An opportunity cost theory of US treaty behavior* Judith Kelley and Jon Pevehouse WORKING PAPER: DO NOT CITE WITHOUT PERMISSION Please do not cite without authors’ permission jkelley@duke.edu pevehous@polisci.wisc.edu * We thank Kathryn Chylla, Frank Halloran at the US State Department, John Gamble for sharing his data with us, and participants at the November 6, 2010 Duke-Harvard Foreign Relations Workshop, "The Political Economy of U.S. Foreign Relations Law,” Duke University. This paper was also presented at the Annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Seattle, WA, 2011, and the Annual meeting of the International Studies Association, San Diego, April 1-4, 2012. For very helpful comments we thank workshop participants at Georgetown University, Florida State University, the University of Pennsylvania, and Cornell University. We also thank Mark Pollack for additional comments. 1 An opportunity cost theory of US treaty behavior What factors influence whether the US participates in global treaty-based cooperation? Traditional explanations hold that states act based on their national interest and, for the US this means that as long as two-thirds of senators are convinced that the benefits of the treaty outweigh the costs, the US should participate in the treaty. However, at times the US fails to join treaties that appear to have the support of the requisite 2/3 of senators, or even quite uncontroversial treaties. This has long ago earned the senate a reputation as “the graveyard of treaties.” This paper argues that this occurs because the constitutional advice and consent process imposes opportunity costs for both the president and the senate in terms of senate floor time, and that these costs slow down the process significantly or even block it completely. A statistical analysis of all multilateral treaties after 1967 shows that while, as expected, the traditional political and treatyspecific factors influence a treaty’s success in the senate, so do opportunity cost. This means that the president and the senate do not simply consider each treaty on its own merits; rather treaties may be sidelined due to the opportunity costs associated with dealing with them. The US Senate can be quite speedy at ratifying treaties. In March 2003, the US signed the NATO protocols to enable the accession of several new members. By April the president had sent the treaty to the senate and by May the senate provided its advice and consent. However, such speed is rare. For example, also in 2003, the World Health Organization concluded the Framework Convention on Tobacco Control (FCTC) and the United States signed the treaty. Then Senator Barack Obama, a long time tobacco control advocate also fighting personal tobacco addiction, joined in a letter urging President George W. Bush to the send the FCTC to the senate for ratification. Now President Barack Obama has now been president for four years. Why then has he failed to transmit the treaty? Similarly, in 1994, President Clinton transmitted the Law of the Sea and the Agreement on Part XI to the Senate. Since then, the Law of the Sea has been on the Treaty Priority List1 of Presidents Clinton, Bush, and Obama. Moreover, it has had the support of over two-thirds of the Senate.2 Why then has it remained unperfected? Why do some treaties remain on the president’s desk or remain tabled in the Senate despite strong incentives to ratify the treaty? 1 Administrations have begun to issue “treaty priority list” for each new Congress. These typically list (1) treaties currently on the Committee's calendar on which the Administration supports Senate action at this time, (2) treaties currently on the Committee's calendar on which the Administration does not support Senate action at this time, and (3) treaties not yet before the Committee on which the Administration is actively reviewing treaty transmittal packages with a view toward Senate action prior to adjournment of the Congress. For an example, see http://www.state.gov/documents/organization/116355.pdf and http://globalsolutions.org/files/general/White_House_Priorities_List.pdf 2 http://www.nytimes.com/gwire/2009/05/07/07greenwire-sen-kerry-looks-for-window-to-ratify-law-of-th12208.html 2 In this paper, we formulate an answer to these questions. Specifically, we assess the question: Once the United States has signed an international agreement that requires Senate advice and consent, what explains how long the president takes to transmit it to the Senate, and if he does transmit it, what explains how long the Senate takes to bring it to a vote or whether the Senate ever gives it advice and consent at all? Indeed, the US is often in the forefront of treaty creation and plays a formative role in the formulation of a majority of treaties. Why then does the US lagged behind other states in treaty ratification? One study of 76 treaties open to all states and concluded between 1990 and 2005 on a broad range of issue areas found that the US had only 34 treaties, far behind European countries and the second lowest among Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries (Elsig, Milewicz et al. 2012: 8). Legal scholars have increasing pointed to the Senate’s failure to ratify treaties, yet scholars have not explained why this occurs so often. Although there has been some analysis of the Senate advice and consent process for presidential nominations (McCarty and Razaghian 1999 ; Binder and Maltzman 2002 ; Derouen, Peake et al. 2005), scholars have paid very little attention to the US treaty advice and consent process. We know of only one broad and systematic examination of the US treaty process across treaties and time (Krutz and Peake 2009), one study of determinants of treaty reservations attached by the Senate (Auerswald and Maltzman 2003), and a few analyses of security treaties (Krepon and Caldwell 1991 ; Delaet and Scott 2006), or case studies of individual treaties (Evans and Oleszek 2003).3 There has been more attention to what determines whether the US administration treats a particular international agreement as an executive agreement or as a treaty that requires Senate advice and consent (Martin 2005 ; Krutz and Peake 2009), than to the advice and consent process itself. Yet, the Senate advice and consent process for treaties is important for several reasons. First, the treaties that the administration determines requires senate advice and consent tend to be, by constitutional design, matters of significant US commitments, sometimes involving delegation of significant authority or resources. Second, whether the Senate provides advice and consent, and whether the US ultimately ratifies treaties influences how the US participates in international cooperation. For example, a lack of advice and consent, and the subsequent delay in US treaty ratification prevents the US from participating fully in the organizational work that flows from the treaty. Thus, the US may be relegated to observer status, despite actively cooperating with the treaty organization, a point the president sometimes bemoans in his transmittal letters to the senate.4 Furthermore, given its global leadership role, US participation can be pivotal in 3 Note that there has been more emphasis on whether the president seeks to evade the senate advice and consent process through use of executive agreements, a debate we set aside for now, but see our discussion under data clarifying our sample identification process. (Martin 2005 ; Krutz and Peake 2009) 4 See for example President Bill Clinton’s Message Letter of Transmittal accompanying the South Pacific Regional Environment Programme Agreement. Treaty Doc. 105-32, November 7, 1997, in which the submittal letter from the State Department, which the president sends to the senate along with the president’s own message of transmittal, notes that lack of US ratification will leave the United States without influence on important committees within the treaty organization. 3 whether international cooperation on a particular issue succeeds. In cases such as the Kyoto Protocol on global warming, the absence of Senate advice and consent may diminish global efforts to cooperate on important issues, thus having important effects not only for the US but for other states as well. Lastly, during negotiations of a treaty, when other states surmise that the US will not ultimately join the treaty regime, the US loses influence over the negotiations (Galbraith 2012). This in turn further diminishes the likelihood that the US will join the treaty and thus bolsters even further skepticism about US good faith during treaty negotiation. A former Legal Advisor to the State Department stressed this as a big problem for US negotiators, because “It may well be that we will sign the treaty, but our negotiating partners have no confidence that the executive branch will necessarily be able to get a potentially controversial treaty through the Senate (Johnson 2010).” Note that this dynamic also is contradictory to existing international relations theory: two-level games literature traditionally suggests that domestic ratification difficulties can grant international negotiators leverage in negotiation (Putnam 1988). Thus, treaties requiring Senate advice and consent represent a particularly interesting body of international agreements and it is important to understand how this domestic process influences the US ability to cooperate with other nations. Traditional national interest arguments In the international relations theory, most existing analysis of treaty ratification is crossnational and treats states as rational, unitary actors. Indeed, nearly all of the analysis of treaty ratification examines cross-national behavior on a given treaty. Thus, several scholars compare decisions across states for specific treaties and demonstrate various logics that drive state participation in treaties (Fredriksson 2000 ; Moravcsik 2000 ; Simmons 2000 ; Buthe and Milner 2008 ; Simmons 2009). The logic may vary across issues, but the underlying assumption usually is that states are unitary actors and that they join treaty regimes that are in their national interest. Sometimes the benefit is a signaling value that states attribute to joining a treaty even if they have no intent of observing it (Vreeland 2008), but the fact remains that a state is thought to weigh the pros and cons of the treaty and join if the benefits outweigh the costs. Based on this logic, if a treaty is in the interest of the US, the US should ratify it. Thus, the US failure to join various treaties such as the International Criminal Court is explained by the costs to the US of agreeing to the treaty as exceeding the benefits. That is, existing theory essentially base state decisions to join treaty regimes as only on how the attributes of the treaty serve the national interest. However, although this frame of analysis can take us a long way in understanding the fate of many treaties, it leaves some puzzles, because there appear to be several cases where the US clearly values a treaty, yet does not ratify it. For example, US negotiators sometimes push hard for certain provisions but then, even when the US manages to obtain nearly all its demands, the US fails to ratify the treaty. The American efforts to renegotiate Article 11 of the Law of the Sea relating to deep sea bed mining are a case in point. Sometimes the US even initiates treaties and shapes their form, and then fails to 4 ratify them. For example, the US has not joined the ILO Convention (185) on Seafarers’ Identity Documents, which was written in direct response to 9/11 terrorist attacks and aimed to strengthen port of entry security. The US was the main driver behind this convention and the tripartite US delegation voted unanimously to adopt it in 2003. But the treaty has been held up in the Senate, supposedly due to a visa provision that runs contrary to some federalism provisions in US immigration law.5 But why would federalism trump national security? Thus, the strong negotiating behavior of the US in this case signals that even treaties that are in the US interest can remain unperfected. Similarly, if the US should become party to treaties that are in their interests, it is also a puzzle why the US sometimes participates actively in some treaty regimes, seeking to meet the requirements and build their organizational structures, but does not ratify the underlying treaty. For example, the US played a major part in the treaty negations for the Biodiversity Convention and has an excellent compliance record, but has not ratified the treaty itself. Likewise, the US participates in research and development for the Agreement on Conservation of Albatrosses and Petrels. President George Bush Jr. transmitted the treaty to the senate in 2008, 7 years after its conclusion, endorsing it as being fully in the US interest, yet the treaty still lingers in the Senate. Why does the United States actively support and promote the use of international bodies but then fails to ratify the treaty documents generating these bodies? The US behaves in other ways that signal that it endorses some treaties that it nonetheless has not ratified. In trade law and other law, the US will refer to unperfected treaties as precedential for US-authored treaties. For example, although the US has not ratified most ILO Conventions, it is reinforcing the content of many those unratified conventions in a trade agreement with Peru (Charnovitz 2008 96).Why does the US incorporate into trade agreements various human rights conditions (Hafner-Burton 2009), some of which the US has not ratified and accepted into its own domestic law? This suggests that, paradoxically, the US is not necessarily opposed to the general content of many of these international treaties, and indeed that the US is interested in their existence as a source of norm development. Classic domestic explanations The classic response to these puzzles is that the procedural rules in the advice and consent process enables 1/3 of senators, or the senate foreign relations chair to block treaties. This argument recognizes that domestic politics and institutions play an important role in foreign policy (Allison 1971 ; Stoll 1984 ; Putnam 1988). Key to these arguments about two-level games is that domestic veto players can credibly threaten to withhold support for ratification (Mansfield, Milner et al. 2005). This is why Haller and Holden have argued that a supermajority ratification rule such as the one in the senate increases the bargaining position of a country, but it does so at the cost of also increasing the risk that a treaty fails to become ratified (Haller and Holden 1997). In an analysis of 5 President's Committee on the International Labor Organization, Esther Brimmer, Assistant Secretary, Bureau of International Organization Affairs, Department of Labor, Washington, DC, May 4, 2010 http://www.state.gov/p/io/rm/2010/141482.htm 5 ILO convention ratification by 17 countries, Boockmann also found that partisan preferences of government parties influence ratification probabilities significantly, but only when one considers the power allocation within the governing body (Boockmann 2006). Thus, a major obstacle to the Senate treaty process is the political opposition to a treaty in the senate (Krutz and Peake 2009). However, even traditional understandings of partisanship and domestic politics leave Senate advice and consent behavior as a puzzle. For example, why do some treaties have 67 votes in support on the Senate floor as well as the support of the president and Senate foreign relations chair, yet do not get brought up for a vote? The Law of the Sea clearly meets this threshold. Others appear to have equally strong support. For example, the Rotterdam Convention and the Stockholm Convention each made it out of committee, but although both Republican and Democratic foreign relations committee chairs have supported them, recommending their ratification, they have failed to move forward. Thus, many treaties appear to have broad domestic political support, signaling that politicians generally assess them as being in the interests of the US, yet they linger. There is also a range of possible legal reasons that the US does not ratify treaties that it generally supports. One such reason is that the US may simply not derive any added benefit from ratifying it. This point has been made specifically regarding human rights treaties, where the stability of the US constitution and the existence of a strong and independent judiciary already guarantees citizens protection in many areas and where it is not necessary to actually ratify the treaty for a state to obtain its benefits (Bradley 2010 331, 333). Relatedly, some treaties may stall because they conflict with the federal structure of US policy making and related concerns about whether policy making power resides at the federal or state level (Bradley 2010 330). Still, these explanations tend to be very idiosyncratic to each treaty situation. As with the basic national interest arguments, clearly the legal and basic institutional arguments may often go a long way towards explaining the US behavior towards international treaties. However, we propose another explanation that may be at work in addition to these factors and may help explain the puzzling outcomes. Opportunity costs This paper presents an opportunity cost theory of treaty ratification. We argue that the US sometimes delays or derails treaties not because they engender such opposition that passing them would be impossible given the institutional rules, but because the President and the Senate often does not prioritize them because they consider the opportunity cost of doing so too costly. This occurs because the legislative agenda is a fixed and highly prized resource. Advice and consent as a two-step process Before elaborating the opportunity cost theory, it is important to consider the treaty ratification process itself. Indeed, the fate of US treaties, and thus an opportunity cost 6 theory of treaty ratification, cannot be examined without considering the process more fully. After the US signs an agreement, the president decides whether to transmit it to the Senate, and then the Senate Foreign Relations Committee (SFRC) decides whether to recommend the treaty and pass it out of committee along with a treaty document drafted by that Committee. This treaty document then moves to the floor for debate, possible amendments, and a vote. To provide its advice and consent, the Senate must pass the document with no less than a two-thirds majority. Only then can the president deposit the instrument of ratification, formally ratifying the treaty.6 The nature of the two-step process means that it is necessary to account for behavior at both stages to understand outcomes. We therefore theorize (and model) the treaty advice and consent process as a two-step process. The first step, the transmittal decision, is important to consider, because it may well be strategic. Indeed, when President Clinton wanted to introduce the Convention on the Rights of the Child in 1995, Senator Jessie Helms, Chair of the SFRC, felt so strongly about it that he, along with 26 cosponsors, introduced a Senate Resolution urging the President to not transmit the Convention to the Senate. Thus, if some Senators are very opposed to a treaty, they have incentives to voice this opposition, which can be distracting or politically harmful for the president. In addition, because the president usually endorses the treaty in the transmittal letter, the act of transmittal is a request to the Senate for support for the endorsement. Thus, there may be a reputational cost to transmitting treaties and have them stall (Krutz and Peake 2009 140). For several reasons, withholding transmittal can therefore be politically astute. Thus, when theorizing the senate advice and consent process, it is important to consider both the factors that influence the president’s transmittal decision and the senate’s advice and consent process. The fixed political agenda space and policy priorities Opportunity costs arise when resources are fixed. We argue that political agenda space is such a fixed resource; there are only so many things a president can do, and only so much Senate floor time. When prioritizing legislative agenda time, Senators and presidents favor issues that increase their popularity and chances for reelection (Mayhew 1974). This usually means that senators focus foremost on domestic politics, which usually drives elections (Abramson, Aldrich et al. 1987). This is not because the public does not care about international issues. Indeed, the US public tends to care deeply about foreign policy issues that have direct effects such as war and trade, and as a result, Senators also devote considerable time to these. Indeed, trade agreements can engender considerable domestic debate, as in the case of NAFTA, and when the US engages in war, the public clearly cares deeply (Howell and Pevehouse 2007). However, these issues are not typically the topics of treaties submitted for Senate advice and consent. Trade related treaties are usually handled through congressional-executive agreements, and although some article II treaties may be related indirectly to war, issues of specific wars are usually not treaty issues. 6 In addition, at any time a treaty can be returned to the president or, if the committee reports the treaty but no vote transpires, the treaty can go back to the committee. 7 Thus, Article II treaties are rarely the bread and butter of domestic politics. Voters may hold preferences on a given treaty, but treaties rarely motivate voters. For example, the US public has largely supported the International Criminal Court created by the Rome Statute. However, confessed support for the ICC in treaty has not translated into a mobilized voter base for the Rome Statute, and the issue is therefore not one that Senators consider integral to their re-election. The implication of this insight is central: the decision to push a treaty through the advice and consent process may be less about an objective examination of costs and benefits of the treaty (as assumed by traditional analysis) than about the benefit of spending time on the treaty relative to the benefit of other possible agenda activity that may produce important domestic legislation such as health care reform, for example. In other words: senate advice and consent depends on the associated opportunity costs. The opportunity cost can manifest itself for different types of treaties. Even non-divisive treaties require some presidential attention to move through the process (Johnson 2010), and therefore these may simply fall by the wayside because they gather little attention. Other, more important treaties might also be affected by the opportunity cost, however. Even if opponents might not technically command the requisite 1/3 of senators to block the treaty, they may impose such high time costs that make the Senate and president are reluctant to send sending onto the agenda of the Senate when there are many competing priorities. So how great is the opportunity cost of treaty ratification in terms of presidential and senate time? First and foremost, the opportunity cost is a function of the value of the legislative agenda space at any given point: It depends on what else could be accomplished with the time. This theory leads to a quite unconventional proposition. Whereas pure institutional analysis would expect the president to be most likely to transmit treaties to the senate when he has a lot of political support and can garner the requisite 2/3 vote, the opportunity cost theory predicts that this is exactly the time when he will be least likely to spend time on treaties. When the president commands support in the Senate, the chances of passing valuable legislation is higher (McCubbins and Cox 1993). In other words, when the president commands support in the Senate, there is a surplus of political capital and thus opportunity to move valuable legislation on the political agenda and the calendar of the Senate. This boon of political capital raises the opportunity cost of the Senate agenda time. Thus, the greater the president’s political support, the less likely he will be to transmit treaties to the Senate. In addition, although the House does not have a formal role in the treaty process, it does have a role in the domestic legislation process. Because of this, we expect the level of political support in both the House and the Senate should be relevant in the decision to transmit. That is, with sizable majorities in both legislative chambers, the President would be especially unlikely to transmit treaties to the Senate. This leads to two observable propositions: 8 P1: The more co-partisans the president has in the House and the Senate, the less likely he will be to transmit treaties to the senate. P2: The greater the president’s approval ratings, the less likely he will be to transmit treaties to the senate. In the Senate, the value of floor time is more based on the political cycle. When the president transmits a treaty the time costs rarely materialize in the very near term, because the treaty has to pass through the SFRC process, which takes some time. However, if the Senate places a treaty on the legislative calendar, then the impending time cost is fairly immediate. This means that the Senate can be more sensitive in the actually scheduling of treaties. Our opportunity cost theory predicts that the Senate will be less inclined to spend time on treaties during times when Senators want to instead push for domestic legislative victories. Time is always scarce in the legislative branch (Hall 1996), but there is variation in that scarcity. In election years, but particularly in presidential election years, domestic legislation becomes too contentious to pass, particularly as the election grows nearer. Indeed, it is expected that as the election season begins, the president and Congress do not want to take major policy positions that could upset the electorate in the home district.7 This lowers the cost of Senate time. This is especially true when the president is not up for reelection, because the Senate is considered rather powerless to enact domestic legislation at that time. Thus, calendar time becomes more plentiful. This leads to the following expectation: P3: In presidential election years, and especially during “lame duck” years, treaty ratification will be faster. P4: The senate is more likely to spend time on the treaty advice and consent process in the fall of election years, than during the rest of the year. Finally, the opportunity costs for the senate is greater when it has to vote on not only the treaty itself, but also consider implementing legislation. The president often states in the transmittal letter whether the treaty requires implementing legislation, and such requirements will demand that the senate spends additional time on the implementing legislation. In a busy senate, our opportunity cost theory would therefore expect requirements for implementing legislation to impose additional delays or cause the treaty to be set aside. P5: Treaties that require implementing legislation will take longer to receive Senate advice and consent. 7 Recall much of the controversial negotiations about the debt ceiling revolved around whether there would be another debate that would be needed closer to the 2012 elections, with the clear implication that no rational Congressperson would want to engage in that debate in the shadow of an election. 9 Revisiting other factors As noted in the discussion already, standard political institutional analysis expects that the Senate will not give advice and consent to treaties when 2/3 of Senators or the SFRC chair oppose the treaty. As a matter of general expectation, Republican politicians should be expected to be more opposed to treaty commitments. Republican Senators traditionally stress sovereignty and conservative morals, both of which are elements that are at times seen as threatened by multilateral agreements. For example, past work suggests that Republicans are more reluctant to support arms treaties (Krepon and Caldwell 1991 ; Delaet and Scott 2006). Scholars have also found that “conservative Senates and pivotal senators systematically exploit the right to add reservations” (Auerswald and Maltzman 2003 1097), suggesting that conservative Senators are more cautious of offering their advice and consent. In general the greater tendency for more conservative politicians to oppose international treaty commitments thus leads us to expect in general that democratic presidents will be more inclined to transmit treaties, and that the more conservative the SFRC chair and the 2/3 senator the slower treaties will progress through the process. However, actual support for passage may not be the only concern. Decision-making rules, veto points, and legislative procedures open up the opportunity for small groups of Senators to continue debate nearly indefinitely (Moravcsik 2005 150-151). This means that a small group of the most conservative senators can essentially block a vote although they do not necessarily have sufficient votes to defeat it were it brought to a vote. Based on the opportunity cost theory, such opposition is important because it magnifies the expected time the president or senator foreign relations chair would expect debate on the treaty to take and thus may deter the president or senate from action. Senator Richard Lugar (R-Ind) lamented this state of affairs in a 2009 speech to the Washington Foreign Law Society: “[T]oo often, narrow objections to treaties are allowed to prevent any Senate consideration. The Senate’s rules allow the Senate to vote to cut off debate on a treaty, and thereby to ensure that a vote on the treaty may occur. But the Senate’s leadership – both Democrat and Republican -- has been reluctant to exercise this option in recent years. Their concern appears to be that doing so would require the Senate to spend too much time debating particular treaties, to the exclusion of other matters that have greater domestic political appeal. As a result, the Senate has not held a significant debate on a treaty since the late 1990s, when the Senate debated and approved the Chemical Weapons Convention, and debated and rejected the Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty. In essence, for more than a decade, treaties have had to meet a standard for Senate approval 10 that approaches unanimity -- far exceeding the already difficult two-thirds majority requirement established in the Constitution.”8 In sum, based on both the opportunity cost theory and on a simple preference-based theory, the general expectation is that the more opposed Senate veto players, including the most conservative senators, are to a treaty, the longer the Senate advice and consent process will take. As also noted, there are many legal properties, which may explain the fates of particular treaties, just as treaties on certain issues may engender unique lobbies for or against the treaties. Because our goal here is not to explain what all these treaty properties may be, this analysis will not include highly treaty specific attributes. However, it does consider the general subject matter of treaties and expects, in particular, that human rights treaties will take longer to progress through the advice and consent process. Descriptive data Time period For the statistical analysis, our data includes multilateral treaties in the advice and consent process post-1967. This means that the treaties may have been signed prior to 1967, but they are only in our sample if they had not yet been ratified by then. Thus, they have to be still untransmitted or pending, by 1967.9 Notably, we include some treaties that the US has signed, but the president has not yet transmitted them to the Senate. Assembly a list of these treaties is difficult, because no list of them exist. Furthermore, it is potentially tricky to decide which international agreements belong on this list, as some of them may be executive agreements that do not require senate advice and consent. To devise an accurate list, we searched multiple available treaty databases for agreements signed by the United States, but to which the United States had not yet become a party. These databases include the United Nations Treaty Database, ECOLEX,10 The Hague Conference on Private International Law,11 and Oceana Law.12 We also compared our list against a list of multilateral treaties from Gamble’s dataset on treaties and Wikipedia’s “treaties by year of conclusion.”13 After assembling this list, we consulted with the Office of the Assistant Legal Adviser for Treaty Affairs in the State Department. Here Frank Holleran, the Treaty Analyst and Depositary Officer, helped us identify treaties that were not designated to go through the advice and consent process, and also added some treaties that we had missed. Thus, we are quite confident that our list of un-transmitted treaties is 8 (Lugar 2009) go back to 1945 to look for unperfected treaties which could still be on the table as of 1967. http://www.ecolex.org/start.php 11 http://www.hcch.net/index_en.php 12 http://www.oceanalaw.com/ 13 http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Category: Treaties_by_year_of_conclusion 9 We 10 11 fairly accurate and that the treaties included are indeed ones requiring senate advice and consent. Bilateral treaties We limit our statistical analysis to multilateral treaties, for several reasons. About half the treaties that go through the advice and consent process in the United States are bilateral, but these bilateral treaties differ from multilateral treaties in at least four important ways. First, bilateral treaties tend to deal with a narrow set of topics. For example, the bilateral treaties transmitted to the senate between 1967 and 2011 belong primarily to five categories: consular conventions (17), property or copyright treaties (9), tax conventions (129), investment treaties (49) and extradition treaties (147). Together these treaties make up 350 treaties, which constitute 88 percent of all the non-multilateral treaties in Thomas that were transmitted in 1967 or later. Second, bilateral treaties often are renewals or revisions of treaties with a given country repeatedly. Thus, for example, 8 of the tax conventions approved for senate advice and consent since 1967 are with Canada. This means that these treaties often are minor revisions of previous documents, which reduces the need for debate. For these reasons, Galbraith calls these treaties “repetitive bilateral treaties” (Galbraith 2012 4). Third, bilateral treaties often follow various standard formats. This enables the senate to deal with them in bundles, meaning that the senate passes two or more treaties of the same kind on the same date, and often as part of the same vote. Typically 4-8 treaties are bundled. Thus, half the consular conventions were bundled with at least one other treaty. The senate bundled 95 percent of the tax conventions, 89 percent of the property or copyright treaties, 87 percent of extradition treaties and 88 percent of investment treaties. The senate bundled extradition treaties 82 percent of the time, in one case providing advice and consent to 30 treaties on the same day. This bundling means that any delay in passing these bilateral treaties is irregular because the senate will hold them until there is a hearing for treaties of a given type. Indeed, the senate routinely holds hearings on treaties of a given type once a year or every two years (interview). Thus the standard format of most bilateral treaties leads the senate to deal with them very differently than multilateral treaties which must by and large by dealt with on an ad hoc basis. Thus, bilateral treaties differ significantly from multilateral treaties, both in content, partners, and in how the senate chooses to handle them. That said, the fact that the senate indeed chooses to bundle these treaties provides support for the opportunity cost argument. The similarity of these treaties reduces the need for debate and subsequently facilitates bundling, which in turn reduces the need for senate floor time and thus the opportunity cost to the senate. Congressional Executive Agreements It is for similar reasons that we do not include executive agreements in the analysis, although for purposes of international law they are identical. Executive agreements take 12 two forms: sole and congressional. Sole executive agreements are made by the president alone and actually constitute the vast majority of international agreements to which the US is a party. Sole-executive agreement can only cover matters within the President's authority or matters in which Congress has delegated authority to the President. With a few notable exceptions, these agreements are routine. Congressional executive agreements are another matter. These require passage in both the House and the Senate. However, the requirement for passage is only a majority vote. Therefore the possibilities for blocking the legislation and taking up valuable floor time are not as great, and the opportunity cost of pushing the agreement to a vote is therefore not as great either. Furthermore, the congressional executive agreements tend to concern matters of trade, the one foreign policy area outside of war that probably concerns citizens most because it influences both jobs and consumer prices (Fordham and McKeown 2003). Thus, we would expect legislators to be more willing to spend time on congressional executive agreements. Multilateral treaties As discussed above, we focus on multilateral treaties for several reasons. In addition to the concerns above, a focus on multilateral treaties also has the benefit of focusing the analysis on those agreements most likely to influence broader global cooperation. If we limit the sample to multilateral treaties in the advice and consent process post-1945, there are 394 treaties for which we have complete information. Of these, the president eventually transmitted 354, and the average time to transmittal is about 3.2 years (standard deviation about 6.5 years), with the maximum being 49 years. Of the treaties transmitted, 296 were ultimately ratified in an average of 1.9 years, with the standard deviation being 4.4 years and the longest spell being 41 years For data visualization and analysis purposes, however, we limit our sample to post-1967 treaties. The next three figures display absolute signature, transmittal and ratification trends over time, but only for treaties signed after 1967. Figure 1 displays signatures. Note the bursts of signatures in the early 1970s and the 1990s, and also the much lower rate of US signature of international agreements in recent years: Whereas until 2003 the US has always signed at least 4 multilateral treaties a year, after 2003 there has been three years when it signed only one such agreement, and one year, 2008, when it signed none. This shows that the flow of treaties available for transmittal is not at all constant, something we will consider later in the model. Figure 2 shows that the number of transmitted treaties likewise varies a lot from year to year. It is interesting to both note in Figure 2 and 3 the low activity during the Obama administration. Indeed, the year 2010 under president Obama marks the first year in our sample that no multilateral treaty was ratified at all. 13 15 10 5 0 Figure 1: Number of multilateral treaties signed by the United States per year since 1967 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Figure 2: Number of multilateral treaties transmitted to senate per year since 1967 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 Figure 3: Number of multilateral treaties receiving advice and consent by the senate per year since 1967 Our hypotheses expected that treaty ratification would be faster in presidential election years, and especially during lame-duck years. This means that we should expect to see 14 more multilateral treaties pass during those times. Figure 4 shows how many multilateral treaties pass on average in a particular type of year. It is clear that on average the fewest multilateral treaties are passed in non-election years, more in midterm election years, and even more in presidential election years. Finally, the average number of treaties passed in “lame duck” years is clearly the highest, and is more than twice that in non-election years. 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 non election years Midterm election year presidential lameduck election election years years Figure 4: Average number of multilateral treaties given senate advice and consent during a particular type of year, 1967-2011 It is also interesting to consider the activity in the Senate throughout the year, given that we have expectations that the fall, especially before elections, will tend to be more active for treaties. Figure 5 shows the frequencies of treaty ratification in months throughout the different types of years. In general there is a certain rhythm to the year. Even in nonelection years, treaties are more likely to be passed late summer and fall. However this trend gets increasingly pronounced as we move into election years, then presidential election years and finally “lame-duck” years, where it is by far the most pronounced with September seeing a virtual flurry of treaties. 15 lameduck years pres election years (not lameduck) midterm election years non election years December November October September August July June May April March February January December November October September August July June May April March February January December November October September August July June May April March February January December November October September August July June May April March February January 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Figure 5: Average number of multilateral treaties passed in a given month, 1967-2011 16 Analysis Note that we have cast our theory as one of timing: although Presidents do refuse to send treaties to the Senate and the Senate does occasionally vote down a treaty (the last time as the senate rejected a treaty was the Comprehensive Nuclear Test Ban Treaty in 1999), the more interesting question is to understand what factors lead to delay in the Senate advice and consent process.14 Moreover, because at least some presidential transmittal decisions are likely to be strategic, simply examining all treaties that are transmitted leaves out a valuable and quite likely non-random set of the sample. On the other hand, simply modeling signature time to the advice and consent decision oversimplifies the process and ignores that there are some treaties the Senate cannot provide with its advice and consent, because the president has never transmitted them to that body. We therefore first model the transmittal decision, so that our ratification model can take the transmittal decisions into account. As noted, treaties may fail at the stage of presidential transmittal. More commonly, as previously discussed, a president may hold a treaty for some time before transmitting – we chose to explicitly model this decision as well as the choice of the Senate to provide advice and consent. To analyze our hypotheses as a part of this two-stage process, we undertake a two-step multivariate analysis of our treaty data. We first estimate a model for the transmission decision, then follow with a model based on the advice and consent decision. Our data is time-series, cross-sectional by nature, set up in treaty-year format, to capture changes in the key independent variables over time, should a treaty remain on the president’s desk or in the senate for more than one year. Thus, each variable we describe below is coded on a yearly basis. Core Variables Given our arguments above, we expect several variables to influence the length of time it takes for Presidents to transmit treaties to the Senate as well as the time from transmittal until the senate provides advice and consent. We examine the influence of political party support in both houses of the legislature (P1) by defining President % Control, which is the percentage of the House and Senate controlled by the party of the President. Traditionally, scholars would expect this variable to lead to an easier road to advice and consent. We, however, expect this to be associated with a longer time to advice and consent. We include this variable in both states (transmit and advice and consent) of our model. We expect higher presidential approval ratings (P2) to be correlated with a lower desire to transmit treaties to the Senate, given that this approval is likely to translate into bigger 14 In a similar vein, scholars have chosen to analyze delays in Senate consent on nominations. See (McCarty and Razaghian 1999 ; Binder and Maltzman 2002 ; Derouen, Peake et al. 2005) 17 momentum on domestic legislative imperatives. To examine this idea, we introduce Approval, the annual average of the Gallup presidential approval poll for each year of observation.15 We include this variable only in the first stage of our model given that this is a factor that presidents are likely to consider, but not the Senate in their decisionmaking. To address P3 and P4, involving the dynamics of the electoral calendar and its effect on opportunity costs, we define two variables: Lame duck and Re-election. The first of these two variables is coded as 1 in the final year of a president’s second term. The second of these is defined as 1 in the final year of a president’s first term, when he is up for reelection. We expect both of these variables to be expected with shorter advice and consent times given that there is little incentive for the Senate to work on domestic issues during these two periods of time. Moreover, we include these only in the ratification portion of the model since they are likely to be more important for Senate decisionmaking.16 Finally, we address P5 by introducing the variable Implementation, an indicator variable coded “1” if further domestic legislation is required for implementation of the treaty – i.e. the treaty is not self-executing. The variable is coded “0” otherwise. Control factors Of course, as previously discussed other factors may influence both the president’s decision to transmit a treaty to the Senate as well as the Senate ratification process. To this end, we introduce several control variables to both models. First, we define SFR Chair as the DW-Nominate score of the chair of the Senate Foreign Relations Committee. The Nominate score measures the underlying liberal-conservative spectrum of the voting record of members of Congress (Lewis and Poole 2004). Higher Nominate scores suggest a more conservative committee chair, while lower values suggest a more liberal chair. Because the chair of the committee remains for two years, this variable varies every other year. Second, we also use the DW-Nominate scores to define Conservative Senator to measure the ideology of the most conservative Senator in the chamber. This easily observable metric should influence both the President’s decision to transmit a treaty as well as the length of time a treaty takes to move through the advice and consent process. We expect that the more conservative the most conservative Senator, the longer both transmittal and ratification will take. Third, we define Democratic President, which equals 1 if the President is a Democrat. Our expectation is that Democratic Presidents will be more likely to transmit sooner and push for quicker advice and consent in the Senate. 15 Data is taken from the Gallup web site. www.gallup.com. 16 Inclusion of these variables in the transmittal stage of the model yields no evidence they influence presidential decision-­‐making. 18 Fourth, we calculate the number of treaties available to be transmitted based on the number of untransmitted treaties left from previous presidents and the new number of treaties concluded during the year. We label this variable Treaties Available for Transmittal. We control for these same dynamics in the ratification stage by computing the number of treaties under consideration in the Senate, labeled Treaties Available for Advice and Consent. Finally, it is also important to control for the type of treaty under consideration. Issue area could have important implications for the speed at which the treaty moves through the process. To this end, we classify treaties into four broad categories of types: Human Rights (e.g., UN human rights treaties), Commercial (e.g., trade agreements), International Law (e.g., technical treaties regarding rules and procedures in international law), Environment (e.g., regulatory treaties involving the environment), and Arms Control (e.g., multilateral arms treaties such as the Comprehensive Test Ban Treaty). In terms of the ratification model, we also are interested in the effects of the first stage (transmittal) on the second (advice and consent). This is investigated by calculating a predicted time to transmit from the President’s desk. We estimate a first stage model, then calculate a predicted median survival time – that is, the time the treaty will sit on the president’s desk. Again, we expect that longer periods of time on the president’s desk should lead to faster action in the second stage of the process: Senate advise and consent. Our initial models thus hold that transmittal and advice and consent are a function of the following: Transmittal = f(President % Control; Approval; Type: International Law; Type: Human Rights; Type: Arms Control; Type: Commercial; Democratic President; Transmit Available; SFRC Chair; Conservative Senator) Advice and Consent = f(President % Control; Type: International Law; Type: Human Rights; Type: Arms Control; Type: Commercial; Democratic President; Advice and Consent Available; SFRC Chair; Conservative Senator; Lame duck; Re-election; Predicted Transmit Time) To analyze data on time to transmittal or advice and consent, we turn to event history or duration models following Krutz and Peake (2009). As shown in Figures 6 and 7, the underlying distributions of the time-to-transmit and time-to-advice and consent dependent variables follows a Weibull distribution. In our subsequent multivariate analysis, we estimate a series of Weibull models, using the accelerated failure time metric to ease interpretation. For our coefficient estimates, it should be noted that positive signs indicate a positive effect on the hazard rate, meaning shorter transmission/ratification times. Negative signs indicate longer transmission/ratification times. Figure 6. Hazard rate for treaties signed by the US transmitted to the Senate. 19 0.00 0.25 0.50 0.75 1.00 Kaplan-Meier survival estimate 0 10 20 30 40 50 analysis time Figure 7. Hazard rate for ratification of treaties transmitted to Senate. 0.00 0.25 0.50 0.75 1.00 Kaplan-Meier survival estimate 0 20 40 60 analysis time 20 Results The estimates of the transmit stage of the model are found in column 1 of Table 1. Consistent with our expectations, President Percent Control is negative and statistically significant. This finding is strong evidence of the opportunity cost logic: the more copartisans the President has in Congress, the longer he takes to transmit treaties.17 Again, this logic is in contrast to extant theories of the production of domestic laws, where it is presumed stronger partisan support will facilitate legislative production. Moreover, this effect is substantively important as well. Increasing the average number of co-partisans by nine seats yields a increase in the predicted transmit time of over 35 percent.18 Similarly, the estimate of Approval is negative but not statistically significant, indicating that higher levels of public approval for the president have little influence on transmit times for treaties. Several control variables do achieve statistical significance and the estimates are consistent with our theoretical expectations. First, SFR Chair is negative and statistically significant, indicating that more conservative chairs lead to a lower hazard rate – i.e., longer transmit times. Similarly, the more conservative is the most conservative Senator, the longer the transmit time from the President’s desk, as suggested by the negative and statistically significant coefficient on Conservative Senator. Conversely, the positive estimate of Democratic President indicates that democratic presidents more quickly transmit signed treaties to the Senate for ratification. The substantive effect of this variable is quite high: switching from a Democratic to a Republican president yields a predicted increase of transmittal time of nearly 2 years: a doubling over the baseline prediction. And while the Commercial, International Law, and Human Rights indicators for treaty type are statistically distinct from the reference category, chi-square tests show they cannot be distinguished from other treaty categories. The rest of our treaty type categories are statistically indistinguishable from the reference category and each other. It is also worth noting that if we remove these type variables completely from the model, our estimates do not change significantly, suggesting that although these treaty specific variables may be important in explaining the outcomes, they are not systematically related to our variables of interest. This first stage model is important in that it both helps to determine what makes the president decide to send treaties into the advice and consent process, and it allows us to generate an instrument for use in the second model, which estimates the time-toratification once the treaty hits the Senate.19 We thus use this transmit model to predict 17 We get a similar result if only the Senate is computed in this measure. 18 All predicted probabilities are computed against a baseline model assuming a democratic president, an environmental treaty, and all other variables held at their mean value. 19 Note that the model gains identification from the inclusion of Approval in the first stage and Lame duck and Re-­‐election in the second stage. In addition, because Treaties Available is 21 the time that a treaty remains with the president – and later introduce this predicted variable into the second stage of our model. We now have an instrument that contains the factors that will influence whether the president believes a treaty will have difficulty in the Senate. Should he believe this is the case, we would see longer expected transmit times. If the president’s strategic decisions are correct, our prediction is that longer transmit times should predict shorter ratification times, since the president should have waited for an opportune time to act. Turning to our model of Senate ratification, the estimates of the ratification model can be found in Column 2 of Table 1. Note that nearly all of the domestic political variables that were statistically significant in the first stage do not achieve statistical significance in the second stage. Namely, Democratic President, President Percent Control, and Conservative Senator do not achieve conventional levels of statistical significance. Rather, these domestic political factors exert their influence in the decision of the President to transmit treaties. SFR Chair, however, is statistically significant in this second stage. Thus, a more conservative chair of the Senate foreign relations committee slows down the advice and consent process, independently of its effect on delaying presidential transmission. Increasing the conservativeness of the chair by one standard deviation leads to a predicted increase of over 50 percent in the time of advice and consent.20 Lame duck is positive and significant, indicating that the Senate moves faster on treaties in the final year of an executive’s eight year time in office when Senate floor time is less valuable. This variable has a large substantive effect: moving from a lame duck year to a non-lame duck year yields an over 70 percent increase in the time to advice and consent. Similarly, Re-election is positive and significant, indicating that treaties move through the advice and consent process about 40 percent faster in presidential re-election years. Next, we re-estimate the model, but include the variable Predicted Transmit, which is the predicted transmit time from the previously estimated model. The estimate of Predicted Transmit is statistically insignificant, as shown in column 3 of Table 1. This indicates that a longer predicted time of transmittal has no influence on the ratification process. One interpretation of this result could be that presidents do not accurately read the strategic ratification game in front of them. If holding a treaty longer led to quicker ratification times, this would indicate successful strategic delay to speed the acceptance of the treaty. We find no empirical evidence of this, however. We extend our ratification model in two ways. First, we check an alternative version of our ideology variable by measuring the NOMINATE score of the 67th Senator and using this measure to replace Conservative Senator. The estimate of this new variable, measured as only those treaties on the President’s desk in the first stage, it can also be used to help in model identification. 20 In the second stage models, the baseline probability is computed on an environmental treaty, democratic president, Re-­‐election set to 0, and Lame duck set to 1. 22 Senate67 is not statistically significant – thus, whether one examines the most conservative end of the ideological spectrum in the Senate or the threshold vote for passage, ideology does not appear to matter in a systematic way. Second, as indicated by P5, it is possible that the requirement of implementing legislation could slow down the treaty ratification process as Senators balk at the additional requirement to change the status quo. To check for this possibility, we code an indicator variable Implementation, which is coded as a “1” if the treaty will require additional legislation, “0” otherwise.21 We add this new variable to our original ratification model. The estimates of this new model can be found in column 4 of Table 1. The new variable is statistically significant, although its inclusion does not change any of the major substantive variables of interest. Still, this does suggest that treaties requiring further legislative effort are more likely to experience a delay in ratification. In sum, when considering these models, it is a combination of the effect of the ideology of the committee chair, along with the electoral calendar that appear to drive the advice and consent process. Few other political factors or treaty characteristics seem to influence the timing of treaty advice and consent. Conclusion Existing international relations theory expects states to join treaty regimes if they serve the national interest. Yet it does not take much to see this as an oversimplification: there are many cases where the US has not ratified a treaty, yet shows its support for the treaty in other ways, indicating that the treaty serves its interests. To explain this, scholars of American politics will quickly add that, of course, what really matters is whether actors with veto powers in the political process believe that the treaty is in the national interest. Because of the power they hold over the process, the political preferences of the senate foreign relations chair or the 2/3-senator can derail the senate advice and consent process. These actors may oppose treaties based on principled issues that have little to do with the substance of the treaty cooperation. Or strong lobbies against a treaty may deter them from supporting the treaty. Whatever the origin of their preferences, they have the ability to essentially hold the treaty hostage. We agree that is not possible to look at the national interest in ratifying a treaty in isolation from the domestic political opposition. Indeed, we clearly show the importance of veto players. However, we also argue that not even this traditional veto-player analysis fully explains US treaty participation. Sometimes those opposed to the treaty are not in veto positions. Sometimes even benign treaties, with little opposition at all, fall by the wayside. Our analysis reveals another much less appreciated factor that influences the treaty process: the opportunity costs of Senate time. 21 The sample size of this model is smaller as we are missing data on a number of treaties concerning their requirement of implementing legislation. We are currently in the process of filling in this missing data. 23 Our analysis has shown that the United States often delays or abstains from ratifying treaties because the constitutionally required advice and consent process increases the political costs of treaty ratification. Specifically, we have articulated an opportunity cost theory of treaty ratification. This theory argues that the fixed agenda space of the Senate adds an opportunity cost to ratification, because the president and the senate has to decide whether to spend time on the treaty or to spend time on other, often more valued, domestic legislation. The opportunity cost is partly a function of political preferences, but, more interestingly, it is also a function of the political value of the Senate floor time. Thus, the decision to push a treaty through the advice and consent process may be less about an objective examination of costs and benefits of the treaty (as assumed by traditional analysis) than about the benefit of spending time on the treaty relative to the benefit of other possible agenda activity that may produce important domestic legislation such as health care reform. In other words: Senate advice and consent depends on the associated opportunity costs. This insight is what explains otherwise perplexing patterns of US treaty behavior such as the fact that Senate support for the president delays rather than accelerates treaty ratifications. However, this pattern becomes understandable in the light of our opportunity cost theory: The more support the president enjoys, the more productive the Senate is being in passing domestic legislation, and the further the president and the Senate are from their re-election campaigns, the more valuable the time of the Senate agenda is. Thus, these conditions increase the opportunity costs for treaties, and the president or the senate may find them so large that the treaty either gets delayed or becomes entirely stuck. These findings speak both to American politics and international relations. For American politics, the findings reveal something new and interesting. Prior analysis of the other Senate advice and consent process, namely that of presidential nominations, has found that divided government, political polarization and elections obstructs Senate advice and consent. In contrast, we find that treaty advice and consent is more, not less, likely when the president lacks strong support in the Senate, when the Senate is gridlocked, and during election years. Based on our opportunity cost theory, we argue that this is because presidential nominations are domestic matters, which are forced onto the senate agenda whereas treaties are foreign policy matters, which are optional and face multiple hurdles. Indeed, the work on presidential nominations demonstrates the core of the opportunity cost argument, namely that it is time consuming to force controversial items on the Senate agenda. For international relations theory, the findings mean that there is not as straightforward translation from some unified national preferences into national politics as traditional cross-national analysis of treaty ratification assumes. Traditional analysis of state participation in international treaties usually treats states as unitary actors and assumes that their decision to join treaties depends purely on an analysis of its costs and benefits and that states therefore will join treaties that are in their interests. More sophisticated incorporation of domestic preferences as advocated by theory on two-level games is 24 useful, but it too expects that treaties that enjoy wide support would receive timely Senate advice and consent. However, we have found that in the United States, senate rules can make treaty ratification time consuming if there is even the slightest opposition to a treaty. Importantly, a particular treaty may simply be too low a priority to compete with other legislative demands. Thus, even treaties that enjoy the support of 2/3 of Senators, enough technically to win senate advice and consent, may have to wait a long time to be scheduled for a floor vote or may never make it. This finding also has implications for global cooperation. The United States often plays a pivotal role in whether international cooperative efforts are successful. Without the United States, it may be harder to get other countries to join, and the United States itself may lack a full voice within newly created organizations. 25 Table 1: Weibull models of the multilateral treaty process, 1967-2008. Ratify -1.625 (1.028) --.-- Ratify -1.455 (1.163) --.-- Ratify# -1.630 (1.063) --.-- 0.182 (0.234) -1.497*** (0.376) 0.125 (0.320) 0.194 (0.242) -0.056 (0.197) 0.004 (0.012) -0.610*** (0.165) 0.092 (0.717) --.-- 0.199 (0.249) -1.459*** (0.401) 0.114 (0.321) 0.242 (0.286) -0.093 (0.234) 0.004 (0.012) -0.582*** (0.190) --.-- Predicted Transmit Transmit -3.535*** (0.904) -0.007 (0.004) -0.345* (0.186) -0.632** (0.298) 0.001 (0.233) -0.505*** (0.174) 0.698*** (0.169) 0.006 (0.007) -0.627*** (0.148) -1.392* (0.740) --.-- Lame duck --.-- Re-election --.-- Implementation --.-- 0.636*** (0.180) 0.465*** (0.121) --.-- -0.024 (0.085) 0.642*** (0.181) 0.463*** (0.122) --.-- 0.302 (0.264) -1.296*** (0.411) 0.438* (0.237) 0.347 (0.238) 0.221 (0.190) -0.014 (0.012) -0.814*** (0.160) 0.691 (0.713) --.-- Constant 1.259** (0.630) -0.960*** (0.810) -1.049 (0.840) 0.374** (0.168) 0.334*** (0.114) -0.349* (0.198) -0.848 (0.844) N ln_p 1815 -0.028 (0.044) 1653 -0.254*** (0.058) 1653 -0.255*** (0.058) 1334 -0.107* (0.057) President % Control Approval International Law Human Rights Arms Control Commercial Dem. President Availability+ SFR Chair Conserv. Senator Note: *** = p<0.01; ** = p<0.05; * = p<0.10; all tests two-tailed. Robust standard error estimates are computed. + = Availability altered based on transmit or ratification stage. # This model limited to treaties signed after 1967. 26 REFERENCES Abramson, P., J. Aldrich, et al. (1987). "Progressive Ambition among United States Senators: 1972ñ1988." The Journal of Politics 49(1): 3-­‐35. Allison, G. (1971). Essence of decision: explaining the Cuban missile crisis. Boston, Massachussetts, Little Brown. Auerswald, D. and F. Maltzman (2003). "Policymaking through advice and consent: Treaty consideration by the United States Senate." Journal of Politics 65(4): 1097-­‐1110. Binder, S. and F. Maltzman (2002). "Senatorial delay in confirming federal judges, 1947-­‐1998." American Journal of Political Science 46(1): 190-­‐199. Boockmann, B. (2006). "Partisan politics and treaty ratification: The acceptance of International Labour Organisation conventions by industrialised democracies, 1960–1996." European Journal of Political Research 45(1): 153-­‐180. Bradley, C. (2010). "The United States and Human Rights Treaties: Race Relations, the Cold War, and Constitutionalism." Chinese Journal of International Law 9(2): 321-­‐344. Buthe, T. and H. Milner (2008). "The politics of foreign direct investment into developing countries: increasing FDI through international trade agreements?" American Journal of Political Science 52(4): 741-­‐762. Charnovitz, S. (2008). "Editorial Comment: The ILO Convention on Freedom of Association and Its Future in the United States." American Journal of International Law 102(1): 90-­‐107. Delaet, J. and J. Scott (2006). "Treaty-­‐Making and Partisan Politics: Arms Control and the U.S. Senate, 1960–2001." Foreign Policy Analysis 2(2): 177-­‐200. Derouen, K., J. Peake, et al. (2005). "Presidential mandates and the dynamics of Senate advice and consent, 1885-­‐1996." American Politics Research 33(1): 106-­‐131. Elsig, M., K. Milewicz, et al. (2012). Who is in love with multilateralism? Treaty commitment in the post-­‐Cold War era. Evans, L. and W. Oleszek (2003). A Tale of Two Treaties: The Practical Politics of Treaty Ratification in the US Senate. Congress and the Politics of Foreign Policy. C. Campbell, N. Rae and J. Stack Jr. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey, Prentice Hall: 70– 89. Fordham, B. and T. McKeown (2003). "Selection and Influence: Interest Groups and Congressional Voting on Trade Policy." International Organization 57(03): 519-­‐549. Fredriksson, P. (2000). "Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: what determines legislative delay." Public choice 104(3/4): 345. Galbraith, J. (2012). "Prospective Advice and Consent." Yale Journal of International Law Forthcoming. Hafner-­‐Burton, E. (2009). Forced to be Good: Why Trade Agreements Boost Human Rights. Ithaca, Cornell University Press. Hall, R. (1996). Participation in Congress. New Haven, Yale University Press. 27 Haller, H. and S. Holden (1997). "Ratification requirement and bargaining power." International Economic Review 38(4): 825-­‐851. Johnson, T. (2010). Interview with John B. Bellinger III, U.S. Trouble with START and Other Treaties, July 9. Krepon, M. and D. Caldwell (1991). The Politics of arms control treaty ratification. Hampshire, United Kingdom, Palgrave Macmillan. Krutz, G. and J. Peake (2009). Treaty politics and the rise of executive agreements: international commitments in a system of shared powers. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. Lewis, J. and K. Poole (2004). "Measuring Bias and Uncertainty in Ideal Point Estimates via the Parametric Bootstrap." Political Analysis 12(2): 105-­‐127. Lugar, R. (2009). "Speech on treaties to the Washington Foreign Law Society, 14 September." Retrieved October 14, 2010, from http://lugar.senate.gov/news/record.cfm?id=317861&&. Mansfield, E., H. Milner, et al. (2005). "Vetoing cooperation: The impact of veto players on international trade agreements." American Political Science Association, Washington, DC. Martin, L. (2005). "The President and International Commitments: Treaties as Signaling Devices." Presidential Studies Quarterly 35(3): 440-­‐465. Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven, Connecticut, Yale University Press. McCarty, N. and R. Razaghian (1999). "Advice and consent: Senate responses to Executive branch nominations 1885-­‐1996." American Journal of Political Science 43(4): 1122-­‐1143. McCubbins, M. and G. Cox (1993). Legislative Leviathan. Berkeley, California, University of California Press. Moravcsik, A. (2000). "The origins of human rights regimes: Democratic delegation in postwar Europe." International Organization 54(2): 217-­‐252. Moravcsik, A. (2005). The Paradox of US Human Rights Policy. American Exceptionalism and Human Rights. M. Ignatieff. Princeton, New Jersey, Princeton University Press: 147-­‐197. Putnam, R. (1988). "Diplomacy and domestic politics: the logic of two-­‐level games." International Organization 42(3): 427-­‐460. Simmons, B. (2000). "International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs." American Political Science Review 94(4): 819-­‐835. Simmons, B. (2009). Mobilizing for Human Rights: International Law in Domestic Politics. New York, New York, Cambridge University Press. Stoll, R. (1984). "The guns of November: Presidential reelections and the use of force." Journal of Conflict Resolution 28(2): 231-­‐246. Vreeland, J. (2008). "Political institutions and human rights: Why dictatorships enter into the United Nations Convention Against Torture." International Organization 62(1): 65. 28