4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Product differentiation Horizontal differentiation 4820–4 Linear city Circular city Geir B. Asheim Advertising Department of Economics, University of Oslo ECON4820 Spring 2010 Last modified: 2010.02.16 The extent of the market — Different products or differentiated variants of the same product 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim How far does the market extend? Which firms compete with each other? What is an industry? Introdution Questions Outline Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Advertising Products are not homogeneous Exceptions: Gasoline, electricity Still, some products are more equal to each other than to other products in the economy. These products constitute an industry with differentiated products. But where do we draw the line? Examples: beer vs. soda? soda vs. milk? beer vs. milk? Two kinds of product differentiation 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Questions Outline Bertrand model 1 Horizontal differentiation Ex: Different location of stores Different time slots for airline departures Consumers differ in their preferences over the product’s characteristics (as color, taste, location of outlet). The optimal choice for identical prices depends on consumer preferences. Covered here. Linear city Circular city Advertising 2 Vertical differentiation Ex: Cars of different quality and in different price segments Products differ in some characteristic (called quality ) in which all consumers agree what is best. For equal prices, all prefer the variant with higher quality. The optimal choice is the same for everyone. For different prices, consumer make different choice (e.g. due to differences in income). Covered next time. Horizontal product differentiation Positive questions 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Questions Outline Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Advertising Pricing behavior for given number of firms and given locations. How does product differentiation influence the firms’ price competition? Location choice for given number of firms. How do firms differentiate their products to weaken price competition? Entry decisions. Horizontal product differentiation Normative questions 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Questions Outline Bertrand model Is the product variation too large in equilibrium? Too much product differentiation? Linear city Circular city Advertising Are there too many variants in equilibrium? Too many firms enter? Outline 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Bertrand model with differentiated products Introdution Questions Outline Bertrand model Linear city Spatial competition The linear city The circular city Circular city Advertising Advertising and informational product differentiation Informative? Persuasive? Bertrand model with differentiated products (1) 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Structure: (1) Prices set (2) Demand determines quantities Firms 1 and 2 have constant unit cost c1 and c2 and set prices p1 and p2 simultaneously. Sales are given by Di (pi , pj ), which is the continuous demand function for firm i. Bertrand model max(pi − ci )Di (pi , pj ) pi Linear city Circular city Advertising Why does a continuous demand function mean that products are differentiated? Result Let c1 = c2 = c. If D1 (p1 , p2 ) > 0 when p1 ≤ min{c, p2 } and D2 (p2 , p1 ) > 0 when p2 ≤ min{c, p1 }, then in any Nash equilibrium (p1∗ , p2∗ ) we have that (p1∗ , p2∗ ) (c, c). Bertrand model with differentiated products (2) 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Advertising Proof. To be shown: (p1 , p2 ) is not a Nash equilibrium if min{p1 , p2 } ≤ c. Case 1: min{p1 , p2 } < c. At least one firm i has negative profit. Non-negative profit by setting pi ≥ c. Case 2: min{p1 , p2 } = c. If pi = c and pj ≥ c, then by assumption Di (pi , pj ) > 0, and firm i’s profit is zero. Since Di (·, ·) is continuous, firm i can attain positive profit by setting pi = c + ε for ε > 0 sufficiently small. Hence, differentiated products solve the Bertrand paradox, in the sense that it leads to price exceeding marginal cost. The linear city model with linear transportation costs (1) 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Following Hotelling (1929), consider a linear city of length 1 with consumers uniformly distributed along this interval. Also, assume that firm 1 is located at 0 and firm 2 is located at 1. For a consumer located at x (∈ [0, 1]) the cost to buy from firm 1 is p1 + tx and the cost to buy from firm 2 is p2 + t(1 − x). Every consumer buys one unit from a firm with lowest cost. Linear city Linear transp. costs Quadratic transp. costs Circular city Advertising Indifferent consumer x̃: p1 + tx̃ = p2 + t(1 − x̃), which implies p2 − p1 + t p1 − p2 + t and 1 − x̃ = 2t 2t ⎧ ⎪ if pi ≤ pj − t ⎨1 pj −pi +t Di (pi , pj ) = if pi ∈ (pj − t, pj + t) 2t ⎪ ⎩ 0 if pi ≥ pj + t x̃ = The linear city model with linear transportation costs (2) 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Linear transp. costs Quadratic transp. costs Circular city Advertising max (pi − c) pi ∈[pj −t,pj +t] FOC if pi ∈ (pj − t, pj + t): ⎧ ⎪ ⎨ pj − t pj +c+t pi = 2 ⎪ ⎩ pj + t pj − pi + t 2t pj + c + t − 2pi = 0 if pj ≥ c + 3t if pj ∈ (c − t, c + 3t) if pj ≤ c − t Unique Nash equilibrium, (p1c , p2c ) satisfies: p1c = p2c = c + t. Hence, price exceeds c. Do firms maximize product differentiate to relax price competition? Problematic to discuss choice of product differentiation with linear transportation costs. Why? What product differentiation maximizes welfare? The linear city model with quadratic transportation costs (2) 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Linear transp. costs Quadratic transp. costs Circular city Assume that firm 1 is located at a and firm 2 is located at 1 − b, where 0 ≤ a < 1 − b ≤ 1. For a consumer located at x (∈ [0, 1]) the cost to buy from firm 1 is p1 + tx 2 and the cost to buy from firm 2 is p2 + t(1 − x)2 . Structure: (1) Firms choose locations a and b (2) Given locations, firms choose prices p1 and p2 (3) Demand determines quantities Advertising Maximal product differentiation to weaken price competition: a = 0 and b = 0 Less product differentiation would have maximized welfare: a = 14 and b = 14 What about entry? Better to analyze in the circular city model. The circular city model and firm entry Presentation of model 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Structure: (1) Firms choose whether to enter; locate symmetrically around a circle (length 1) (2) Given entry and locations, firms choose prices; we assume maximal differentiation (3) Demand determines quantities Circular city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry Advertising f : Fixed cost of entry (pi − c)Di − f : Firm i’s (ex ante) profit Assume linear transportation costs. Ask: How many firms will enter? The circular city model and firm entry Equilibrium price 4820–4 Product different. I Demand for i’s product, given that the competitors’ price is p. Assume that firm i only competes with his nearest competitors. Geir B. Asheim Indifferent consumer x̃: pi + tx̃ = p + t( n1 − x̃), which implies: Introdution p − pi + Di (pi , pj ) = 2x̃ = t Bertrand model t n Linear city p − pi + max(pi − c) pi t Circular city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry Advertising FOC if pi ∈ (p − nt , pj + nt ): p + c + t n t n −f − 2pi = 0 Find the symmetric equilibrium by setting pi = p: p=c+ t n The profit margin (p − c) is reduced if greater entry (larger n) The circular city model and firm entry Equilibrium entry 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim How many firms will enter? Demand for each: maximize n subject to (p − c) n1 − f = nc ≤ Introdution Bertrand model and nc + 1 > p c+ Circular city Advertising t f c Linear city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry √ 1 n t n2 −f ≥0 t f tf Higher transport costs (larger t) weakens price competition, increases price, and leads to greater entry (larger n). In equilibrium: Total cost of entry: Total transportation cost: Total cost: t ff = √ tf √ t 1 t 4 f = 4 tf √ 5 4 tf The circular city model and firm entry Socially optimal entry 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Consumption is given (p > c does not lead to efficiency loss). Hence, social planner wishes to minimize the sum of entry costs and transportation costs: 2n1 t min nf + t 2n xdx = min nf + 4n n Linear city Circular city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry Advertising n= 1 2 n 0 t f = 12 nc Too many firms in equilibrium Private motivation for entry: Business stealing Social motivation for entry: Saving transportation costs In social optimum: Total cost of entry: Total transportation cost: t 1 2 4 12 t ff t f Total cost: = 1 2 = 1 2 √ √ √ tf tf tf The circular city model and firm entry Discussion 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Maximal product differentiation is assumed. Can this be endogenized through a 3–stage game → Economides (1984) Simultaneous entry is assumed Linear city Circular city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry Advertising What about sequential entry? → Prescott & Visscher (1977) Each firm produces only one brand (one product variant) What if each firm can produce multiple brands? Then they can attach their competitors from more than one direction. Leading to multi-brand monopoly rather than one-brand oligopoly? Maximal or minimal differentiation? Arguments for less differentiation 4820–4 Product different. I Locating where demand is. Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Equilibrium price Equilibrium entry Socially opt. entry Positive externalities between firms. Ex.: A particular type of stores is located in the same street. The consumers know where to go and can compare more easily products that are differentiated from other characteristics than location. No price competition (Hotelling, 1929). Advertising Ex.: Commercial TV companies wishing to maximize their audience, transmit similar programs in the same time slot. Political parties approach the center (median voter). Related to the positive demand effect. Advertising Informational product differentiation 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Informative: focus here Persuasive: shifting consumers’ preferences Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Advertising Model Equilibrium Consider a linear city of length 1 with consumers uniformly distributed along this interval. Also, assume that firm 1 is located at 0 and firm 2 is located at 1. For a consumer located at x (∈ [0, 1]) the cost to buy from firm 1 is p1 + tx if informed of firm 1 and the cost to buy from firm 2 is p2 + t(1 − x) if informed of firm 2. A consumer becomes informed of firm i by receiving advertising from firm i. Fraction of consumers receiving advertising from firm i: ϕi Advertising costs: Ai = A(ϕi ) = 2a ϕ2i Advertising Model of informational product differentiation 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Advertising Model Equilibrium Potential market for firm 1: ϕ1 Out of these consumers, a fraction 1 − ϕ2 have not received information from firm 2 The rest, a fraction both firms ϕ2 out of ϕ1 , 1knowp2about −p1 D1 = ϕ1 (1 − ϕ2 ) + ϕ2 2 + 2t Firms simultaneously & independently choose advertising & price 1 p2 −p1 a 2 max(p1 − c)ϕ1 (1 − ϕ2 ) + ϕ2 2 + 2t − 2 ϕ1 p1 ,ϕ1 FOCs p1 : ϕ1 (1 − ϕ2 ) + ϕ2 12 + ⇒ p1 = p2 +c−t 2 + t ϕ2 p2 −p1 2t 1 ϕ2 =0 − (p1 − c) ϕ2t −p1 ϕ1 : (p1 − c) (1 − ϕ2 ) + ϕ2 12 + p22t − aϕ1 = 0 −p1 ⇒ ϕ1 = p1a−c (1 − ϕ2 ) + ϕ2 12 + p22t Advertising Equilibrium 4820–4 Product different. I Geir B. Asheim Introdution Bertrand model Linear city Circular city Find the symmetric equilibrium by setting p1 = p2 = p and ϕ1 = ϕ2 = ϕ: p= + t ϕ √ ⇒ p = c + t ϕ − 1 = c + t 2a = c + 2at t p−c ϕ ϕ t 2 ϕ = a (1 − ϕ) + 2 = a ϕ − 1 1 − 2 ⇒ ϕ= Advertising Model Equilibrium p+c−t 2 2 1+ q2 (which requires t ≤ 2a) 2a t Π = 2a ϕ2 = ∂p ∂a > 0, ∂ϕ ∂a 1+ q2a 2a t < 0, 2 ∂Π ∂t > 0, ∂Π ∂a > 0. An increase in advertising costs increases firms’ profits A direct negative effect. An indirect positive effect: a ↑ ⇒ ϕ ↓ ⇒ p ↑