1989, Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. ECB Governing Council, 2010, Reinforcing Economic Governance in the Euro Area, available at http://www.ecb.int/pub/pdf/other/reinforcingeconomicgovernanceintheeuroareaen.pdf Gaspar, Vítor, 2003, Comment, in Marco Buti (ed.) Monetary and Fiscal Policies in Europe: Interaction and Coordination, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Gerlach, Stefan, Alexander Schulz and Guntram Wolff, 2010, Banking and Sovereign Risk in the Euro Area, CEPR Discussion Paper 7833. Lamfalussy, Alexander, 1989, Macro-coordination of fiscal policies in an economic and monetary union, in Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities. Marzinotto, Benedicta, Jean Pisani-Ferry and André Sapir, 2010, Two Crises, Two Responses, Bruegel Policy Brief, 01, March, 2010. Restoy, Fernando, 1996, Interest Rates and Fiscal Discipline in Monetary Unions, European Economic Review, 40: 1629-46. Schuknecht, L. J. von Hagen and G. Wolswijk, 2008, Government risk premiums in the bond market: EMU and Canada, ECB Working Paper Series 879, March. Published in 2009 in the European Journal of Political Economy 25, pp:371-384. Schuknecht, L. J. von Hagen and G. Wolswijk, 2010, Government risk premiums in the EU revisited: the Impact of the Financial Crisis, ECB Working Paper Series 1152, February. Stark, Juergen, 2001, The Genesis of a Pact, In Anne Brunilla, Marco Buti and Danielle Franco (eds.) The Stability and Growth Pact: the architecture of fiscal policy in EMU, New York: Palgrave. Trichet, Jean-Claude, 2010, Lunch address Central Banking in Uncertain Times: Conviction and Responsibility, at the Jackson Hole Conference Macroeconomic Challenges: the Decade Ahead, available at http://www.ecb.int/press/key/date/2010/html/sp100827.en.html United Nations, 2009, World Population Prospects: The 2008 Revision, Population Database, New York: United Nations, available at http://esa.un.org/unpp/.