4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Mergers Introduction Efficiency defense 4820–13 FarrellShapiro criterion Geir B. Asheim Department of Economics, University of Oslo ECON4820 Spring 2010 Last modified: 2010.05.04 Why merge? Why allow mergers? 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Firms merge to Introduction Outline Efficiency defense reduce competition — increase market power reap cost savings — economics of scale and scope FarrellShapiro criterion Firms should be allowed to merge if cost savings are greater than the efficiency loss Oliver Williamson’s efficiency defense Outline 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Outline Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion Evaluation of the efficiency defense Static effects of mergers The Farrell-Shapiro criterion: A sufficient condition under Cournot competition Evaluation of the efficiency defense 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion Williamson’s point: It may not take a hugh cost saving to dominate the deadweight loss from a merger. But what if . . . . . . the pre-competitive price is not competitive? . . . cost-savings don’t accrue to the non-merging firms? Product reshuffling: More of the production in the industry will be made by the low-cost merging firm — an additional source of cost savings in the industry . . . maximization of aggregate surplus is not the appropriate welfare standard? . . . dynamic effects are important? R&D, capacity investment, new products, etc. Static effects of mergers 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion In general, the welfare analysis of mergers are complex, even within rather simple models. An alternative: A sufficient condition for a merger to be welfare improving. This is what the Farrell-Shapiro criterion provides, assuming that firm engage in Cournot competition. A merger affects the merging firms price costs the non-merging firms price consumers price Positive external effect is sufficient 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion When a merger is proposed, then presumably it is profitable for the merging firms So the competition authority when looking for a sufficient condition for a welfare-improvement can limit the analysis to the merger’s effect on (i) non-merging firms, and (ii) consumers → the external effect of a merger Cost savings affect mainly the merging parties. So focusing on the external effect, we need not access vague statements from the firms on their cost savings. If the merger leads to a higher price, then non-merging firms benefit and consumers suffer. But what is the total effect? A merger model with Cournot competition 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion X: C: xi : ci I: O: XI X−i total output in the industry total cost in the industry output of firm i = ci (xi ): cost of firm i Insiders (merging firms) Outsiders (non-merging firms) = i∈I xi : total output in the merging firms, etc. = j=i xj : total output of all firms but i dxi : Firm i’s output increase in a response to λi = − dX a unit decrease of total output P(X ): Inverse demand function Firm i’s FOC under Cournot competition: 0 = P(X ) + xi P (X ) − ci (xi ) Welfare effects of a merger 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion dW = pdX − dC = pdXI − dCI + pdXO − dCO = (pdXI + XI dp − dCI ) −XI dp + dπI = dπI − XI P (X )dX + i∈O [P(X ) − ci (xi )]dxi i∈O xi P (X )λi dX xi XP (X )dX + λi X XP (X )dX i∈O λi si − sI XP (X )dX = dπI + = dπI − XI X i∈O Farrell-Shapiro criterion: Assume that dX < 0. Then λi si − sI XP (X )dX > 0 dW − dπI = if and only if i∈O i∈O λi si > sI . But what is λi ? (Firm i’s response to a change in total output) 4820–13 Mergers Let P (X ) + P (X )X < 0 & ci (xi ) > P (X ), ∀X , ∀i, ∀xi ≤ X Geir B. Asheim 0 = P(xi + X−i ) + xi P (xi + X−i ) − ci (xi ) Introduction 0 = (2P + xi P − ci )dxi + (P + xi P )dX−i Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion dxi dX−i iP = Ri (X−i ) = − 2P P +x+x i P −c i dxi = Ri dX−i ⇒ dxi (1 + Ri ) = Ri [dxi + dX−i ] = Ri dX R dxi λi = − dX = − 1+Ri = i P (X )+xi P (X ) P (X )−ci (xi ) >0 Example: Constant MC (ci = 0) and linear demand (P = 0), so that λi = 1. All firms have equal cost and, thus, is of equal size before merger. The external effect is positive if the number of merging firms is less than half the number of all firms: sI < i∈O si ⇔ m < n2 Discussion 4820–13 Mergers Geir B. Asheim Introduction Efficiency defense FarrellShapiro criterion External effect A merger model Welfare analysis What is λi ? Discussion Criticism of the Farrell-Shapiro approach The merger might not be privately profitable Empire building Tax motivated mergers Preemption (or encouragement) of other mergers A merger’s effects on collusion What effect does a merger have in an industry where firms collude? — On balance: unclear. The merging firms now earn more and have reduced incentives to cheat on the collusive agreement after the merger (Especially) the non-merging firms now earn more without collusion and therefore have increased incentives for breaking out of the collusive agreement after the merger