Corporate control Ownership and control • one share – one vote? Hart, ch. 8 The market for corporate control • takeover bidding Hirshleifer; Stein Bankruptcy • How to make sure that viable firms are not declared bankrupt? White Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 1 The structure of voting rights In most firms at the Oslo Stock Exchange: • all shares receive the same fraction of dividends • all shares have the same voting rights at the general assembly But in a few firms: • one class of shares without voting rights • all shares still receive the same fraction of dividends • class A and class B shares Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 2 Why does the structure of voting rights matter? What do you get from controlling a firm? Let us distinguish between: • public value – money gained from owning shares in a firm dividends and • private value – benefits gained from managing the firm - widespread? - newspapers, sports teams - but: fiduciary duty / minority interests A management team may want to take over a firm because their private value are high, despite their public value being low. If control is gained from a low fraction of the firm, then it is less costly in terms of public value to obtain the high private benefits from managing. Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 3 A model Incumbent management team vs. rival management team: I vs. R. Everybody risk neutral. No discounting. Public value: Private value: yI and yR. bI and bR. Is the rival team better in terms of public benefits? - If Yes, then yR ≥ yI. If No, then yR < yI. Date 0: The firm goes public. A large number of very small shareholders. None of the two management teams own shares. Voting structure chosen. Two classes of shares, A and B. Dividend entitlements: sA, sB, sA + sB = 1 Vote entitlements: vA, vB, vA + vB = 1 Assume: vB > ½. [Special case, one share - one vote: sA/vA = sB/vB = 1] Incumbent management team starts up. Uncertainty about the ys and bs. Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 4 Date 1: Uncertainty about the ys and bs is resolved. Rival team appears, decides on a take-over. If take-over, then incumbent team must decide on resistance. The control contest. If take-over is successful, management is replaced. Date 2: The company is closed down. Dividend is paid to shareholders. Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 5 The control contest Suppose the rival team decides to take over. The rival team makes a public tender offer. The incumbent team may choose to make a counteroffer. Shareholders are faced with one or two offers. They may choose to tender to the rival, to the incumbent, or to hold on to their shares. The offers are unrestricted: In order to buy any shares in a particular class of shares, the bidders must offer to buy all shares in that class. [One share – one vote: vB > ½ ⇒ sB = 1.] The offers are unconditional: The bidders buy shares also when the bid for control fails. The control contest centers on the class B shares. (Remember: vB > ½.) No use in bidding for the class A shares in addition. (Current shareholders will hold on to those shares as long as there are any capital gains.) Special case: Suppose the private value of the incumbent management is insignificant – bI = 0. If the incumbent team bids, they offer the whole public value of class B shares, given that they continue: sByI - They cannot afford to buy more - Shareholders are not willing to accept less Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 6 The rival team makes an offer if - it is going to beat the incumbent offer - it is profitable (i) Suppose the rival management team is better: yR ≥ yI. The rival team offers the whole public value of class-B shares, given that they take over: sByR - This beats the incumbent offer and is profitable. profitable, because of the private value bR - Shareholders are not willing to accept less. (ii) Suppose the incumbent team is better: yR < yI. In order to win, the rival must offer sByI. This is profitable if and only if: bR > sB(yI – yR). → If yR < yI and bR > sB(yI – yR), then the less efficient management wins the contest, and public value gets low. At the outset (date 0), owners don’t want this to happen. What should they do? – Make sB(yI – yR) as large as possible. → Put sB = 1. → One class of shares. – One share – one vote. As long as one or both of bI and bR are close to zero, one share – one vote is (weakly) best. But what if they both are significant? Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 7 Example with both bI and bR significant. Suppose rival team has higher public value but smaller private value. yI = 200 < yR = 300. bI = 55 > bR = 10. Suppose we have two classes of shares of equal size, with all voting power in class B: sA = sB = ½; vA = 0, vB = 1. How much is rival team willing to pay for control over class-B shares? – sByR + bR = ½300 + 10 = 160. How much is incumbent team willing to pay to keep their control? – sByI + bI = ½200 + 55 = 155. → The rival team will succeed with an offer 155 + ε ≈ 155. The total value of the firm is: sAyR + (sByI + bI) = ½300 + 155 = 305. With one share – one vote: The incumbent team cannot win the contest. Shareholders will accept all offers better than 300. The rival team will succeed with an offer 300 + ε ≈ 300. The total value of the firm is: 300. Owners prefer two classes! Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 8 Social value versus owners’ value Social value is y + b; always maximized with one share – one vote, even when both bs are significant. - The contest always won by the team with the higher y + b. Restricted offers An offer can be made to buy only a fraction, say λ, of the controlling class-B shares. This makes it cheaper to take over, and chances that an inefficient management team will succeed increase. The problem is reduced with a voting structure such that: sA/vA = sB/vB = 1. → One share – one vote. Tore Nilssen – Economics of the Firm – Lecture 3 – slide 9