1 Chapter 2 Gender Preference, Fertility Choices and Government Policy in India 2.1 Introduction If we consider the theory of fertility transition, many developing countries are still in the early to mid stages of transition where observed fertility levels exceed desired family sizes. Evidence of such phenomenon in developing countries can usually be found in high levels of unwanted fertility, gender preferences and child replacement effects (Bongaarts, 2000). It is often established that couples in developing countries tend to have higher fertility either because of poor access to contraceptives, or because they have a taste preference for a certain gender composition in their existing children—or simply because high infant mortality rates force couples to have a higher fertility rate in order to maintain desired family size. India has been especially affected by these problems. While the infant mortality rate has gone down, it is still higher than many other developing countries and thus one can 2 imagine that part of the reason for high fertility is the need to replace deceased children. However, despite much effort, the impact of high child mortality on reproductive behavior is not fully understood. Several studies have noted that couples in India tend to have a strong preference for sons over daughters. In an effort to have sons, many couples either continue to have children until the desired number of sons has been reached, or get abortions done. Studies have also found that there are thousands of women in India who would prefer to postpone or avoid pregnancy but do not use contraceptives. These women have an "unmet need" for contraception and it‟s plausible that part of their high fertility is unwanted. In this paper I examine the impact of a shift in the government policy in India to reduce fertility levels in 1997, when the government moved from policies encouraging family planning and female sterilization to policies affecting demand for larger families. The highly centralized, target-based and inflexible policies in the pre 1997 period with heavy reliance on female sterilization did not address the high fertility problem appropriately. By providing monetary and other incentives to couples opting for sterilization, these policies ended up in targeting older women who already had a large enough family size. Thus even though some improvements in national averages were seen, fertility reduction stalled after some time because the taste preferences of couples remained in favor of large family sizes with a higher concentration of boys. In contrast, the policies since 1997 have been aimed at reducing fertility through better awareness of the benefits of smaller family sizes. These policies target all women in reproductive age groups and thus a reduction in 3 fertility is achieved by improving the overall maternal and child health, creating awareness and demand for smaller family sizes and improving access of modern contraceptive methods. The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In section 2.2 I discuss the related literature on gender bias in India and key factors resulting in such behavior. I then discuss the policy environment in India before and after 1997. Section 2.3 describes the data used for estimation. Section 2.4 briefly describes the original data through key summary statistics. In section 2.5 I describe the methodology used to estimate various models, sample selection, creation of variables and summary statistics on them. The main results are described in section 2.6, with a conclusion in section 2.7. 2.2 Related Literatures/ Motivation 2.2.1 Preferences for Son Several studies have noted that couples in India tend to have a strong preference for sons over daughters (Arnold et al, 1998). In an effort to have sons, many couples either continue to have children until the desired number of sons has been reached, or get abortions done. In either case, this may have an adverse effect on not only general maternal and child health in the country but also on fertility rates. Arnold et al, (1998) conclude that son preference fundamentally affects fertility behavior and child mortality and girls with older sisters are often at the highest risk of mortality. Previous studies have found that a large number of social, cultural and economic considerations are at the root 4 of such a preference pattern among couples (Friedman et al, 1994). Studies have identified that there is a greater economic utility from having a son. In the joint Hindu family system, the eldest son is expected to take care of his parents once they become old, although there is some evidence that sons are no longer a dependable source of oldage support (Bardhan 1988). A daughter on the other hand, gets married into another household and is morally obligated to assume responsibility for caring for her parents-inlaw. Upon marriage, the son brings a daughter-in-law home to his house who not only helps around the house but also brings monetary gains to the household in terms of dowry. A daughter on the other hand is an economic burden in the sense that huge sums of dowry need to be given to marry her off. According to traditional Hindu religion, women are not allowed to attend cremations. It is believed that a human being will abode heaven and attain moksha (salvation) only if his/her last rites are performed by his/her son. However, according to the religion, it is also important to have a daughter because parents can earn religious merit by selflessly giving her away in marriage. This suggests that the observed son preference may be the result of a complex interplay of socio-economic factors. A strong preference for son may hinder the attainment of ideal fertility rates in the country if couples continue to have children in order to reach their ideal sex-composition among their children. Coupled with the fact that the average age at marriage for women is low in India, this may also be one of the reasons for poorer maternal and child health in India. Existing studies however do 5 not exhibit a consistently strong effect of son preference on fertility (Mutharayappa, et. al, 1997) 2.2.2 Different Policy Regimes Population growth has long been a concern of the Government of India. More than 50 years ago, India became the first country in the developing world to initiate a statesponsored family planning program with the goal of lowering fertility and slowing down the population growth rate. Since then, fertility levels have declined throughout the country, with total fertility rate decreasing from 5.89 births per woman in 1971 to about 3.4 births per woman in 1994 and 2.9 births in 2004. This is still high compared to the replacement level fertility rate of 2.1. The annual percentage growth in population though decreased over the decades is still high at 1.93. The contraceptive prevalence rate (CPR) has also increased from about 10 percent in the early 1970s to around 45 percent in the mid-1990s. Since its inception in 1951, the national family planning program has been dominated by demographic goals. However, the government adopted and promoted highly methodspecific family planning targets in the 60s and 70s, wherein the central government gave to each state method-specific contraceptive targets, which were based on calculations to achieve replacement fertility level by a certain year. These targets were then distributed to the districts by the state governments, and the district administrator or health officers passed them on to the Primary Health Care Center (PHC). In turn, each paramedic 6 working under the PHC was given a target number of new acceptors for each method. In most states the targets for family planning were also given to non-health staff, such as staff of revenue, education and rural development. The district administrator and the state level technocrats and bureaucrats reviewed performance of health care organization, at each level, based on the achievement of the targets. Under the target-oriented planning and monitoring system introduced in 1966, the prevailing idea in dealing with overpopulation was that drastic measures needed to be taken. Education regarding temporary methods of contraception was neglected in favor of encouraging permanent sterilization. Government agencies would have sterilization quotas to fill among the employees, and the inability to meet them was sometimes met with withheld salaries, withdrawal of annual increments or transfer to undesirable posts. Workers were often rewarded with a radio or television if they successfully convinced enough people to opt for the surgery. As a result, providers often over-reported the use of reversible contraceptives or coerced couples into accepting sterilization in order to meet program expectations. Financial incentives were also given to couples opting for sterilization, including monetary award and better chances of loan approval. At its worst, the target-oriented approach became highly coercive during the national emergency of 1975-77. It is alleged that almost 11 million sterilizations were performed in that period. The program focused primarily on sterilization, mostly ignoring client choice and limiting availability to a narrow range of services. This approach was criticized by 7 extending the argument that people in developing countries have large families because they want to and not because they don‟t have access to birth control. It was argued that efforts should be made to increase the demand for a smaller family size rather than increasing the supply of certain birth control measures. Some women‟s organization also viewed this policy as a violation of human rights (Karkal M, 1998). Additionally, the poor quality of care offered by contraceptive providers was considered indicative of the government‟s lack of respect for women‟s health It seemed that in its early years of inception, the national focus on sterilization created an “all or nothing” mentality among Indians towards birth control especially since the awareness of other, temporary methods of contraception was limited (Pathak et al. 1998). The National Family Health Survey conducted in 1992-93 shows that of all contraceptive use at the time, 67% was by female sterilization (compared to 9% male sterilization). The prominence of female sterilization indicates another flaw in the India population control strategies. By targeting women instead of men, the government inadvertently opted for the more hazardous means of birth control. The surgical procedure in women is more difficult and the rate of failure is high, not to mention the danger to the patient, sometimes resulting in death. Thus in the regime of semi-forced, safety-negligent policies, we get what is likely to be a fairly accurate explanation of why family planning efforts failed to curb rampant population growth in India in the 60s, 70s and 80s. When the only option available to 8 many couples is one that is irreversible, not to mention potentially life-threatening, couples would probably be inclined to either no contraceptives at all, or sterilization after enough number of children are born. Such policies no doubt lowered TFR in the short run but were ineffective in improving maternal and child health, reducing gender inequalities and promoting smaller family size as a conscious choice among couples. In short, the program as implemented was shortsighted, insensitive to the needs of clients, and discouraged community involvement. In 1992, the Indian government published its eighth five year plan in which it enlisted several factors leading to poor realization of its family welfare goals. The key deterrent of these goals was the target-based approach and centralized planning followed until then. That same year, the government launched the Child Survival and Safe Motherhood Program to enhance the health of women and children and further reduce maternal and child mortality. The family Welfare Program continued to emphasize family planning services and the child survival components of the new program—especially the expansion of the child immunization services—was implemented earlier than the safe motherhood components. Therefore, the overall national program still offered little to improve the quality or availability of reproductive health services to women The government report acknowledged other problems as well: Both initial and on-the-job training of service providers had been poor; information and education efforts had been ineffective, presenting family planning as a means to contain population growth rather 9 than as a way to improve a family's economic and social status by limiting births; the infrastructure for extension services in some of the more populous regions was lacking, the program had few resources for new initiatives or for strengthening health care services; and the government program allowed for little active involvement of the community. As awareness of the existing program's weaknesses was growing, evidence emerged that data from assessments of the program did not correspond with data from populationbased surveys: Contraceptive use rates calculated from program statistics were inconsistent with observed fertility levels, and official program-based protection rates were significantly higher than survey-based contraceptive prevalence rates. In April 1996, the Indian government decided to abolish method-specific family planning targets throughout the country. In October 1997, India reoriented the national program and radically shifted its approach to more broadly address health and family limitation needs. The new approach, called the Reproductive and Child Health (RCH), involves a more comprehensive set of reproductive and child health services and a focus on client choice, service quality, gender issues and underserved groups, including adolescents, postmenopausal women and men. The goals of the RCH program included removing all targets; phasing out incentive payments to both providers and acceptors of family planning methods; increasing utilization of existing facilities rather than creating new 10 structures; and using the voluntary and private sectors to increase access to services and fill gaps left by public-sector providers. The target-free approach of 1996 meant that centrally determined targets would no longer be the “driving force” behind the program. Instead, the community's service needs would determine the program's priorities. With the new approach, planning was to be decentralized and responsibilities were to reside at the level of the primary health centers: Targets would be set by local health workers, "in consultation with the community at the grassroots level." 2.3 Data Description The reproductive and child health interventions provided by the Government of India are expected to provide quality services and achieve multiple objectives. The GOI desired to re-orient the program and strengthen the services at the out-reach level. The new scheme required decentralization of planning, monitoring and evaluation of services at a lower level i.e., district. The rapid household survey was conducted with these objectives in mind. The need to generate district level data was felt so as to design the course of the new approach. The World Bank provided financial support for carrying out this survey. The GOI decided to undertake Rapid Household Survey of 50 percent of the districts of the country every 11 year. The first phase of this survey was conducted in 1998, the second phase in 1999 and another round of survey was done in 2001-02. During the second phase, the importance of collecting information on the household possession of durable assets was recognized and survey questions were included in the questionnaire. In this survey we only use the 2001-02 dataset, mainly because the districts covered in 2001-02 are not the same as those covered in 1999 and the survey in 2001-02 was more comprehensive than that done in 1999. In every district, 1100 households and all the eligible women (15-44 years) in these households were covered. The data was collected by using uniform questionnaires, sample design and field procedures. The survey thus provided comparable data for all districts covered in any particular year. The main objective of the survey was to estimate the service coverage of the following: 1. Ante Natal Care (ANC) and Immunization services 2. Extent of safe deliveries 3. Contraceptive prevalence 4. Unmet need for family planning 5. Awareness about RTI/STI and HIV/AIDS 6. Utilization of government health services and user's satisfaction 12 A total of 247,018 women aged 15-44 years were surveyed in 289 districts. Information on pregnancies borne up to the survey date was obtained from these women. After excluding women for which inconsistent data was reported/recorded we are left with 244,834 cases. These women report whether or not they ever became pregnant, the year of each birth, their age at that time, whether the birth was a single or multiple birth, sex of the child, whether the child died and if yes, the year and month of the child‟s death. Thus we are able to observe the complete birth history of each woman in our sample. This becomes our original dataset with unit of observation being a woman. The next section summarizes the main characteristics of this dataset. 2.4. Descriptive Statistics Age of the woman at the time of survey: Women aged 15-44 are included in this survey. About 75% of the women report their age to be between 15 and 35. Thus, most women covered in this survey are still fertile. However, when plotting the frequencies of reported age (Figure1), we find a bias in reporting age in multiples of 2 and 5 years. This is expected as most women in this sample hail from rural areas with little or no education, and no existing records of their birth. Thus age of the woman is a very noisy variable in this sample. 13 Year of birth of the child: The earliest child bearing year recorded in this sample is 1970 and goes up to 2003. Since most women were not observed for the whole of 2002 and 2003, we exclude these years from our sample and only use the birth activity of each woman up to 2001. Again this variable is very noisy (Figure 2), with rounding bias in multiples of 2 and 5 years. However, there does seem a general upward time trend for at least the first and second birth. Age of the woman at the time of birth: Surprisingly, this variable is very smooth and our guess is that since this variable is correlated with the two very noisy variables described above, the net effect is to produce such smoothness (figure 3). The mean age of the mother at the time of first birth is only 20 years while that at the time of second birth is only 22 years. An average woman in this sample is susceptible to child birth every 2 years after the age of 18 (Table 2). Number of Births: In this sample, 89% women had at least one birth, 73% had at least 2 births, 50% had at least 3 births, 30% had at least 4 births and only 16% had at least 5 births. Other summary statistics: Rural women are generally less educated and at a higher risk of early marriage in India. We thus present other characteristics of women differentiated by residence type (Table 14 1). We see that almost 69% of women in our sample come from rural areas. Only 43% of rural women can read and write while 71% of urban women can read and write. The average number of schooling years of a rural woman is 7.5 while that of an urban woman is 9.5. About 68% of rural women‟s husband can read and write while 85% of urban women‟s husband can read and write. The mean age at effective marriage (the age at which a woman starts living with her husband) is not much different for rural and urban women. In fact, it differs by only a year and shows that women tend to start families very early on in life, as early as when they are 17 and 18 years old. 2.5. Methodology In this paper I examine the fertility choices made by Indian women. Various factors such as age of the woman, education status, whether the woman comes from an urban or rural setting etc could affect these choices. Certain states in India are known to be poor performing in terms of health and social indicators, and thus women coming from these states would tend to exhibit different fertility choices as compared to women from other states. These states are Bihar, Rajasthan, Uttar Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh. The World Bank came up with an interesting acronym to refer to these states, viz., BIMARU, which means “sickly” in Hindi. In the Indian setting, another factor affecting fertility choice would be gender preferences in the composition of a woman‟s existing children. Thus, a woman with one girl and one boy might make fertility decisions quite different from another woman with two boys. There can be several other factors affecting fertility 15 decisions, but we will mainly consider urban-rural, BIMARU-Other, and parity differentials. Similarly, the various government policies adopted should explain part of the fertility choices of women. 2.5.1 Sample Selection In the Indian context, early marriage and birth are not uncommon phenomenon. In fact, in our data, some women start childbearing as early as at the age of 10. Although modeling fertility choices of these women is important, such an analysis is restricted by lack of enough observations. Thus we consider a woman to reach her reproductive cycle at the age of 13. I assume that in each 12 month period following the age of 13, each woman in the sample makes a decision to have a child or not. There is an issue of age at effective marriage. Since women are asked the age at which they started living with their husband, it may be argued that not all women get married as early as 12-13 and thus one must consider the age at effective marriage as the date when the woman starts making her reproductive decisions. The problem with following this rule is that many times women get married very early but continue to stay with their parents. During that time, even though a woman may not have actually started living with her husband, she may still be exposed to the risk of becoming pregnant if she has conjugal relationship with her husband. Thus this variable may be very noisy and not appropriate for modeling purposes. 16 Thus each period after the age of 13, a woman makes a decision whether or not to have a birth in the following 12 month period. If she is successful, then the woman exits the sample. If she is not, then she remains in the sample for another 12 month period at the end of which she is successful or not. Using this strategy, we create sub-samples of women making decision to have their first, second, third, fourth or fifth birth. In the model of first birth, women enter the sample at 13 and exit when they have their first birth. If the woman has never had a child then she enters at age 13 but exits only in the interview year. Thus each observation in our sample is now a one-year record rather than observation, since each woman may remain in the sample for more than one period. Collecting information in this manner, we get a new data for the birth 1 model with 1,942,876 records. The datasets for models of birth two, three, four and five are similarly created. The only difference is that obviously in these models a woman enters at a later age than the first model. For example, the earliest age at which a woman can make her second birth decision is when she is 14 years old. For births three, four and five, the entry ages are respectively 15, 16 and 17. Also, the woman enters the second birth model only 12 months after her first birth. For example, having had one child, a woman can either choose to have another child or not. If she chooses to have another child, then she enters the sample 12 months after the age at which she had her first child and exit at the age at which she had a second child. On the other hand if she chose not to have another child 17 until the time of survey then she enters the sample 12 months after the age at which she had her first child and remains in the sample until the age at the time of survey. The new datasets thus created have 559,507 records for birth 2, 586,428 records for birth 3, 464,753 records for birth 4 and 277,899 records for birth 5. 2.5.2 Creation of variables Dummies for whether previous children are alive: A dummy variable is included for whether or not each of the existing children is alive at the time the woman is sitting around in a sample. For example, if a woman had her first birth at 14 and second at 20, then she enters the decision making for birth 2 when she is 15 and remains in the sample until she is 20. These dummies tell us for each of the 5 years she was in the sample, her first child was alive or not. Looking at the descriptive statistics, we find that for about 92-94% of the time, a woman‟s previous child is alive. Dummies for whether previous children are boys: We include dummies for various combinations of gender compositions that a woman might have in her existing children. We see that of the women who‟ve had only one child, almost 54% have had a boy. In women with two existing children, 31% have two boys and in women with three existing children, 14.4% have three boys. We also include an interaction term of the boy dummy and time trend, to generate the time profile of women who have had boys in the past. 18 Time since last birth: For each of the year a woman is active in any particular sample, I calculate the number of years that have elapsed since her last birth. If a woman waited more than four years before having another child, I group them together as women waiting for five or more years since last birth. Almost 18% of women who have one existing child have another birth within one year. Generally, it is professed that there should be at least a gap of three years between two consecutive children for better maternal and child health. However in our sample, only 40% women wait more than three years before a second birth. Spacing between two children becomes worse for higher order births, with 38% women waiting three or more years before a fourth birth and 37% women waiting that long before a fifth birth. Policy dummy and time trend variables: We first test our model to see if including a time dummy for each year has more information than simply including a time trend and conclude that fitted probabilities seem to be linear in time. These results are presented in the next section. Thus we include a time trend in our model. The new population policy of the government of India became effective in 1997. We thus include a policy dummy which is one for each year from 1998 onwards. We keep a one year lag in switching the policy dummy on so to allow for the propagation of the new policy. Finally, we interact the policy dummy with years since the policy became effective to see if gains from the new policy are accruing overtime. 19 Other variables: I include age dummies, a dummy for whether the woman belongs to rural area and another dummy for whether the woman belongs to the states of Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan or Uttar Pradesh (BIMARU). 2.5.3 Model I use a probit model to estimate the likelihood of having a birth, controlling for the age of the woman, the gender of her previous children, whether they are alive or not, time since last birth, time trend and policy variables. For example, the probability of having a second birth conditional on a first birth will be as follows: Prob(Birth 2=yes| birth 1=yes) = a1*(child 1 alive?) + a2*(first child boy?) + a3*(2 years since birth 1) + a4*(3 years since birth 1) + a5*(4 years since birth 1) + a6*(5 or more years since birth 1) + b1*(rural) + b2*(BIMARU) + c1*(time) + c2*(Dummy for 1998) + c3*(D98*time) + d1*(age14) + d2*(age15) + ……+ d29*(age42) I run various specifications of the above model, specifically including interactions of the policy variable with different variables in my model to see if the policy benefited certain types of women more than others. Then using the coefficients from the basic models, I evaluate the fitted probabilities of various births with respect to age of the woman. At the 20 time the data was collected (2002), the 1998 policy had only been in effect for four years, but the effect of the policy will take place over the lifetime of the mothers, a much longer period of time. I use the coefficients from the above models, assume that the last year is the ultimate distribution on first, second, third and beyond births, and then simulate the distributions of births for a mother reaching age 13 in the last year of my sample. I do this with and without the D98 policy variable turned on. This is the long run impact of the policy, which will be much greater than the short run impact. Time clusters Vs. Women Clusters: There was an issue of whether the appropriate clustering variable would be year of birth or the mother. Since the new policy is time specific, it can be argued that the appropriate cluster that minimizes the variability within each cluster and maximizes the variability between clusters is years and not the mother. I estimated the models with both types of clusters and find that the Z scores are smaller with the time clusters. This is as predicted since we have fewer clusters of time than of mothers. Also, we only have data for a few years after the implementation of the policy and thus the full impact of it may not be captured in the estimates. As a comparison, I presented some models with women clusters in appendix A. 21 2.6. Results I first estimated all five models with time dummies to allow for full variation in time effects. Table 2.3 reports the coefficients on just the year dummies, while suppressing the coefficients on all other variables. We see that the likelihood of first birth does not get affected over time, presumably because each woman cares to have at least one or two children. In all subsequent births, the effect of the time coefficients is just scalar transformation and relatively constant over time, except after the inception of the policy when the likelihood of second and higher order birth goes down. This can also be seen in figure 2.4 where I plot these time coefficients and in figure 2.5 where I plot the conditional or fitted probabilities for a woman aged 25 years over time. Tables 2.4 and 2.5 each compares the time dummy model with a time trend model for births 1 and 2. The first model in each table uses year dummies; while the second model captures the effects of time using linear time trend variables in each table. A likelihood ratio test rejects the null hypothesis that the time dummies are all in a linear trend, however, that is to be expected with such a large dataset. Thus all subsequent models capture the effect of time using linear time trends instead of a dummy for each year, which enables me to capture the policy impact using a few parameters. It also permits me to examine possible interactions of key variables. Table 2.6 gives regression results from the basic model described above. Coefficients on mother‟s age dummies have been suppressed. Several points can be noted in this table. 22 Firstly, couples seem to care about the result of their immediately preceding childbearing experience. In each of the models, the fact that the immediately preceding child is alive reduces the probability of another birth by a larger value than the life status of other children. Looking at gender compositions, having a first child boy does not affect the probability of second birth: the coefficient on the first boy is statistically significant but has a small impact on the Z score (-.065). As we move to higher order births, we see that the effect of having boys is more pronounced. The coefficients also display a nonmonotonic effect with families that have a mixture of boys and girls having fewer future births than those with all boys or all girls. The largest decline on future births seems to occur for women with 2 boys. Coming from either a rural area or a BIMARU state significantly increases the chances of going for additional births. It is also more likely that these women will go for higher order births as well. In general women like to space their children 2-3 years apart. If too much time has elapsed since the last birth, this would imply either that the woman is old and has already completed her fertility choices or is young but has some reproductive health issues. Birth 2 model does not perform so well because most women want to go for a 2nd child. Therefore, rural women do not look different from urban and women from BIMARU states do not look different from those from other states. Looking at the time trend and the policy variables, we see that over time, the probability of first and second births has remained essentially constant up until 1997, the probability 23 of additional births decreased very slightly in each year without any apparent differential effect on third, fourth or fifth order births. It may be noted that clustering on time seems to be producing lower numbers for the standard errors making the policy dummy statistically insignificant in all five models. This is as expected since we only have 20-30 clusters at the most for each model with such rich data. The standard errors are also getting affected by the fact that very little time elapsed since the introduction of the new policy in our sample. As a comparison, I presented the same results after clustering on women in table A.1 in appendix A. the coefficients on time dummies and policy time interaction are statistically significant in this table In the model of first births, the policy dummy was positive and the time trend since the policy change was positive: the improved prenatal care and information seems to have increased, not decreased the number of first births. For the second birth, the policy effect was also small, with a modest decline observed after two years. The dramatic impact of the policy is observed for the third and higher births. There was a significant decrease in the probability of third and higher births, on the order of .07 or .08 per year. If this trend persists beyond the sample period observed here, this will have a profound effect on the birth pattern and average family size in India. The results from the 1997 policy reforms emphasizing demand side incentives can be contrasted with the female sterilization policy which affected mostly older women who had already made their fertility choices and thus had larger families anyway. After the inception of policy, there is a significant reduction in the likelihood of giving another 24 birth within 2 years of last birth. This indicates that the policy has been effective in encouraging couples to space their first and second birth at least 3 years apart. Table 2.7 presents the same regression as table 2.6 but with the addition of another interaction—the interaction of boy dummy with time to compare the behavior of mothers that have boys overtime to those who don‟t have boys. We see that having boys does not affect the likelihood of second birth over time—presumably since most women care to have at least two children. However, for each subsequent birth, mothers who already have boys are more likely to go for another child in general, but less likely to go for another child overtime. This tells us that women who are lucky to have first few male children would in general be more likely to try and repeat the experience .Overtime the gender preference bias does not seem to reduce with fertility decisions being strongly guided by the number of „boy births‟. As a comparison of the standard errors, table A.2 in appendix A reports results on the same regressions but with women clusters. In tables 2.8a and 2.8b I report Z scores calculated by each of three types of error structures. In general most of our coefficients are losing power because of bootstrapping. Table 2.9 examines alternative interactions between the policy variables and other covariates in the model. Because of colinearity, I did not include all of the interactions in one model, but instead included one set of interactions at a time. The results are suggestive, not conclusive, about which interactions are most important for understanding the impact of the policy reforms. 25 The first model shown in Table 2.9 is the same as the first in Table 2.6. In model 2, I included the interaction of policy dummy with the dummies describing time since the last birth. We see that except for birth 2, after the introduction of the policy there was a significant reduction in the likelihood of another birth within two years following the last birth. This indicates that the policy has been successful in encouraging women to increase the spacing between two children from 2 years to the desired 3 year norm. Similarly, coefficients of the policy gender dummy interaction tell us that since the inception of the policy, there has been a significant reduction in the likelihood of more births if a woman has 1-2 boys already. It appears that the policy reforms worsened rather than improved the gender preference for boys. Results from models 4 and 5 for each birth indicate that the reforms were not particularly effective in reducing the likelihood of additional births in rural areas and BIMARU states. The pattern suggests that second and births and subsequent births may have been increased rather than reduced. Figures 2.6 through 2.10 use the estimated model to generate within sample and outside of sample predictions for a hypothetical average woman who ages in each year given the parameters that would be in effect in that year. Hence the same woman is assumed to instantaneously make all of the decision that would normally occur at ages 13, 14, 15, 17,…, 42. These simulations are useful for seeing what the long run implications would be from any delays of births and reduced fertility. The 1996 and 2002 simulations use actual parameters for those years, while the predictions for 2008 extrapolate to reflect patterns if the trends observed from 1998 to 2002 continued for six more years. We see 26 that an average woman is more likely to have first and second births. This is plausible if the maternal and child health aspect of the new policy improved the maternal health of women. The probability of third and higher order births goes down with time, and by 2008 the probability that a woman would have more than 3 births is less than half of the 1998 value. The expected number of children declines significantly, as the number of mothers with five or more children drops to less than 10 percent of their 1996 values. Thus the new policy should be effective over time in reducing total fertility rates through smaller family sizes. Figures 2.11, 2.12 and 2.13 show that the policies seem to have reduced the probabilities of births in general with relatively larger reduction for families with more boys. In figure 2.14 I compare the likelihood of third birth for a woman who has two girls to one that has two boys for 1996 and then compare it with 2008. Compared to the significant reduction in likelihood of another birth for the mother with two boys, the average mother with two girls seems to have no change in likelihood of third birth. Hence, the 1997 national policy appears not to have reduced the significant problem of gender bias in Indian couples. 2.7. Conclusions In this paper we model the probability of various order birth decisions that a woman could make, controlling for mothers‟ age, time and other covariates. Predicted probabilities of various order births are calculated across time and for mothers of different ages. Finally, model coefficients are used to predict birth decisions of a hypothetical mother in various years. We find modest reduction in conditional birth 27 probabilities as time elapses after the introduction of the new policy. We also find that with the introduction of the new policy, an average mother has improved likelihood of first and second birth and reduced likelihood of having more than two births. If this trend were to continue, by 2008 most mothers would choose to have 2-3 children. Finally, the policy has not been effective in reducing the “son preference” bias as mothers with existing sons are more likely to wait for another child than mothers with no sons. Tables and Figures: Table 2.1: Summary Statistics By region of Residence Rural Urban 167,695 77,139 % rural women 68.6 31.4 % women can read and write 42.8 71.3 Avg # of schooling years % women's husband can read and write Average # of husband' schooling years 7.5 68.1 9.2 9.5 85.6 10.6 Age at effective marriage 17.3 18.6 Number of Observations Table 2.2: Other Descriptive Statistics Variable Number of Observations Mean 244,834 Mean age of Mean age of Mean age of Mean age of Mean age of Mean age of 25 years 20 years 22 years 24 years 26 years 28 years woman at the time of survey woman at first Birth woman at second Birth woman at third Birth woman at fourth Birth woman at fifth Birth Average spacing between 1st and 2nd child Average spacing between 2nd and 3rd child Average spacing between 3rd and 4th child Average spacing between 4th and 5th child 2.65 years 2.61 years 2.53 years 2.49 years 28 Table 2.3: Probit Regression Estimates of the Probability of Various Births with Time Dummies, time clusters Variable Birth 1 Coeff Z -1.011 1972 -1.233 1973 -1.465 1974 -1.406 1975 -1.506 1976 -1.382 1977 -1.307 1978 -1.466 1979 -1.447 1980 -1.280 1981 -1.403 1982 -1.200 1983 -1.406 1984 -1.237 1985 -1.365 1986 -1.308 1987 -1.266 1988 -1.325 1989 -1.335 1990 -1.226 1991 -1.352 1992 -1.227 1993 -1.396 1994 -1.326 1995 -1.341 1996 -1.301 1997 -1.274 1998 -1.278 1999 -1.270 2000 -1.194 2001 -1.050 Constant -1.644 Obs 1942876 Log-Likelihood -574117 Psuedo-R2 0.1397 1971 -1.00 -1.27 -1.52 -1.46 -1.57 -1.44 -1.36 -1.53 -1.51 -1.34 -1.46 -1.25 -1.47 -1.29 -1.42 -1.37 -1.32 -1.38 -1.39 -1.28 -1.41 -1.28 -1.46 -1.38 -1.40 -1.36 -1.33 -1.33 -1.33 -1.25 -1.10 -1.71 Birth 2 Coeff Z -0.156 -0.111 -0.140 -0.111 -0.081 -0.095 -0.118 -0.006 -0.147 0.048 -0.100 0.099 -0.026 0.023 0.019 -0.010 -0.009 0.118 -0.069 0.084 -0.056 0.022 -0.023 0.011 0.003 0.020 -0.062 -0.079 -0.026 -0.773 559507 -312457 0.0948 -20.39 -10.88 -12.60 -8.77 -6.70 -7.88 -9.42 -0.51 -11.77 3.68 -7.65 7.20 -1.91 1.63 1.32 -0.67 -0.62 7.85 -4.62 5.35 -3.61 1.33 -1.40 0.65 0.19 1.15 -3.53 -4.32 -1.42 -9.14 Birth 3 Coeff Z 0.195 0.100 0.191 0.220 0.252 0.145 0.342 0.253 0.434 0.311 0.411 0.358 0.335 0.314 0.436 0.304 0.412 0.283 0.365 0.296 0.358 0.313 0.322 0.233 0.177 0.209 -0.825 586428 -246424 0.1559 25.73 8.81 15.83 18.72 20.41 11.12 26.73 19.41 33.81 23.69 29.79 25.28 23.31 21.34 28.79 20.25 26.01 18.32 22.81 18.06 21.57 18.34 18.73 13.37 9.84 11.48 -3.21 Birth 4 Coeff Z -0.050 -0.118 0.055 -0.110 0.046 -0.025 0.128 0.014 0.077 0.029 0.079 0.022 0.170 -0.034 0.139 0.002 0.091 0.035 0.094 0.071 0.059 -0.036 -0.053 -0.027 -0.003 464753 -159243 0.1799 -4.78 -9.39 3.75 -6.63 2.47 -1.29 6.22 0.66 3.34 1.17 3.06 0.79 5.89 -1.11 4.35 0.05 2.62 0.95 2.47 1.79 1.44 -0.84 -1.20 -0.59 -0.02 Birth 5 Coeff Z 0.370 0.229 0.209 0.171 0.308 0.217 0.313 0.258 0.273 0.230 0.364 0.177 0.322 0.209 0.273 0.265 0.317 0.272 0.304 0.159 0.186 0.193 -0.145 277899 -91639 0.1686 25.92 14.52 10.71 7.70 13.15 8.67 11.82 8.86 8.79 6.93 10.26 4.75 8.09 5.01 6.19 5.74 6.57 5.39 5.81 2.92 3.29 3.28 -0.47 29 Table 2.4: Probit Regression Estimates of the Probability of Birth 1, with and without Time Dummies, time clusters Variable BIMARU States Rural Women Time Trend 1997 Policy Dummy D98*Time Trend Constant Time Dummies: 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Obs Log-Likelihood Wald-Chi2 Psuedo-R2 Coeff Z values Coeff Z values 0.137 0.144 12.03 16.51 -1.644 -1.71 0.137 0.145 0.003 -0.095 0.071 -9.285 12.10 16.63 1.54 -2.03 4.38 -2.27 -1.011 -1.233 -1.465 -1.406 -1.506 -1.382 -1.307 -1.466 -1.447 -1.280 -1.403 -1.200 -1.406 -1.237 -1.365 -1.308 -1.266 -1.325 -1.335 -1.226 -1.352 -1.227 -1.396 -1.326 -1.341 -1.301 -1.274 -1.278 -1.270 -1.194 -1.050 1942876 -574117.3 119177.79 0.1397 -1.00 -1.27 -1.52 -1.46 -1.57 -1.44 -1.36 -1.53 -1.51 -1.34 -1.46 -1.25 -1.47 -1.29 -1.42 -1.37 -1.32 -1.38 -1.39 -1.28 -1.41 -1.28 -1.46 -1.38 -1.40 -1.36 -1.33 -1.33 -1.33 -1.25 -1.10 1942876 -575263.1 118103.26 0.1379 30 Table 2.5: Probit Regression Estimates of the Probability of Birth 2 given Birth 1, with and without Time Dummies Variable Child 1 Alive? Child 1 Boy? BIMARU States Rural Women 2 years since last birth 3 years since last birth 4 years since last birth 5 or more years since last birth Time Trend 1997 Policy Dummy D98*Time Trend Constant 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 No. Of Observations Log-Likelihood Wald-Chi2 Psuedo-R2 Coefficient Z values Coefficient Z values -0.437 -41.21 -0.436 -40.9 -0.065 -16.97 -0.065 -16.97 0.081 6.09 0.081 6.09 0.037 2.57 0.037 2.61 0.913 64.31 0.919 60.07 0.907 124.43 0.909 113.06 0.810 63.65 0.813 62.99 0.500 34.43 0.504 32.87 0.003 1.36 -0.017 -0.37 -0.018 -1.17 -0.780 -9.00 -6.508 -1.54 -0.155 -20.72 -0.110 -10.73 -0.138 -12.11 -0.109 -8.49 -0.078 -6.34 -0.092 -7.39 -0.114 -8.96 -0.003 -0.23 -0.143 -11.21 0.052 3.98 -0.096 -7.29 0.104 7.68 -0.021 -1.56 0.029 2.10 0.025 1.81 -0.004 -0.26 -0.003 -0.19 0.125 9.05 -0.062 -4.55 0.091 6.52 -0.048 -3.51 0.030 2.10 -0.015 -1.03 0.020 1.38 0.012 0.86 0.029 2.04 -0.053 -3.63 -0.069 -4.67 -0.016 -1.08 559507 559507 -312457.93 -312918.27 56811.39 55930.22 0.0948 0.0935 31 Table 2.6: Selected Coefficients on Probit Regression of the Probability of various order Births with time trend, year clusters and Bootstrapped Standard Errors, without Boy Time Interaction Birth 1 Birth 2 Variable Coeff Z Coeff Z Child 1 Alive? -0.436 -38.93 Child 2 Alive? Child 3 Alive? Child 4 Alive? 1 Boy? -0.065 -16.16 2 Boys? 3 Boys? 4 Boys? BIMARU States 0.137 14.32 0.081 6.90 Rural Women 0.145 17.94 0.037 2.91 2 years since last birth 0.919 68.93 3 years since last birth 0.909 117.32 4 years since last birth 0.813 70.45 5 or more years 0.504 36.76 Time Trend 0.003 1.66 0.003 1.24 1998 Policy Dummy -0.095 -1.04 -0.017 -0.20 D98*Time Trend 0.071 2.32 -0.018 -0.62 Constant -9.285 -2.43 -6.297 -1.36 No. Of Observations 1942876 559507 Log-Likelihood -575263 -312920 Wald-Chi2 250983 1070000 Psuedo-R2 0.1379 0.0935 Birth 3 Coeff Z -0.210 -12.27 -0.406 -26.44 Birth 4 Coeff Z -0.215 -23.31 -0.200 -21.80 -0.395 -39.63 -0.211 -0.320 -17.89 -19.70 -0.257 -0.503 -0.445 -22.00 -32.36 -31.33 0.259 0.121 0.947 0.862 0.677 0.202 -0.007 -0.012 -0.041 14.386 586428 -246861 2570000 0.1544 13.77 8.02 44.23 56.73 49.16 10.61 -2.64 -0.16 -1.47 2.57 0.302 0.116 0.874 0.696 0.446 -0.121 -0.008 -0.019 -0.031 16.578 464753 -159504 4190000 0.1785 26.40 10.22 38.58 38.10 16.34 -3.51 -3.19 -0.27 -1.21 3.19 Birth 5 Coeff Z -0.123 -14.97 -0.141 -17.61 -0.167 -27.79 -0.409 -33.34 -0.289 -17.95 -0.504 -35.13 -0.517 -34.43 -0.431 -18.67 0.311 31.67 0.124 9.52 0.815 36.05 0.585 33.43 0.312 13.80 -0.289 -11.74 -0.007 -2.78 0.011 0.11 -0.034 -0.93 13.518 2.81 277899 -91755 3130000 0.1676 32 Table 2.7: Selected Coefficients on Probit Regression of the Probability of various order Births with time trend, year clusters and bootstrapped standard errors Birth 1 Birth 2 Variable Coeff Z Coeff Z Child 1 Alive? -0.436 -37.67 Child 2 Alive? Child 3 Alive? Child 4 Alive? 1 Boy? -1.483 -1.41 2 Boys? 3 Boys? 4 Boys? Boy1*Time 0.001 1.35 Boy2*Time Boy3*Time Boy4*Time BIMARU States 0.137 14.32 0.081 5.76 Rural Women 0.145 17.94 0.037 2.72 2 years since last birth 0.919 79.06 3 years since last birth 0.909 133.51 4 years since last birth 0.813 62.05 5 or more years 0.504 39.05 Time Trend 0.003 1.66 0.002 0.98 1998 Policy Dummy -0.095 -1.04 -0.017 -0.27 D98*Time Trend 0.071 2.32 -0.018 -0.79 Constant -9.285 -2.43 -5.734 -1.14 No. Of Observations 1942876 559507 Log-Likelihood -575263 -312918 Wald-Chi2 250983 . Psuedo-R2 0.1379 0.0935 Birth 3 Birth 4 Coeff Z Coeff Z -0.211 -13.80 -0.215 -21.59 -0.406 -29.48 -0.200 -21.94 -0.396 -33.31 19.083 14.15 17.437 27.522 17.03 31.307 24.173 4.19 7.79 5.30 -0.010 -14.31 -0.009 -0.014 -17.25 -0.016 -0.012 -4.26 -7.93 -5.41 0.259 0.121 0.947 0.861 0.677 0.204 0.001 -0.012 -0.041 -2.921 586428 -246762 . 0.1548 16.89 8.71 55.06 54.40 59.14 10.25 0.58 -0.17 -1.68 -0.70 0.303 0.117 0.873 0.696 0.446 -0.120 0.003 -0.019 -0.031 -4.954 464753 -159450 . 0.1788 22.96 10.87 40.41 46.27 22.56 -4.14 0.78 -0.29 -1.38 -0.77 Birth 5 Coeff Z -0.124 -15.70 -0.140 -17.12 -0.167 -26.66 -0.409 -30.08 14.907 2.96 21.223 4.30 17.655 3.79 20.798 2.52 -0.008 -3.02 -0.011 -4.41 -0.009 -3.91 -0.011 -2.58 0.311 32.96 0.124 9.40 0.815 34.82 0.584 36.54 0.312 15.48 -0.288 -12.57 0.002 0.67 0.011 0.11 -0.034 -0.94 -4.021 -0.64 277899 -91747 . 0.1676 33 Table 2.8a: Bootstrap vs. Standard Z Scores from the Model on Likelihood of Birth 1, 2 and 3 with Time Clusters Birth 1 Variable Coeff Child 1 Alive? Child 2 Alive? 1 Boy? 2 Boys? Boy1*time Boy2*time BIMARU States 0.137 Rural Women 0.145 2 years since last birth 3 years since last birth 4 years since last birth 5 or more years Time Trend 0.003 1998 Policy Dummy -0.095 D98*Time Trend 0.071 Constant -9.285 Observations 1942876 Birth 2 Birth 3 Z Z Z Z (Probit) Z (BS) (OLS) Coeff (Probit) Z (BS) (OLS) 12.10 14.32 12.45 16.63 17.94 13.05 1.54 -2.03 4.38 -2.27 1.66 1.12 -1.04 -2.01 2.32 4.06 -2.43 -1.17 Coeff -0.436 -40.97 -37.67 -41.32 -0.211 -0.406 -1.483 -0.88 -1.41 -1.38 19.083 27.522 0.001 0.85 1.35 1.34 -0.010 -0.014 0.081 6.08 5.76 6.26 0.259 0.037 2.61 2.72 2.94 0.121 0.919 60.05 79.06 48.16 0.947 0.909 112.92 133.51 88.91 0.861 0.813 63.04 62.05 49.83 0.677 0.504 32.87 39.05 33.78 0.204 0.002 1.20 0.98 1.01 0.001 -0.017 -0.37 -0.27 -0.42 -0.012 -0.018 -1.17 -0.79 -1.18 -0.041 -5.734 -1.39 -1.14 -0.83 -2.921 559507 586428 Z Z (Probit) Z (BS) (OLS) -12.03 -26.00 14.77 17.18 -14.93 -17.39 14.90 8.34 43.46 49.83 46.14 8.17 0.49 -0.30 -2.93 -0.59 -13.80 -29.48 14.15 17.03 -14.31 -17.25 16.89 8.71 55.06 54.40 59.14 10.25 0.58 -0.17 -1.68 -0.70 -14.61 -34.83 3.39 2.75 -3.48 -2.85 18.94 9.52 24.98 27.65 26.30 18.71 -1.93 -0.53 -2.05 2.13 Table 2.8b: Bootstrap vs. Standard Z Scores from the Model on Likelihood of Birth 4 and 5 with Time Clusters Variable Child 1 Alive? Child 2 Alive? Child 3 Alive? Child 4 Alive? 1 Boy? 2 Boys? 3 Boys? 4 Boys? Boy1*Time Boy2*Time Boy3*Time Boy4*Time BIMARU States Rural Women 2 years since last birth 3 years since last birth 4 years since last birth 5 or more years Time Trend 1998 Policy Dummy D98*Time Trend Constant No. Of Observations Coeff -0.215 -0.200 -0.396 Birth 4 Z (Probit) Z (BS) -24.12 -21.59 -18.81 -21.94 -37.81 -33.31 Z (OLS) -24.88 -26.75 -22.85 17.437 31.307 24.173 4.12 7.69 5.85 4.19 7.79 5.30 0.92 -0.75 -0.49 -0.009 -0.016 -0.012 -4.18 -7.82 -5.96 -4.26 -7.93 -5.41 -0.98 0.67 0.40 0.303 0.117 0.873 0.696 0.446 -0.120 0.003 -0.019 -0.031 -4.954 464753 24.01 9.16 34.12 41.52 18.16 -3.51 0.97 -0.47 -2.26 -0.96 22.96 10.87 40.41 46.27 22.56 -4.14 0.78 -0.29 -1.38 -0.77 19.23 10.19 21.70 29.69 19.30 5.11 -3.05 -0.57 -1.36 3.34 Birth 5 Coeff Z (Probit) Z (BS) -0.124 -13.24 -15.70 -0.140 -18.14 -17.12 -0.167 -24.92 -26.66 -0.409 -29.19 -30.08 14.907 2.69 2.96 21.223 3.88 4.30 17.655 3.50 3.79 20.798 2.67 2.52 -0.008 -2.75 -3.02 -0.011 -3.97 -4.41 -0.009 -3.61 -3.91 -0.011 -2.73 -2.58 0.311 28.94 32.96 0.124 8.68 9.40 0.815 32.35 34.82 0.584 32.77 36.54 0.312 13.12 15.48 -0.288 -10.81 -12.57 0.002 0.62 0.67 0.011 0.19 0.11 -0.034 -1.89 -0.94 -4.021 -0.60 -0.64 277899 Z (OLS) -13.07 -17.93 -17.00 -13.03 -0.02 -1.51 -2.14 -0.16 -0.03 1.45 2.07 0.10 17.97 10.46 20.67 32.93 15.91 -1.71 -2.75 0.08 -1.38 2.97 34 Table 2.9: Test of significance of selected variables interacted with policy variable, Time Clusters, Bootstrapped Standard Errors Model 1: Model 2: Model 3: Model 4: Model 5: Variable Trend Time trend D98 D98*Time Trend Time since last birth D98 policy dummy D98*Time Trend D98*2 years D98*3 years D98*4 years D98*5 or more years Gender Composition D98 policy dummy D98*Time Trend D98*1 boy D98*2 boys D98*3 boys D98*4 boys BIMARU States D98 policy dummy D98*Time Trend BIMARU Dummy D98*BIMARU Rural Women D98 policy dummy D98*Time Trend Rural Dummy D98*Rural Birth 1 Coeff Z Birth 2 Coeff Z Birth 3 Coeff Z Birth 4 Coeff Z Birth 5 Coeff Z 0.003 -0.095 0.071 0.003 -0.017 -0.018 1.24 -0.20 -0.62 -0.007 -0.012 -0.041 -0.008 -0.019 -0.031 -0.007 0.011 -0.034 -2.78 0.11 -0.93 0.063 -0.018 -0.143 -0.048 -0.024 -0.154 0.86 -0.73 -6.18 -2.25 -1.09 -6.68 0.152 1.44 0.118 1.22 0.085 -0.038 -1.23 -0.030 -1.03 -0.035 -0.232 -12.70 -0.231 -11.50 -0.193 -0.163 -5.60 -0.106 -2.75 0.022 -0.157 -6.27 -0.066 -1.16 0.049 -0.247 -5.93 -0.203 -3.43 -0.115 0.77 -0.84 -7.21 0.66 1.01 -2.23 -0.012 -0.018 -0.009 -0.16 -0.65 -1.38 0.063 -0.041 -0.080 -0.126 0.79 -1.58 -5.13 -6.65 0.080 -0.031 -0.091 -0.136 -0.118 0.94 -1.06 -5.64 -7.08 -7.23 0.091 -0.034 -0.084 -0.087 -0.080 -0.120 1.05 -0.99 -3.83 -4.79 -3.76 -3.73 1.66 -1.04 2.32 -2.64 -0.16 -1.47 -3.19 -0.27 -1.21 -0.063 0.072 0.154 -0.099 -0.69 2.24 17.87 -4.51 -0.045 -0.018 0.062 0.087 -0.57 -0.66 4.45 2.86 -0.054 -0.041 0.227 0.127 -0.77 -1.64 10.29 4.07 -0.037 -0.031 0.290 0.044 -0.53 0.008 -1.30 -0.034 15.58 0.308 2.11 0.007 0.07 -0.71 17.70 0.30 -0.065 0.071 0.152 -0.045 -0.84 2.58 18.02 -2.07 -0.054 -0.018 0.025 0.056 -0.81 -0.72 1.45 2.58 -0.054 -0.65 -0.041 -1.32 0.106 5.21 0.0597 2.46 -0.054 -0.031 0.104 0.048 -0.85 -1.11 6.69 1.76 -0.13 -0.79 6.13 1.63 -0.013 -0.034 0.115 0.032 35 Figure 2.1: Age of the Woman at the Time of Survey 7 6 % Frequency % Frequency 5 4 3 2 1 0 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 Age Figure 2.2: Year of Various Order Births 9 8 Birth 1 Birth 2 7 Birth 3 Birth 4 Birth 5 5 4 3 2 1 Year of Birth 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 1975 1974 1973 1972 1971 0 1970 % Frequency 6 36 Figure 2.3: Age of Woman at the Time of Various Births 35000 30000 Birth 1 Birth 2 25000 Number of Women Birth 3 Birth 4 Birth 5 20000 15000 10000 5000 0 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age Figure 2.4: Time Coefficients from Models of Various Order Birth likelihood 0.500 Coefficient Estimate 0.000 Birth1 Birth2 -0.500 Birth3 Birth4 Birth5 -1.000 -1.500 -2.000 Year 37 Figure 2.5: Predicted Probabilities of Birth 1, 2 and 3 for Age 25 Women Using Year Dummies 0.4 0.35 Conditional Probabilities 0.3 0.25 0.2 0.15 0.1 Birth1 0.05 Birth2 Birth3 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 1979 1978 1977 1976 1975 1974 1973 1972 1971 0 Figure 2.6: Density Function For Birth 1 in 1996, 2002 & 2008, By Age of Woman 0.20 0.18 Prob of Birth 1(96) 0.16 Prob of Birth 1(02) Prob of Birth 1(08) Probability of Birth 1 0.14 0.12 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman 38 Figure 2.7: Density Function of Birth 2 for 1996,2002 & 2008, By Age of Mother 0.16 0.14 Prob of Birth 2(96) Prob of Birth 2(02) 0.12 Probability of Birth 2 Prob of Birth 2(08) 0.10 0.08 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.00 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Mother Figure 2.8: Density Function of Birth 3 for 1996, 2002 & 2008, By Age of Mother 0.09 0.08 0.07 Prob of Birth 3(96) Prob of Birth 3(02) Probability of Birth 3 0.06 Prob of Birth 3(08) 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman 39 Figure 2.9: Density Function of Birth 4 for 1996, 2002 & 2008, By Age of Mother 0.06 0.05 Prob of Birth 4(96) Probability of Birth 4 0.04 Prob of Birth 4(02) Prob of Birth 4(08) 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman Figure 2.10: Density Function of Birth 5 for 1996, 2002 & 2008, By Age of Mother 0.04 0.04 0.03 Prob of Birth 5(96) Probability of Birth 5 Prob of Birth 5(02) 0.03 Prob of Birth 5(08) 0.02 0.02 0.01 0.01 0.00 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 Age of Woman 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 40 Figure 2.11: Density Function of Woman with No Boys & 2 Previous Children for 1996, 2002 & 2008 0.1 0.09 0.08 Prob (no Boys, 1996) Prob (no Boys, 2002) Probability of Birth 0.07 Prob (no Boys, 2008) 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman Figure 2.12: Density Function of Woman with 1 Boy amongst 2 Previous Children for 1996, 2002 & 2008 0.09 0.08 0.07 Prob (1 Boy, 1996) Prob (1 Boy, 2002) Probability of Birth 0.06 Prob (1 Boy, 2008) 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman 41 Figure 2.13: Density Function of Woman with Both Previous Children as Boys for 1996, 2002 & 2008 0.09 0.08 0.07 Prob (2 Boys, 1996) Prob (2 Boys, 2002) 0.06 Probability of Birth Prob (2 Boys, 2008) 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Age of Woman Figure 2.14: Density Function of Woman with Both Previous Children as Boys Vs. Girls for 1996 & 2008 0.1 0.09 0.08 Prob (2 Girls, 1996) Prob (2 Girls, 2008) Probability of Birth 0.07 Prob (2 Boys, 1996) Prob (2 Boys, 2008) 0.06 0.05 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42