Plan and literature reference for the lectures 4 April and 18 April 2006. Lecture 11: Macro dynamics of the open economy. • Ch 23-25 in IAM • We start by reviewing the equations of the open economy model AD-AS model in IAM. — Exactly the same as in the book, but we simplify the notation somewhat Ragnar Nymoen Department of Economics, University of Oslo • We spend some more time than the book on the modelling of the market for foreign exchange, and on the interplay between the marked for foreign exchange and the domestic money market April 3, 2006 2 1 The open economy AD-AS framework • The analysis of the open economy AD-AS will focus on the difference between monetary policy regimes, and on the difference between short-run effects of shocks and policy changes, and the long-term effects of such changes. — In particular we build on the concepts developed in the IDM part of the lectures, — and on the application of that analysis in Ch. 19 of IAM: the dynamics of the closed economy AD-AS model. — Ch. 17 of IAM, monetary policy and aggregate demand, is also import background. Using the symbols form IAM, Ch 23.3, with subscript t added, the condition for equilibrium in the product market is defined as Yt = Dt + Gt + N Xt where: • Yt is real domestic GDP • Dt is real domestic private demand (sum of private consumption and housing and business investment) • Gt is real government expenditure. • N Xt is the trade balance. 3 (1) 4 Since Dt includes both consumption and investment we include both private disposable income, Yt − Tt, Tt being the real tax bill in period t, and the real interest rate rt as explanatory variables, i.e. our theory of domestic demand becomes Real exports in period t is Xt and Mt is the quantity of imported foreign goods. The real exchange rate in period t is defined as f Etr = Dt = D(Yt − Tt, rt ) >0 <0 which is consistent with IAM, eq (17) on page 709 when note is taken that 1. We do not impose Gt = Tt. 2. We simplify by abstracting from the effects of the real exchange rate E r , foreign GDP Y f and confidence ε on domestic demand. The trade balance, denoted, N Xt is defined in equation on page 707 in IAM. EtPt Pt f on page 704. Pt and Pt denote the domestic and foreign price level indices. If there are no responses in Xt and Mt when Etr increases, Yt will be reduced as a result of a real devaluation in period t. This may well be the case if the time period is short and there are adjustment lags in Xt and Mt. In this case, the terms-of-trade effect of a devaluation dominates. In the following we shall however assume that the time period is long enough to allow the combined quantity effect (an increase in Xt and a lowering of Mt) to knock out the terms-of-trade effect. N Xt = Xt − Etr Mt 6 5 Hence Collecting the assumptions so far: ∂N Xt >0 ∂Etr f Yt = D(Yt − Tt, rt ) + Gt + N X(Yt − Tt, Yt ,Etr ) >0 subject to the Marhall-Lerner condition which is explained in detail on page 709 in IAM. The theory of the trade balance is completed by assuming that Xt depends f positively on Yt and that Mt depends positively on Yt − Tt. f <0 <0 In IAM the following composite demand variable is defined (p. 706, equation (17)) D̃ = D + N X. In line with this, we re-write (2) as f N Xt = N X(Yt − Tt, Yt ,Etr ) Yt = D̃(Yt − Tt, rt, Yt , Etr ) + Gt 7 8 <0 >0 >0 (2) >0 >0 (3) The derivatives of the D̃ function become ∂D − ∂NX D̃Y = ∂Y ∂Yt t D̃T = −D̃Y D̃r = ∂D ∂r t D̃Y f = ∂NX f 0 < D̃Y < 1 Equation (4) represents product market equilibrium in period t for given values f e of Tt, Gt, Yt , rt, πt+1 and Etr . We note that it is a dynamic theory, by definition, although we have abstracted from many sources of dynamics when deriving (4). D̃r < 0 0 < D̃Y f < 1 ∂Yt D̃E = ∂NX D̃E r > 0 ∂Etr which is the same signs as on page 710 of IAM. We will follow the book and work with a linearized version of (4). You do not need to read the appendix in Ch 22, just accept f yt = β0 + β1 ert − β2 rt + β3 gt + β4 yt The (ex ante) real interest rate rt is defined as >0 e rt = it − πt+1 e is the where it, is the domestic nominal interest rate in period t, and πt+1 expected rate of inflation in period t + 1. Substitution in (3) gives f e , Y , Er) + G Yt = D̃(Yt − Tt, it − πt+1 t t t (4) >0 >0 (5) >0 at face value. yt = ln(Yt) and so on, so βi > 0 (i = 1, 2, 3, 4) are elasticities. Compared to equation (23) on page 710 in IAM we have dropped the terms ȳ etc. Think of them as subsumed in β0. Equation (4), and its derivatives, is the first building block in our open economy macro model. 9 10 To complete the model we need to add more assumptions and equations, notably for 1. The supply-side. This will be an expectations augmented Phillips curve, of the form in equation (41) on page 716 in IAM (its derivation on page 712-715 in Ch 23.4 can be skipped): πt = πte + γ(yt − ȳ) + st (6) where ȳ is the level of output consistent with πt = πte and no supply shocks st = 0. Remark. In the light of what we have learnt about wage-price dynmaics probably means that the model understates the role of demand shocks. 3. The domestic money market, because this is where the nominal interest it is determined (in most regimes, but not under inflation targeting). Moreover, the domestic money market and the market for foreign exchange are closely related, so it is necessary to take an ‘excurs’ to the theory of the foreign exchange market and how it is related to the domestic financial markets: Money and domestic bonds. 2. The market for foreign exchange, because this is where the nominal exchange rate Et in Etr = regime. EtPtf Pt is determined in a floating exchange rate 11 12 The market for foreign exchange Definition and basic analytical framework The participants in the market for foreign exchange (FEX) are • Investors: Private banks and financial institutions, as well as foreign central banks and domestic and foreign (production) firms. • The domestic monetary authority, usually, the central bank. — decides the demand of foreign exchange 13 Price (kr/$) Demand Supply The joint (but uncoordinated) decisions of the investors determine the net supply of foreign exchange. • in the very short-run (the daily to monthly horizon), the net supply is dominated by capital movements: foreign currency is supplied as a result of the investors’ management of huge financial portfolios. • in the intermediate-run: the supply of currency is also affected by the flow of currency generated by current account surpluses or deficits (exporting firms get paid in USD, and thus will exchange USD to kroner). We start by first reviewing the basic characteristic of the FEX market when we abstract from the trade balance effect. This is the pure stock or portfolio model of the FEX market. We then explain how we can modify the framework by the effects of the flow foreign currency resulting from international trade. 14 In the graph, we have drawn the (government’s) demand for foreign currency as a vertical line. A synonym is the foreign exchange reserve and it is denoted Fg in the graph (this notation is not in IAM) Fg is the whole stock of foreign currency deposited in the central bank, less any debt (incurred by the government) in foreign currency. E The supply schedule is market “S” and is upward sloping, i.e., as usual the supply of foreign currency is increasing in price. Demand and supply relate to the whole stock of foreign currency What determines net supply of foreign currency? Fg Quantity ($) • As noted, in the short-run, it cannot be the trade balance (primary current account), because this is a flow variable. Figure 1: The market for foreign exchange in terms of demand and supply curves 15 • instead factors that can, in any point in time, effect a revaluation of existing assets. One such variable is the price of the commodity, the nominal exchange rate E, which, for this reason is in the vertical axis in the graph. 16 Other variables with an immediate effect (at any point in time) on the net supply of foreign currency is 1. The domestic interest rate, it. An increased risk premium affects the supply of FEX immediately (no lags) Price (kr/$) Supply Demand E f 2. The foreign interest rate, it 3. The expected rate of currency depreciation, e −E Et+1 t e /E ). ≈ ln(Et+1 t Et In the so called portfolio model of the FEX market, detailed in the course ECON4330, this term are collected in a term dubbed the risk-premium f e /E ) rpt = it − it − ln(Et+1 t which has an negative (and immediate!) effect on the supply of foreign currency. Fg Quantity ($) Hence the line representing a supply shift is due to either 1. an increase in it, f 2. or a reduction in it , 3. or a shift down in the expected rate of depreciation. 17 Hence on daily and monthly basis, almost all the variation in the net supply of currency to the central bank is explained by the factors that determine the expected short-term return on kroner denominated assets, namely interest rates and expected depreciation, as well as the nominal exchange rate itself. 18 A trade surplus which lasts for several periods will shift the supply of FEX gradually (with lags) Price (kr/$) Supply 1 month with surpluss Demand 2 months with surplus 1 year with surplus E This is true wether capital mobility is perfect or not: Even with less than perfect mobility we expect that in the short-term, the changes in currency supply is dominated by the terms that make out the risk premium on investment in kroner. Perfect capital mobility: The supply schedule becomes horizontal. The impact multiplier of supply with respect to a small change in Et is infinite. We will talk more about perfect capital mobility below, but we first consider the role of the trade surplus/deficits 19 Fg Quantity ($) In the longer term, the trade balance becomes of importance, since persistent surplus in N Xt means that a private and government savings are building up which will have to be allocated to foreign or domestic assets. Graphically, we represent this by small and gradual horizontal shifts in the supply schedule. 20 Capital mobility (1) Price (kr/$) Mathematically, the degree of capital mobility is given by the derivative of the f supply function S(Et, it, it ....), graphically by the slope of the supply curve: Supply Demand E C A B Supply curve with low capital mobility Fg kroner/$ Quantity ($) E Initial situation is A. Then a positive (horizontal) shift in the S-curve. The new equilibrium depends in the exchange rate regime: A →B Supply curve with high capital mobility Floating exchange rate. quantity ($) A →C Fixed exchange rate. The central bank intervenes in the market and increases its demand for USD (the foreign exchange reserves increases) 21 22 Capital mobility (2) Capital mobility is perfect when a small change in E leads to an infinite change in the supply of foreign exchange: mathematically: SE = ∞. Graphically: A horizontal supply schedule in the market for foreign exchange. Price (kr/$) With very high captal mobility, shifts in the supply of foreign currency leads to large endogenous movements in foreign currency reserves, if a fixed E is the policy target. Demand Supply E In terms of economics, this means that with perfect capital mobility there are no separate demand functions for kroner and dollar denominated assets. Instead we have the arbitrage condition: f e /E ) it = it + ln(Et+1 t Note that (7) is the same as setting the risk premium rpt equal to zero. 23 Quantity ($) (7) saying that under perfect capital mobility, investors are indifferent between kroner assets and $ assets: the return on 1 mill invested in kroner assets is the same as the expected return on 1 mill invested in $ assets. (7) is known as the uncovered interest rate parity condition, UIP for short. Fg Capital mobility and the fixed exchange rate regime (1) The degree of capital mobility is important for the operation of exchange rate regimes. The classical “impossibility” is to operate a fixed exchange rate with (near) perfect capital mobility and using foreign currency reserves as policy instrument. 24 Capital mobility and the fixed exchange rate regime (2) However, in principle at least, a fixed exchange rate regime can be operated with a high degree of capital mobility if the interest rate is used as instrument (instead of foreign currency reserves). Note that in (7): f e /E ) it = it + ln(Et+1 t f e Et can be exogenous along with it (determined abroad). If in addition Et+1 is exogenous also, then it is determined by the UIP condition (7). Hence if is it is the policy instrument. Then perfect capital mobility per se, does not rule out the operation of a fixed exchange rate regime. Typology of depreciation expectations: e /E ) = ee + αe ln E ln(Et+1 t t αe < 0 regressive expectations αe > 0 αe = 0 extrapolative (8) constant ( = ee) Using (8) in (7) gives: f it = it + ee + αe ln Et (9) Hence if capital mobility is perfect, and the exchange rate is fixed, the domestic interest rate is determined from (9), which is consistent with endogenous depreciation expectations. e is endogenous, as shown on the next slide This continues to hold if Et+1 25 The Ei-curve 26 Imperfect capital mobility and the Ei-curve. f Since it and ee in (9) are exogenous, (9) defines a curve between Et and it, the Ei-curve. In the case of imperfect capital mobility, the Ei-curve continues to hold, but with important modifications • The slope is no longer 1-1 with the expectations parameter αe (but αe < 0 still secures a downward sloping Ei-curve). With perfect capital mobility, the slope of the Ei curve depends only on expectations. The curve is shifted by changes in foreign interest rates and by 'expectations shocks' it • Several other factor may cause shifts in the Ei-curve. i f αe — Interventions in the market for foreign exchange: if the foreign currency reserve (Fg ) increases, there is a positive horizontal shift in the Ei-curve. ee ln E t 27 — A trade surplus which lasts for some time will cause a gradual negative horizontal shifts in the Ei-curve. 28 Imperfect capital mobility is important since it allows, in principle, if not in practice, a central bank to maintain control of the domestic money supply. The Ei curve is convenient for analyzing equilibrium in capital markets: Money (M ), domestic bonds (Bt) and foreign assets (Fg ). In an open economy the change in the supply of money (M) is given by: ∆Mt = −∆Bt + Et · ∆Fg,t + ∆Et · Fg,t where Bt is the stock of domestic bonds in period t. In a fixed exchange rate regime ∆Et = 0. ∆Mt −∆Bt = +1 Et∆Fg,t Et∆Fg,t This is because the Ei curve shows the foreign exchange market equilibrium values of it and Et. We\ can show the money market equilibrium in the familiar graph of M = m(i, Y ) (10) P where M is nominal money supply and m(i, Y ) is the money demand function. By market operations, the stock of bonds can be changed “1-1” with the change in foreign currency reserves. Thus, money supply is isolated from the market for foreign exchange. This is called sterilization. However sterilization is only possible when capital mobility is imperfect. Finally, from Walras’ Law, when 2 markets are in equilibrium, also the third is in equilibrium. 29 30 interest rate money supply Table 2: Regimes in the domestic money market and the market for foreign exchange. money demand Ei-curve Foreign exchange rate market exogenous variable Foreign exchange reserves Exchange rate it Money Mt Et exchange rate Money market Money supply exogenous Interest rate variable None I III V Figure 2: Joint equilibirum in the domestic money market and in the marked for foreign exchange. 31 32 II IV VI Regime I: Floating exchange rate. Money targeting. (“dirty float” if Fg and sterilization is used discretionaly, which assumes imperfect capital mobility) interest rate Regime II: Fixed exchange rate. Exchange rate targeting (Fg as instrument) with sterilizing monetary policy. Requires imperfect capital mobility. i1 i0 Regime III: Floating exchange rate. For example: interest rate as instrument to target for example inflation. Note: Taylor ruled monetary policy also belongs here. Regime IV: Fixed exchange rate. Exchange rate targeting (Fg as instrument).Requires imperfect capital mobility Money M0 M1 E1 E0 E'0 exchange rate Figure 3: Regime dependent response to changes in exogenous variables. Regime V: Floating exchange rate (“dirty float” if Fg is used discretionaly) Regime VI: Fixed exchange rate. Exchange rate targeting with it as instrument. 34 33 A closer look at Regime VI. Regime II: Ei shifts, due to if % for example. E0 −→ E00 avoided by Fg &. Money market stays at (i0, M0) because of sterilization. Regime IV: Ei shifts, due to if % for example. E0 −→ E00 avoided by Fg &. Money market changes i0 −→ i1 and M0 −→ M1, because of sterilization is not possible. Note: loose monetary policy independence. Regime III: i0 −→ i1 in order to reduce inflation for example M0 −→ M1 and E0 −→ E1. Regime VI: Ei shifts, due to if % for example. E0 −→ E00 avoided by i0 −→ i1 (the same change as in if ). M0 −→ M1 since demand for money falls. Assume again that if increases. From the eq. condition, i must increase by the same amount, irrespective of the degree of capital mobility (since both Fg and E are exogenous in the market). Another source of change in i in the case of this regime is expectations driven runs of speculative attacks. If a situation occurs with large probability of devaluation in the near future, the rise in short interest rates (overnight, monthly) may be huge. Example P rob(10% devaluation within one month) = 0.5. 0.5 × 10% = 5% expected rate of depreciation over the next month. 35 36 Per annum, this corresponds to a interest rate differential of The Swedish effective exchange rate index. 1.4 0.5 × 10% × 12 = 60% 1.3 If this is to be compensated completely, the domestic one-month interest rate (annualized rate) must increase by 60 percentage points! 1.2 1.1 September 1992 1.0 In practice, governments have often tried to defend the exchange rate by a combination of Fg and i policies. Sweden and Norway in the autumn of 1992 are good examples. 0.9 0.8 0.7 In Sweden in particular short-term interest rates shoot-up to the hundreds. Interest on loans with longer maturity (house loans) did not increase as much, because the high short term rates did not last long for long 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 Figure 4: Swedish exchange nominal effective rate. 37 38 Regime dependent macro models 100 17 and 18 September 1992 Swe 1 month f yt = β0 + β1ert − β2rt + β3gt + β4yt e rt = it − πt+1 90 80 f (13) (14) it = it + ee + αe(∆et + et−1) mt − πt − pt−1 = m0 − m1it + m2yt, mi > 0, i = 1, 2 (15) (16) ert = ∆et + πt − πt + ert−1 πt = πte + γ(yt − ȳ) + st 70 60 f 50 40 (11) (12) 30 20 2 January 1991 31 December 1993 10 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 Figure 5: Sweden. 1-month yield on treasury bills. 39 (11) has been explained above. (12) is the definition of the real interest rate. e is the expected rate of inflation, one period ahead. πt+1 (13) is a definition equation for ert , see IAM, p 704 and 711. (14) is the PCM. e /E ) ≡ ee e e (15) is UIP with ln(Et+1 t t+1 − et = e + α (∆et + et−1) inserted. (16) is an equilibrium condition for the money market. Right hand side is a linearization of the demand for money function. 40 Short-run models Regime I f f In all the short-run models, the following variables are exogenous: gt, yt , st, πt , f r it , et−1, et−1 and pt−1 (or pt, see discussion of Regime I below). Regime VI Regime dependent exogenous: mt Money market and FEX market is now interlocked. Solve (15) and (??) for it and the nominal exchange rate; Regime dependent exogenous:∆et. yt πt it o f = β0 + β1 ∆et + πt − πt + ert−1 (17) n o f f e + β3gt + β4yt − β2 it + ee + αe(∆et + et−1) − πt+1 = πte + γ(yt − ȳ) + st (18) f e e = it + e + α (∆et + et−1) (19) 1 f (it − it − ee) − et−1 αe −1 m m it = (mt − πt − pt−1) + 0 + 2 yt m1 m1 m1 ∆et = n mt − πt − pt−1 = m0 − m1it + m2yt (20) (17) is the AD curve. Note that the equilibrium condition on the market for foreign exchange, (19), is included in this equation. (18) is the AS curve. If e , and π e are exogenous, then (17) and (18) determines y and π . i is πt+1 t t t t determined in (19) and mt in (20). ( ( ) m m 1 f −1 f (mt − πt − pt−1) + 0 + 2 yt − e (it + ee) + πt − πt m1 m1 m1 α ( ) m0 m2 −1 e − β2 (mt − πt − pt−1) + + yt − πt+1 m1 m1 m1 yt = β0 + β1 1 αe f + β3gt + β4yt (21) πt = πte + γ(yt − ȳ) + st 41 42 The difference between regime I and VI is the slope of the AD curves (17) and (21): which amounts to abstracting from the effect of πt of real money supply. This is convenient since it is easy to see that using (24), ¯ ∂πt ¯¯ 1 = <0 ¯ ¯ ∂yt AD,rV I −β1 ¯ (22) m1 2 1 − β1 αm e m + β2 m ∂πt ¯¯ 1 2 = ¯ m1 0 2 ∂yt ¯AD,rI −β1 + β1 αm e m − β2 m 1 (23) 2 Note first that (23) hinges on αe 6= 0. The interpretation is that with constant depreciation expectations and perfect capital mobility, it is determined by the UIP condition alone. Hence αe = 0 would introduce an internal inconsistency with the assumption that in this regime, mt is exogenous. Second, in most expositions, (23) is simplified to ¯ m1 2 1 − β1 αm e m + β2 m ∂πt ¯¯ 1 2 = ¯ ∂yt ¯AD,rI −β1 43 (24) − ¯ ¯ ∂πt ¯¯ ∂πt ¯¯ >− , when αe < 0 ¯ ¯ ∂yt ¯AD,rI ∂yt ¯AD,rV I (25) meaning that the slope of the short-run AD curve is steeper in Regime I than in Regime 6, at least when αe < 0. The simplified expression is tantamount to replacing (16) with mt − pt = m0 − m1it + m2yt (26) and replacing pt−1 with pt in the list of exogenous variables. The rationale is that, over short periods of time, the price level and the stock of real money are more or less unaffected by the rate of inflation: The are assumed to be exogenous since they can reasonably be views as pre-determined stock variables. 44 ) π Note the difference from the nominal exchange rate, et (in logs), and its growths rate. The rationale is that the price of foreign currency can change significantly even within very short time periods. The is consistent with the portfolio approach to the foreign exchange market. Hence it does not make good sense to treat et as predetermined in regime I. Regime VI Regime I y Figure 6: Short-run AD curves, fixed φet+1 in regime I and VI. 45 46