Resources for the Future Workshop on Learning-By-Doing in Energy Technologies

advertisement
Resources for the Future Workshop on Learning-By-Doing in Energy Technologies
Position paper by Marvin Lieberman
UCLA Anderson Graduate School of Management
June 2, 2003
Learning-by-doing is a pervasive economic phenomenon. “Learning curves” are
commonly estimated to characterize and forecast the rate of cost reduction. These curves
typically show a log-linear relationship between unit cost and accumulated output.
Efforts to document learning curves have been carried out at very different levels of
aggregation. The earliest studies, which focused on individual workers, tasks or teams,
showed a regularity of cost reduction with increases in cumulative output. Later studies
applied the concept more broadly to products or product categories produced by entire
firms. In the 1970s, the Boston Consulting Group (BCG) gained some notoriety by
demonstrating the pervasiveness of this phenomenon; BCG dubbed it the “experience
curve” to distinguish it from the more micro-level concept of the learning curve. Other
studies at the level of entire industries have demonstrated that cost reductions for product
categories often follow a “technological progress function” driven by growth in industry
cumulative output. Thus, similar empirical regularities seem to hold for learning-based
cost dynamics at very different levels of aggregation.
One source of confusion is that the term “learning curve” is often used to describe the
process of cost reduction with accumulated experience, regardless of the level of
analysis. While there are striking similarities in “learning-by-doing” that apply across
aggregation levels, there are also important differences. Presumably, the learning curves
of greatest interest in this workshop are those corresponding to the industry-wide
“technological progress function.”
Despite confirmation as a strong empirical regularity, learning-by-doing lacks a
compelling theoretical rationale. Hence, learning-by-doing has largely remained outside
of the mainstream of the economics field. Many economists approach the concept of
learning-by-doing with a degree of skepticism. Some theoretical models of learning-bydoing have been developed, based on processes of optimal search with decreasing
returns. As the search process proceeds, further sources of improvement become
increasingly difficulty to uncover. One analogy is to a mine where the richest ore sources
are most likely to be discovered first.
In some ways, the learning curve can be regarded as a simple representation of a host of
micro-level improvement processes. The curve represents the sum of various underlying
effects. The net result of these many influences is a curve that appears smooth and
regular when plotted in log-log space, even though it may be more of a step function
when examined in close detail.
The standard form of the learning curve plots the logarithm of unit cost verses the
logarithm of accumulated output. Thus, cumulative output is typically considered to be
the driver of cost reduction. Numerous studies have shown that cumulative output serves
as a reasonably good proxy for the various factors that induce learning in most industries.
Nevertheless, there is no reason to take cumulative output as the sole driver of the
learning process. In my own studies of the chemical industry, I found that cumulative
investment was also an important driver of cost reduction, although less important than
cumulative output. Many improvements in chemical processes are embodied in new
capital equipment, so it is not surprising that investment plays an important role.
Moreover, some chemical products experienced periods of major technical change, in
addition to the more incremental change represented by the standard learning curve.
During such periods the learning curve showed discontinuities with steeper than average
cost reduction. Part of the learning effect in the chemical industry was also due to
economies of scale. Over time, firms built increasingly larger plants as they solved the
technical problems needed to make such plants economically feasible. An additional
factor was R&D; I found that higher R&D spending raised the slope of the learning
curve. Ultimately, learning in the chemical industry was not a simple function of
cumulative output, even though cumulative output provided the best overall proxy for
learning.
Other researchers have obtained similar findings, although the importance of specific
factors tends to vary with industry characteristics. In industries with a high labor
component, for example, the learning process is more sensitive to human factors (such as
employee turnover) than in the capital-intensive chemical industry. Studies suggest that
such intrinsic characteristics may cause industries to differ in their learning curve
“slopes” when unit cost is plotted against cumulative volume. Industries also differ in
terms of the more detailed factors into which the learning curve might be decomposed.
This workshop is concerned mostly with “technological progress functions” relating to
energy technologies, at the industry level. My studies of the chemical industry were
focused at that level; however, most current research on learning curves considers the
more disaggregate level of individual firms and organizational units. (See, for example,
the many studies reviewed in Linda Argote’s 1999 book, Organizational Learning.)
These studies show that learning rates vary greatly among organizations, and that
learning should not be viewed as a uniform or automatic process driven simply by
increases in cumulative output. Recent studies focus on issues such as organizational
“forgetting,” and transfer of learning across organizational units. The findings of these
studies are of potential relevance for firms that wish to optimize their rates of learning.
From a policy standpoint, one important feature of learning-by-doing is that it can be
regarded partly as an investment. Greater production today promotes cost reductions that
provide savings in the future. Given this investment component, under some conditions
it may be appropriate for private firms or governments to subsidize some part of the
current production cost.
If learning is proprietary and firms have a long time horizon, they may recognize this
investment component and subsidize part of current cost. For example, automobile
producers such as Toyota and Honda may now be pursuing such subsidies in the
production of their hybrid cars. However, if uncertainty is high, or if spillovers to
competitors reduce the proprietary value of learning, firms will not find it in their interest
to subsidize learning. In such cases, some form of public subsidy or incentive may be
justified.
Download